Skip to main content
Log in

Dynamic adjustment of ethanol demand to crude oil prices: implications for mandated ethanol usage

  • Published:
Empirical Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

This paper examines the dynamic behavior of ethanol blenders with a focus on the substitution possibilities between ethanol and crude oil in the fuel blending sector. The estimation results of the dynamic linear logit model reveal that the dynamic adjustment in the input demand system is very sluggish. In addition, the estimation results show that an increase in gasoline output no longer raises the share of ethanol after imposing the mandated percentage standard for ethanol. The estimated price elasticities of input demand offer statistical evidence that ethanol demand is less responsive to crude oil prices in the post-ethanol-mandate period than in the pre-ethanol-mandate period. The decompositions of cross-price elasticities strongly support that the reduced elasticities of ethanol demand with respect to the price of crude oil are more attributable to the mandated percentage standard for ethanol rather than the relative price of ethanol to crude oil.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. There was skepticism about corn-based ethanol. Unlike the arguments of ethanol advocates, many studies on ethanol concluded that corn-based ethanol would be technically and environmentally limited (Pimentel 2003; Pimentel and Patzek 2005; Eaves and Eaves 2007; Searchinger et al. 2008; Thompson et al. 2011; Lankoski and Ollikainen 2011). The technical transformation of corn into ethanol might create large production costs, while the increase in ethanol demand might fail to produce significant environmental benefits. Moreover, welfare analyses on ethanol did not clearly support the ethanol policy (Gardner 2007; Gardner and Tyner 2007; Martinez-Gonzalez et al. 2007; Schmitz et al. 2007; Babcock 2008; Gorter and Just 2009a, b; Du et al. 2009). The ethanol policy would be beneficial to corn producers as well as ethanol producers, but the benefits might be offset by the large costs that government and consumers would pay.

  2. The EPA defines ethanol blenders as any persons who own, lease, operate, control, or supervise ethanol blending plants; the plants imply any refineries where gasoline is produced by adding ethanol to gasoline.

  3. While the literature has given no attention to the substitution possibilities between ethanol and crude oil, a few past studies focused on the substitution of ethanol for gasoline (Rask 1998; Gardner 2007; Babcock 2008; Luchansky and Monks 2009; Anderson 2012). However, their results were mixed with respect to the role of ethanol, showing a wide range of price elasticities. The estimated own-price elasticities of ethanol demand varied from −0.22 (inelastic) to −2.82 (elastic), and the estimated gasoline-price elasticities of ethanol demand ranged from \(-\)2.13 (complements) to 5.05 (substitutes).

  4. Most studies on input substitution employed flexible functional forms based on the duality approach to the demand system for inputs (Diewert 1971; Fuss 1977; Griffin 1977; Pindyck 1979; Guilkey and Lovell 1980; Guilkey et al. 1983; Hall 1986; Diewert and Wales 1995; Fisher et al. 2001; Serletis et al. 2010). However, the dynamic mechanisms with flexible functional forms frequently failed to obey the theoretical conditions (Considine and Mount 1984). In particular, the empirical applications of dynamic flexible forms often yielded unexpected signs of price elasticities.

  5. The Chow test indicates that there exist statistical differences in the estimates between the two periods; the statistic is 18.33 which is significant at the 5 % level (Chow 1960). In addition, there is statistical evidence that a structural change occurs during the full-sample period from 1993 to 2015 (see “Appendix” for detailed results). The results presented in “Appendix” indicate that there exists a structural change due to the Energy Policy Act of 2005, implying that the ethanol mandate may lead to a change in the substitution possibilities.

  6. Frondel and Schmidt (2006) decomposed the observed differences in the cross-price elasticities between capital and energy. Considering the estimates as factual cross-price elasticities, they established counterfactual cross-price elasticities to use the Oaxaca–Blinder decompositions; their analysis applied the decompositions of wage differences to changes in the cross-price elasticities (Blinder 1973; Oaxaca 1973; Oaxaca and Ransom 1994). For the dynamic analysis, Steinbuks (2012) applied the decompositions to the estimates of the dynamic linear logit model in order to identify the technology differences in interfuel substitution.

References

  • Anderson S (2012) The demand for ethanol as a gasoline substitute. J Environ Econ Manag 63(2):151–168

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Babcock B (2008) Distributional implications of U.S. ethanol policy. Appl Econ Perspect Policy 30(3):533–542

    Google Scholar 

  • Blinder A (1973) Wage discrimination: reduced form and structural estimates. J Hum Resour 8(4):436–455

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cameron A, Trivedi P (2005) Microeconometrics: methods and applications. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Chambers R (1988) Applied production analysis: a dual approach. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Chow GC (1960) Tests of equality between sets of coefficients in two linear regressions. Econometrica 28(3):591–605

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chum HL, Warner E, Seabra JE, Macedo IC (2014a) A comparison of commercial ethanol production systems from Brazilian sugarcane and U.S. Corn. Biofuels Bioprod Biorefin 8(2):205–223

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chum HL, Zhang Y, Hill J, Tiffany DG, Morey RV, Eng AG, Haq Z (2014b) Understanding the evolution of environmental and energy performance of the U.S. corn ethanol industry: evaluation of selected metrics. Biofuels Bioprod Biorefin 8(2):224–240

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Considine T (1989) Separability, functional form and regulatory policy in models of interfuel substitution. Energy Econ 11(2):89–94

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Considine T (1990) Symmetry constraints and variable returns to scale in logit models. J Bus Econ Stat 8(3):347–353

    Google Scholar 

  • Considine T, Mount T (1984) The use of linear logit models for dynamic input demand systems. Rev Econ Stat 66(3):434–443

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • de Gorter H, Just D (2009a) The welfare economics of a biofuel tax credit and the interaction effects with price contingent farm subsidies. Am J Agric Econ 91(2):477–488

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • de Gorter H, Just D (2009b) The economics of a blend mandate for biofuels. Am J Agric Econ 91(3):738–750

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Diewert W (1971) An application of the shephard duality theorem: a generalized leontief production function. J Polit Econ 79(3):481–507

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Diewert W, Wales T (1995) Flexible functional forms and tests of homogeneous separability. J Econom 67(2):259–302

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Doornik JA, Hansen H (2008) An omnibus test for univariate and multivariate normality. Oxf Bull Econ Stat 70(s1):927–939

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Du X, Hayes D, Mallory M (2009) A welfare analysis of the U.S. ethanol subsidy. Appl Econ Perspect Policy 31(4):669–676

    Google Scholar 

  • Eaves J, Eaves S (2007) Renewable corn-ethanol and energy security. Energy Policy 35(11):5958–5963

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Elobeid A, Hart C (2007) Ethanol expansion in the food versus fuel debate: how will developing countries fare? J Agric Food Indus Organ 5(2):Article 6

  • Fisher D, Fleissig A, Serletis A (2001) An empirical comparison of flexible demand system functional forms. J Appl Econom 16(1):59–80

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Frondel M, Schmidt C (2006) The empirical assessment of technology differences: comparing the comparable. Rev Econ Stat 88(1):186–192

    Google Scholar 

  • Fuss M (1977) The demand for energy in canadian manufacturing: an example of the estimation of production function with many inputs. J Econom 5(1):89–116

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gardner B (2007) Fuel ethanol subsidies and farm price support. J Agric Food Indus Organ 5(2):Article 4

  • Gardner B, Tyner W (2007) Explorations in biofuels economics, policy, and history: introduction to the special issue. J Agric Food Indus Organ 5(2):Article 1

  • Griffin J (1977) Interfuel substitution possibilities: a translog application to intercountry data. Int Econ Rev 18(3):755–770

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Guilkey D, Lovell C (1980) On the flexibility of the translog approximation. Int Econ Rev 21(1):137–147

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Guilkey D, Lovell C, Sickles R (1983) A comparison of the performance of three flexible functional forms. Int Econ Rev 24(3):591–616

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hall V (1986) Industrial sector fuel price elasticities following the first and second major oil price shocks. Econ Lett 20(1):79–82

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hettinga WG, Junginger HM, Dekker SC, Hoogwijk M, McAloon AJ, Hicks KB (2009) Understanding the reductions in U.S. corn ethanol production costs: an experience curve approach. Energy Policy 37(1):190–203

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hosking JRM (1980) The multivariate portmanteau statistic. J Am Stat Assoc 75(371):602–608

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hosking JRM (1981) Equivalent forms of the multivariate portmanteau statistic. J R Stat Soc Ser B 43:261–262

    Google Scholar 

  • Jones C (1995) A dynamic analysis of interfuel substitution in U.S. industrial energy demand. J Bus Econ Stat 13(4):459–465

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Khanna M, Ando A, Taheripour F (2008) Welfare effects and unintended consequences of ethanol subsidies. Appl Econ Perspect Policy 30(3):411–421

    Google Scholar 

  • Laitinen K (1978) Why is demand homogeneity so often rejected? Econ Lett 1(3):187–191

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lankoski J, Ollikainen M (2011) Biofuel policies and the environment: do climate benefits warrant increased production from biofuel feedstocks? Ecol Econ 70(4):676–687

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Luchansky M, Monks J (2009) Supply and demand elasticities in the U.S. ethanol fuel market. Energy Econ 31(3):403–410

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Martinez-Gonzalez A, Sheldon I, Thompson S (2007) Estimating the welfare effects of U.S. distortions in the ethanol market using a partial equilibrium trade model. J Agric Food Indus Organ 5(2):Article 5

  • Meisner J (1979) The sad fate of asymptotic slutsky symmetry tests for large systems. Econ Lett 2(3):228–234

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Oaxaca R (1973) Male–female wage differentials in urban labor markets. Int Econ Rev 14(3):693–709

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Oaxaca R, Ransom M (1994) On discrimination and the decomposition of wage differentials. J Econom 61(1):5–21

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pimentel D (2003) Ethanol fuels: energy balance, economics, and environmental impacts are negative. Nat Resour Res 12(2):127–134

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pimentel D, Patzek T (2005) Ethanol production using corn, switchgrass, and wood; biodiesel production using soybean and sunflower. Nat Resour Res 14(1):65–76

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pindyck R (1979) Interfuel substitution and the industrial demand for energy: an international comparison. Rev Econ Stat 61(2):169–179

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rask K (1984) Clean air and renewable fuels: the market for fuel ethanol in the U.S. from 1984 to 1993. Energy Econ 20(3):325–345

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Schmitz A, Moss C, Schmitz T (2007) Ethanol: no free lunch. J Agric Food Indus Organ 5(2):Article 3

  • Schnepf R, Yacobucci B (2013) Renewable fuel standard (RFS): overview and issues. Congressional Research Service, Washington

    Google Scholar 

  • Searchinger T, Heimlich R, Houghton R, Dong R, Elobeid A, Fabiosa J, Tokgoz S, Hayes D, Yu T (2008) Use of U.S. croplands for biofuels increases greenhouse gases through emissions from land-use change. Science 319(5867):1238–1240

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Serletis A, Timilsina G, Vasetsky O (2010) Interfuel substitution in the United States. Energy Econ 32(3):737–745

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Steinbuks J (2012) Interfuel substitution and energy use in the U.K. manufacturing sector. Energy J 33(1):1–29

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Terrell D (1996) Incorporating monotonicity and concavity conditions in flexible functional forms. J Appl Econom 11(2):179–194

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Thompson W, Whistance J, Meyer S (2011) Effects of U.S. biofuel policies on U.S. and world petroleum product markets with consequences for greenhouse gas emissions. Energy Policy 39(9):5509–5518

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tyner WE (2007) U.S. ethanol policy: possibilities for the future. Purdue University Cooperative Extension Service, West Lafayette

    Google Scholar 

  • Urga G, Walters C (2003) Dynamic translog and linear logit models: a factor demand analysis of interfuel substitution in U.S. industrial energy demand. Energy Econ 25(1):1–21

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wolff H, Heckelei T, Mittelhammer R (2010) Imposing curvature and monotonicity on flexible functional forms: an efficient regional approach. Comput Econ 36(4):309–339

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Yacobucci BD (2005) Alternative transportation fuels and vehicles: energy, environment, and development issues. Congressional Research Service, Washington

    Google Scholar 

  • Yacobucci BD (2012) Biofuels incentives: a summary of federal programs. Congressional Research Service, Washington

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Dong Hee Suh.

Appendix: Dynamic linear logit model and structural change

Appendix: Dynamic linear logit model and structural change

Additional explanatory variables are added to know whether the ethanol mandate induces a structural break in the dynamic linear logit model (Considine 1989). A dynamic linear logit model is specified as

$$\begin{aligned} \ln \left( \frac{s_c}{s_e}\right) _t&= \alpha _c - \left[ \beta _{cg}^{*} s_{gt}^{*} + \beta _{ce}^{*} \left( s_{ct}^{*} + s_{et}^{*} \right) \right] \ln \left( \frac{w_c}{w_e}\right) _t \nonumber \\&\quad + \left( \beta _{cg}^{*} - \beta _{ge}^{*} \right) s_{gt}^{*} \ln \left( \frac{w_g}{w_e}\right) _t + \gamma _c \ln y_t \nonumber \\&\quad + \theta \ln \left( \frac{x_c}{x_e}\right) _{t-1} + \delta _{c} \ln \left( \frac{w_c}{w_e}\right) _t d_t + \psi _{c} \ln \left( \frac{w_g}{w_e}\right) _t d_t \nonumber \\&\quad + \rho _{c} \ln y_t d_t + \varphi _{c} d_t + \left( \epsilon _c - \epsilon _e \right) _t \end{aligned}$$
(16a)
$$\begin{aligned} \ln \left( \frac{s_g}{s_e}\right) _t&= \alpha _g - \left[ \beta _{cg}^{*} s_{ct}^{*} + \beta _{ge}^{*} \left( s_{gt}^{*} + s_{et}^{*} \right) \right] \ln \left( \frac{w_g}{w_e}\right) _t \nonumber \\&\quad + \left( \beta _{cg}^{*} - \beta _{ce}^{*} \right) s_{ct}^{*} \ln \left( \frac{w_c}{w_e}\right) _t + \gamma _g \ln y_t \nonumber \\&\quad + \theta \ln \left( \frac{x_g}{x_e}\right) _{t-1} + \delta _{g} \ln \left( \frac{w_c}{w_e}\right) _t d_t + \psi _{g} \ln \left( \frac{w_g}{w_e}\right) _t d_t \nonumber \\&\quad + \rho _{g} \ln y_t d_t + \varphi _{g} d_t + \left( \epsilon _g - \epsilon _e \right) _t \end{aligned}$$
(16b)

where \(d_t\) is equal to 1 if the ethanol mandate is effective (i.e., 2006–2015 period), and equal to 0 otherwise (i.e., 1993–2005 period). The maintained hypothesis is that the Energy Policy Act of 2005 has no effect on the relative cost shares of inputs, which implies the null hypothesis is \(\varphi _{c}=\varphi _{g}=0\). In Table 7, the estimation results reject the null hypothesis, showing that the implementation of the ethanol mandate significantly affects the relative cost shares of inputs.

Table 7 Structural change in fuel blending sector, Jan 1993–Aug 2015

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Suh, D.H., Moss, C.B. Dynamic adjustment of ethanol demand to crude oil prices: implications for mandated ethanol usage. Empir Econ 52, 1587–1607 (2017). https://doi.org/10.1007/s00181-016-1112-6

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s00181-016-1112-6

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation