Skip to main content
Log in

Inward-Looking Policies, Institutions, Autocrats, and Economic Growth in Latin America: An Empirical Exploration

  • Published:
Public Choice Aims and scope Submit manuscript

An Erratum to this article was published on 01 April 2011

Abstract

This paper explores the institutionaldeterminants of economic growth in LatinAmerica by taking advantage of recentempirical research that employs subjectiveand objective measures to test for apossible “Northian” explanation that linksinstitutional quality and economic growth.We explore a simple framework that may helpbetter understand the policymakers’ choicesand persistence regarding inward-lookingpolicies that were pursued between the1930s and the 1980s by arguing that in theLatin American case Olson’s (1982) idea ofencompassing interest should be expanded tocover not only the economic stakes of powerholders, but in particular, their psychicincome which includes their politicalstakes, along the lines of recent work byRobinson (1997), Coyne (2002), andothers.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

References

  • Acemoglu, D. and Robinson, J. (2000). Why did the West extend the franchise? Democracy, inequality, and growth in historical perspective. Quarterly Journal of Economics 115: 1167–1199.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Alesina, A., Ozler, S., Roubini, N. and Swagel, P. (1996). Political instability and economic growth. Journal of Economic Growth 1: 189–211.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Anderson, C.W. (1964). Nicaragua: The Somoza Dynasty. In: M. Needler (Ed.), Political systems of Latin America. Princeton: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Barro, R. and Lee, J.-W. (1994). Data set for a panel of 138 countries. Cambridge: National Bureau of Economic Research. http://www.nber.org

    Google Scholar 

  • Bourguignon, F. and Verdier, T. (1998). Oligarchy, democracy, inequality and growth. Journal of Development Economics 62: 285–313.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brennan, G. and Buchanan, J.M. (2000). The power to tax: Analytical foundations of a fiscal constitution. Indianapolis, IN: Liberty Fund, Inc.

    Google Scholar 

  • Brunetti, A., Kisunko, G. and Weder, B. (1997). Institutional obstacles to doing business: Region-by-region results from a worldwide survey of the private sector. Policy Research Working Paper 1759. Washington, DC: World Bank.

    Google Scholar 

  • Business Environmental Risk Intelligence (BERI). Various dates. Business risk service. Geneva: BERI. http://www.beri.com.

  • Chong, A. and Calderón, C. (2000). Institutional quality and distribution of income. Economic Development and Cultural Change 48: 761–788.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chong, A. and Calderón, C. (2000a). Causality and feedback between institutional measures and economic growth. Economics and Politics 12: 69–81.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Clague, C., Keefer, P., Knack, S. and Olson, M. (1996). Property rights in autocracies and democracies. Journal of Economic Growth 1: 243–276.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Clague, C., Keefer, P., Knack, S. and Olson, M. (1999). Contract intensive money. Journal of Economic Growth 4: 185–212.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Coatsworth, J. (1978). Obstacles to economic growth in nineteenth-century Mexico. American Historical Review 83: 80–100.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Coatsworth, J. (1993). Economic retardation and growth in Latin America and southern Europe since 1700. Harvard University. (Manuscript).

  • Coyne, C. (2003). Dictatorship, democracy and intervention: On the interests of the ruling group and the welfare of the ruled. George Mason University. (Manuscript).

  • De Gregorio, J. (1992). Economic growth in Latin America. Journal of Development Economics 39: 59–84.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • De Long, B. and Shleifer, A. (1993). Princes and merchants: European city growth before the industrial revolution. Journal of Law and Economics 36: 671–703.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • De Vries, J. (1976). The economy in Europe in an age of crisis, 1600–1750. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Eggertson, T. (1990). Economic behavior and institutions. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Engerman, S. and Sokoloff, K. (1997). Factor endowments, institutions, and differential paths of growth among new world economies: A view from economic historians of the United States. In: S. Haber (Ed.), How Latin America fell behind. Stanford: Stanford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Engerman, S., Mariscal, E. and Sokoloff, K. (1998). Schooling, suffrage, and the persistence of inequality in the Americas, 1800–1945. Manuscript, University of Rochester.

  • Gastil, R.D. (Ed.) (1982). Freedom in the world: Political rights and civil rights. Westport: Greenwood Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gerschenkron, A. (1962). Economic backwardness in historical perspective. Cambridge: Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Geweke, J. (1982). Measurement of linear dependence and feedback between time series. Journal of the American Statistical Association 79: 304–324.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Geweke, J. (1984). Inference and causality in economic time series models. In: Z. Griliches and M. Intriligator (Eds.), Handbook of econometrics. Amsterdam: North-Holland.

    Google Scholar 

  • Glade, W. (1969). The Latin American economies: A study of their institutional evolution. New York: Van Nostrand.

    Google Scholar 

  • Greif, A. (1994). On the political foundation of the late medieval commercial revolution: Genoa during the twelfth and thirteenth centuries. Journal of Economic History 54: 271–287.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Haggard, S. and Kaufman, R. (1995). The political economy of democratic transitions. Princeton: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hall, R. and Jones, C. (1999). Why do some countries produce so much more output per worker than others? Quarterly Journal of Economics 114: 83–116.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Justman, M. and Gradstein, M. (1999). The industrial revolution, political transition, and the subsequent decline in inequality in 19th-century Britain. Explorations in Economic History 36: 109–127.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Klenow, P. and Rodríguez-Clare, A. (1997). Economic growth: A review essay. Journal of Monetary Economics 40: 597–617.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Knack, S. and Keefer, P. (1995). Institutions and economic performance: Cross-country tests using alternative institutional measures. Economics and Politics 7: 207–229.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Knight, M., Loayza, N. and Villanueva, D. (1996). The peace dividend: Military spending cuts and economic growth. International Monetary Fund Staff Papers 43: 1–37.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Levine, R. and Renelt, D. (1992). A sensitivity analysis of cross-country regressions. American Economic Review 82: 942–963.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lundahl M. (1992). Politics or markets? Essays on Haitian underdevelopment. NewYork: Routledge.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lundahl, M. and Vedovato, C. (1989). The state and economic development in Haiti and the Dominican Republic. Scandinavian Economic History Review 37: 39–59.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mauro, P. (1995). Corruption and growth. Quarterly Journal of Economics 109: 681–712.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • McGuire, M. and Olson, M. (1996). The economics of autocracy and majority rule. Journal of Economic Literature 34: 72–96.

    Google Scholar 

  • Newey, W.K. (1987). Efficient estimation of limited dependent variable models with endogenous explanatory variables. Journal of Econometrics 36: 231–250.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • North, D. (1990). Institutions, institutional change, and economic performance. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Nurkse, R. (1961). Patterns of trade and development. The Wicksell Lectures. Oxford: Basil Blackwell.

    Google Scholar 

  • Olson, M. (1982). The rise and decline of nations. New Haven: Yale University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Olson, M. (1993). Dictatorship, democracy, and development. American Political Science Review 87: 567–576.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Olson, M. (1997). The new institutional economics: The collective choice approach to economic development. In: C. Clague (Ed.), Institutions and economic development: Growth and governance in less-developed and post-socialist countries. Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ornes, G.E. (1958). Trujillo: Little Caesar of the Caribbean. New York: Thomas Nelson & Sons.

    Google Scholar 

  • Political Risk Services. International Country Risk Guide. East Syracuse, United States: Political Risk Services.

  • Prebisch, R. (1984). Five stages in my thinking on development. In: G. Mier and D. Seers (Eds.), Pioneers in development. New York: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rama, M. (1993). Rent-seeking and economic growth: A theoretical model and some empirical evidence. Journal of Development Economics 42: 35–50.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Robinson, J. (1997). A political theory of underdevelopment. Department of Economics, University of Southern California. (Manuscript).

  • Rosenberg, N. and Birdzell, L., Jr. (1985). How the West grew rich: The economic transformation of the industrial world. New York: Basic Books.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rothbard, M. (1993). Man economy and state. Alabama: The Ludwig von Mises Institute.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sachs, J.D. and Warner, A.M. (1995). Economic reform and the process of global integration. Brookings Papers on Economic Activity 1–118.

  • Sala-i-Martín, X. (1997). I just ran two million regressions. American Economic Review 87: 178–183.

    Google Scholar 

  • Scully, G. (1988). The institutional framework and economic development. Journal of Political Economy 96: 652–662.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Singer, H. (1950). The division of gains between investing and borrowing countries. American Economic Review 40: 473–480.

    Google Scholar 

  • Stockholm International Peace Research Institute (SIPRI). Various years. SIPRI Yearbook. Stockholm, Sweden: SIPRI. http://www.sipri.se

  • Summers, R. and Heston, A. (1991). The Penn World Table (Mark V): An extended set of international comparisons, 1950–. Quarterly Journal of Economics 106: 327–336.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Taylor, A. (1998). On the costs of inward-looking development: Price distortions, growth, and divergence in Latin America. Journal of Economic History 58: 1–29.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wei, S.-J. (2000). How taxing is corruption on international investors? The Review of Economics and Statistics 82: 12–22.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Weingast, B.R. (1993). Constitutions as governance structures: The political foundations of secure markets. Journal of Institutional and Theoretical Economics 149: 286–311.

    Google Scholar 

  • Wiarda, H. (1968). Dictatorship and development: The methods of control in Trujillo’s Dominican Republic. Gainesville: University of Florida Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • World Bank. (2001). World development indicators. Washington, DC: World Bank.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Additional information

An erratum to this article can be found online at http://dx.doi.org/10.1007/s11127-011-9787-x

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Chong, A., Zanforlin, L. Inward-Looking Policies, Institutions, Autocrats, and Economic Growth in Latin America: An Empirical Exploration. Public Choice 121, 335–361 (2004). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11127-004-1683-1

Download citation

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11127-004-1683-1

Keywords

Navigation