Skip to main content
Log in

Port Infrastructure: An Access Model for the Essential Facility

  • Original Article
  • Published:
Maritime Economics & Logistics Aims and scope

Abstract

This paper analyses the main consequences for the seaport efficiency of an access regime recently introduced by the Peruvian regulator for the public transportation infrastructure (OSITRAN). Its objective is to make competition viable for services that use, as input, transport infrastructure controlled by a monopolist. It is based on two theoretical contributions, the ‘Coase theorem’ and the ‘Demsetz approach’, and minimises the government intervention risk. Both port operators and providers of port services now have incentives to negotiate conditions of access, which permit competition, or to compete for an exclusivity right when this is desirable. If the parties do not reach an agreement within a reasonable time, the Regulator can enact an access mandate that may punish any of the parties, creating incentives for them to reach a Nash Equilibrium. The model seems to be generating productive and allocative efficiencies in port services, thus contributing to a potential reduction in Peru's maritime transport costs.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Figure 1

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. We thank A Bullard, C García-Godos, R De la Cruz, V Paredes, J Arnold, J Hoffmann, G Nombela and S Farrell for their valuable comments and suggestions. The views expressed in this document do not necessarily reflect the opinion of OSITRAN.

  2. It refers to the organisation that controls the use of port infrastructure.

  3. Formally, the name is ‘Reglamento Marco de Acceso a la Infraestructura de Transporte de Uso Público’ (Regulatory Framework for Access to Transport Infrastructure in Public Use). It was legalised by means of the Resolution of the Directive Council N 034-2001-CD/OSITRAN, published on 31 December, 2001.

  4. Annex N 2 of the Access Regulation.

  5. Articles 19 and 24 of the Access Regulation.

  6. Articles 28 and 30 of the Access Regulation.

References

  • ADEPSEP. 2002: Estado Actual de la Infraestructura de Servicios Públicos: Estimación de la Brecha de Inversión. Lima.

  • Baumol, W, Panzer, J and Willig, D . 1982: Contestable markets and the theory of industrial structure. Harcourt Brace Jovanovich: New York.

    Google Scholar 

  • Coase, R . 1960: The problem of social cost. Journal of Law and Economics, 3: 1–44.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Demsetz, H . 1968: Why regulate utilities? Journal of Law and Economics, 11: 55–66.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fourgeaud, P . 2000: Measuring port performance. World Bank: Washington, DC.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hoffmann, J . 2002: The cost of international transport, and integration and competitiveness in Latin America and the Caribbean. FAL Bulletin 191, ECLAC, Santiago de Chile, July.

  • Hoffmann, J . 2001: Latin American ports: Results and determinants of private sector participation. International Journal of Maritime Economics 3: 221–241.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Martínez-Zarzoso, I, García Menéndez, L and Suárez Burguet, C . 2002: Maritime and overland transport cost and infrastructure: Do they influence exports? IAME Panama 2002 Conference Proceedings, Panama.

  • Micco, A and Pérez, N . 2001: Maritime transport cost and port efficiency. Inter American Development Bank (IADB): Washington, DC.

    Google Scholar 

  • Micco, A and Pérez, N . 2002: Determinants of maritime transport costs. Inter American Development Bank (IADB): Washington, DC.

    Google Scholar 

  • OSITRAN. 2001: Reglamento Marco de Acceso a la Infraestructura de Transporte de Uso Público. Resolución No. 034-2001-CD/OSITRAN www.ositran.gob.pe

  • OSITRAN. 2002: Estudio Comparativo de Tarifas Portuarias de ENAPU. Lima.

  • Sánchez, R, Hoffmann, J, Micco, A, Pizzolitto, G, Sgut, M and Wilmsmeier, G . 2002: Port efficiency and international trade: port efficiency as a determinant of maritime transport cost. IAME Panama 2002 Conference Proceedings, Panama.

  • South Australian Government – SAG. 2001: Application to the National Competition Council for a Recommendation on the Effectiveness of South Australian Ports and Maritime Services Access Regime.

  • South Australian Independent Industry Regulator – SAIIR. 2002a: Regulation of South Australian ports. Information Paper. June.

  • South Australian Independent Industry Regulator – SAIIR. 2002b: Ports access guidelines: Price information & regulatory accounts. Discussion Paper.

FURTHER REFERENCES The following list of documents is considered to be of further interest concerning Privatization, Efficiency and Access.

  • Armstrong, M, Cowan, S and Vickers, J . 1997: Regulatory reform: Economic analysis and British experience. MIT Press: Cambridge, MA.

    Google Scholar 

  • Estache, A and De Rus, G . 2000: Privatization and regulation of transport infrastructure. World Bank Institute: Washington, DC, USA. pp. 119–169.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Goss, R and Stevens, H . 2001: Marginal cost pricing in seaports. International Journal of Maritime Economics 3: 128–138.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Haralambides, H . 2002: Competition, excess capacity, and the pricing of port infrastructure. International Journal of Maritime Economics 4: 323–347.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Haralambides, H, Carriou, P and Benacchio, M . 2002: Costs, benefits and pricing of dedicated container terminals. International Journal of Maritime Economics 4: 21–34.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Haralambides, H, Verbeke, A and Musso, E . 2001: Port financing and pricing in the European Union: theory, politics and reality. International Journal of Maritime Economics 3: 368–386.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ircha, M . 2001: North American port reform: the Canadian and American experience. International Journal of Maritime Economics 3: 198–220.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Juhel, M . 2001: Globalization, privatization and restructuring of ports. International Journal of Maritime Economics 3: 139–174.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Notteboom, T and Winkelmans, W . 2001: Reassessing public sector involvement in European seaports. International Journal of Maritime Economics 3: 242–259.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sappington, D . 1994: Principles of regulatory policy design. Policy Research Working paper 1239. World Bank: Washington, DC.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sierra, P . 2001: Las Facilidades esenciales en la doctrina de los organismos de competencia chilenos. IFM-129.

  • Tarziján, J and Paredes, R . 2001: Organización Industrial para la Estrategia Empresarial. Prentice-Hall: Buenos Aires. pp. 321–335.

    Google Scholar 

  • Valletti, T . 1998: The practice of access pricing: telecommunications in the United Kingdom. World Bank: Washington, DC.

    Google Scholar 

  • Valletti, T and Estache, A . 1998: The theory of access pricing: an overview for infrastructure regulators. World Bank: Washington, DC.

    Google Scholar 

  • Viscusi, W, Vernon, J and Harrington, J . 1989: Economic regulation and antitrust. The MIT Press: Cambridge, MA. pp. 240–260.

    Google Scholar 

  • Warwick Business School. 2001: Papers on Access pricing investment and entry in telecommunications. Centre for Management under Regulation: United Kingdom.

  • Wiegmans, B et al. 2002: Investment in container terminals: public private partnerships in Europe. International Journal of Maritime Economics 4: 1–20.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • World Bank Institute. 2000: Privatization and Regulation of Transport Infrastructure: Washington.

  • World Bank. 2001: Port reform toolkit. http://rru.worldbank.org/Toolkits/index.htm

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Appendix A: THE PERUVIAN SEAPORT SYSTEM

Appendix A: THE PERUVIAN SEAPORT SYSTEM

Peru has seven public seaports, distributed along 2,500 km of coast. The most important is Callao, located in the vicinity of Lima, which in 2001 registered a movement equivalent to 70% of the cargo mobilised at all public seaports. Other important seaports are General San Martín, Matarani and Paita, which jointly mobilised 3.7 million metric tons (MT) (Table A1).

Table a1 Revenues and cargo in Peruvian ports: 2001

Since 1970, the Peruvian seaports have been operated by ENAPU S.A. This is a State-owned company dependent on the Ministry of Transport and Communications. In 1999, the concessioning of seaports began with the concession of the Matarani port to TISUR. Since then, the process has been suspended as a consequence of an adverse political climate to market-oriented reforms.

The public operation of Peruvian seaports has many deficiencies that reduce the competitiveness of Peruvian foreign trade. First, ENAPU has an excessive number of employees, which, at Callao alone, reaches 700 when an adequate number would be between 150 and 200 (see Fourgeaud, 2000). Another problem is that ENAPU is responsible for all of the retirement payments to its former employees, which represents 30% of its annual costs. These problems result in tariffs that are among the highest in the region, as shown by a recent study conducted by OSITRAN (OSITRAN, 2002).

Another negative effect of the public administration is its inability to make the necessary investments to keep up with technological advances. For example, the Port of Callao has neither cranes nor enough depth of water to allow berthing by large ships, despite handling 90% of the country's containerised cargo. It is calculated that the investment needed to modernise the principal Peruvian seaports exceeds US$270 millions (see ADEPSEP, 2002), an amount that the Treasury cannot afford.

Since mid-1980s, ENAPU has not supplied certain services exclusively. This has allowed private firms to increase their share in some port service markets, which, generally, are highly concentrated. For example, 5.5% of maritime agents represent 80% of operations at Callao, while 12% of stevedoring firms represent 70% of the market in Matarani. In other ports, the situation is similar.

Currently, the port service tariffs covers all of their costs, including those that could be covered by an independent access charge. Table A2 shows the access charges that at this moment are covered by the tariffs of wharfage, berthage and towage:

Table a2 Charges of access currently covered by tariffs of seaport services

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Flor, L., Defilippi, E. Port Infrastructure: An Access Model for the Essential Facility. Marit Econ Logist 5, 116–132 (2003). https://doi.org/10.1057/palgrave.mel.9100075

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1057/palgrave.mel.9100075

Keywords

Navigation