Skip to main content

Retail Investors and Disclosure Requirements

  • Chapter
  • First Online:
  • 2216 Accesses

Part of the book series: Economic Analysis of Law in European Legal Scholarship ((EALELS,volume 2))

Abstract

Disclosures are among the most common techniques introduced. The purpose of such regulation is to correct, for the benefit of the potential retail investor, information asymmetries relating to the characteristics of the financial products and the motivations of the intermediary advisor. The devil is in the detail, however, and it has become apparent that disclosing without assessing “how” to disclose may create unexpected and harmful side-effects. For this reason, there is a need for a research agenda centred around the limits deriving from motivation in the use of financial information and in good decision- making. This research design would disentangle connections between financial law and emotions and, in particular, financial law and happiness as well as financial law and altruism.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution.

Buying options

Chapter
USD   29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD   84.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Hardcover Book
USD   109.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Learn about institutional subscriptions

Notes

  1. 1.

    Chater et al. 2010.

  2. 2.

    See e.g., Barber 2005: past performance and the amount spent on marketing are the two main factors that account for the level of retail investment. The cost of management fees does not have an impact. See, however, the critical observations of Coates and Hubbard 2007.

  3. 3.

    Schiller 2012.

  4. 4.

    In a 2012 study, the American financial authority stressed that “American investors lack basic financial literacy”, see SEC 2012 report.

  5. 5.

    Chater et al. 2010.

  6. 6.

    See already Loewenstein et al. 2013.

  7. 7.

    Jovanovic 1982.

  8. 8.

    Coffee 1984.

  9. 9.

    A comprehensive accounting of costs, moreover, should include the time that people need to process the information, the opportunity costs of distracting attention from existing information, and even, in some cases, the hedonic cost of dealing with the information.

  10. 10.

    Ripken 2006.

  11. 11.

    Similarly, it does not require corporations to adopt a code of ethics for senior financial officers but, if no ethics code is adopted, requires corporations to disclose why they failed to do so.

  12. 12.

    Archong et al. 2013.

  13. 13.

    Beales et al. 1981: “[i]nformation remedies are most likely to be the most effective solution to information problems. They deal with the cause of the problem, rather than its symptoms, and leave the market maximum flexibility.”

  14. 14.

    Durkin and Elliehausen 2002, 109 et seq.

  15. 15.

    Durkin and Elliehausen 2002, 109 et seq.

  16. 16.

    It been understood that professional investors do fall into such traps see: Thaler Richard, Sunstein Cass. R. 2014, p. 124; Huang 2005, p. 501; Langevoort 1996; Hirshleifer and Shumway 2003, p. 1009.

  17. 17.

    “All human behavior can be viewed as involving participants who maximize their utility from a stable set of preferences and accumulate an optimal amount of information and other inputs in a variety of markets.” Becker 1976.

  18. 18.

    For a similar (mis)conception in the context of credit reporting, see, Staten and Cate 2004. Does the Fair Credit Reporting Act Promote Accurate Credit Reporting? Building Assets, Building Credit: A Symposium on Improving Financial Services in Low- Income Communities. See also Osovsky 2014.

  19. 19.

    Bowles and Gintis 2000, p. 1413.

  20. 20.

    “…Orthodox economic model of consumer behavior is, in essence, a model of robot-like experts. As such, it does a poor job of predicting the behavior of the average consumer. This is not because the average consumer is dumb, but rather that he does not spend all of his time thinking about how to make decisions.” Thaler 2000, p. 269 and 287.

  21. 21.

    See namely Oren 2008; Wright 2007; Camerer and Loewenstein 2004.

  22. 22.

    Sunstein 2011.

  23. 23.

    Hernstein et al. 1993, p. 149–185.

  24. 24.

    Fox et al. 2005, p. 197.

  25. 25.

    Secretary of the Treasury Paul O’Neill 2002. The State of Financial Literacy and Education in America: Hearing Before the S. Comm. on Banking, Housing, and Urban Affairs, 107th Cong. (testimony of Paul O’Neill, Secretary of the U.S. Department of the Treasury).

  26. 26.

    Willis 2008, p. 284.

  27. 27.

    See Willis 2008, p. 201.

  28. 28.

    US fin. Literacy & educ. Comm’n, taking ownership of the future: the national strategy for financial literacy at vii (2006).

  29. 29.

    Willis 2008, p. 207. Consumers with more education, more financial knowledge, and lower financial discount rates were found more likely to accept an offer of a brief, free credit-counseling session. See Meier and Sprenger 2007.

  30. 30.

    See Willis 2008, p. 205.

  31. 31.

    Willis 2008, p. 205.

  32. 32.

    Hershey et al. 1998, p. 467. See also Choi et al. 2006, p. 335–337. Employees who reported at the end of a retirement-investing seminar that they would increase their savings generally failed to do so.

  33. 33.

    See Anthes and Most 2000; Todd 2002.

  34. 34.

    Benartzi et al. 2007, p. 81.

  35. 35.

    For an overview of the literature of disclosure regulations and proposals see Marotta-Wurgler 2010.

  36. 36.

    See Iyengar and Lepper 2000, p. 996. (“[A]s both the number of options and the information about options increases, people tend to consider fewer choices and to process a smaller fraction of the overall information available regarding their choices…”) Agnew and Szykman 2005, p. 64–66. See also Issacharoff 2010.

  37. 37.

    Howells 2005, p.  363.

  38. 38.

    Hochhauser, Mark. Lost in the Fine Print: Readability of Financial Privacy Notices, at http://www.privacyrights.org/ar/GLB-Reading.htm.

  39. 39.

    Ben-Shahar and Schneider 2010.

  40. 40.

    Shiller 2003, p. 83–104. In addition, disclosure to regulators assist in their task of maintaining systemic stability.

  41. 41.

    For a review, see Spinnler 1991.

  42. 42.

    See namely, Gilovich et al. 2002; Kahneman 2011; Sunstein 2011, p. 1349.

  43. 43.

    Decision makers tend to be influenced by the way in which information is presented, e.g., test participants are more likely to opt for surgery if they are told that the ‘survival’ rate is 90 %, than they would if they are told that the mortality rate is 10 %.

  44. 44.

    Events coming immediately to mind (e.g., a recent financial market crash) are rated as more probable than events that are less mentally available.

  45. 45.

    A propensity to ignore probability all together when a decision is made under uncertainty.

  46. 46.

    A propensity to interpret information (or search for information) in a manner that confirms one’s preconceptions or hypothesis.

  47. 47.

    A preference for avoiding losses over making gains: e.g., test participants prefer to receive a sure EUR46 than have a 50 % chance of making EUR100 (whereas a logical rational agent would take the bet).

  48. 48.

    A propensity to avoid feelings of regret: money and time is invested in a project with dubious results rather than admitting mistake.

  49. 49.

    The tendency to overestimate pleasing outcomes.

  50. 50.

    The inclination to judge harmful actions as worse than equally harmful inactions.

  51. 51.

    Beshears et al. 2009.

  52. 52.

    Mercer et al. 2010.

  53. 53.

    Mercer et al. 2010.

  54. 54.

    It is modelled as an arousal biased competition for neuronal capacity: the BCM model.

  55. 55.

    Hertwig and Ortmann 2001.

  56. 56.

    Hüsser and Wirth 2013.

  57. 57.

    Beshears et al. 2009.

  58. 58.

    See Fischer and Wilkinson-Ryan 2014, p. 605.

  59. 59.

    Karlsson et al. 2009, p. 95–115. See also Sicherman et al. 2012. To Look or Not to Look: Financial Attention and Online Account Logins. Available at http://www8.gsb.columbia.edu/sites/financialstudies/files/files/financialattn.pdf.

  60. 60.

    Leventhal 1971, p. 1208–1224; Rogers 1975; Loeber et al. 2011, p. 292–298.

  61. 61.

    Sharot 2011.

  62. 62.

    Aghion, Philippe. La société de la défiance; Peyrefitte Alain 1995: the author describes how men tend to be “obsessed” with welfare when they perceive it is at risk (see spec. p. 401–402). By contrast the ethos of trust (“confiance”) enables men to build a more satisfactory society; trust cannot be imposed but is a result at the intersection of individual and social factors (self-confidence, confidence in others and in men as well as in God).

  63. 63.

    Experimental data collected by the author, forthcoming.

  64. 64.

    See Algan et al. 2012.

  65. 65.

    Yann et al. 2013.

  66. 66.

    Sah et al. 2012, 2013.

  67. 67.

    Sah et al. 2012, 2013.

  68. 68.

    In several of the experiments, advisees ended up being more likely to comply with the advice, even though they trusted it less.

  69. 69.

    Sah et al. 2012, 2013.

  70. 70.

    Rempel et al. 1985.

  71. 71.

    Locked 1996.

  72. 72.

    Johnson et al. 2005.

  73. 73.

    Non-profit organizations, such as the Consumer’s Checkbook (http://www.checkbook.org/) perform functions along this line.

  74. 74.

    Loewenstein et al. 2014.

  75. 75.

    Research conducted with the support of the Leverhulme Trust Fund.

Bibliography

  • Agnew, Julie R, and Lisa R Szykman. 2005. Asset allocation and information overload: The influence of information display, asset choice, and investor experience. The journal of Behavioral Finance 6 (57): 64–66.

    Google Scholar 

  • Algan, Yann, Pierre Cahuc, and André Zylberberg. 2012. La fabrique de la défiance. Paris: Albin Michel.

    Google Scholar 

  • Anthes, William L., and Bruce W Most. 2000. Frozen in the headlights: The dynamics of women and money. Journal of Financial Planning 13 (9): 130.

    Google Scholar 

  • Barber, Brad M., Terrance Odean, and Lu Zheng. 2005. Out of sight, out of mind: The effects of expenses on mutual funds flows. Journal of Business 78:2095.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Beales, Howard, et al. 1981. Information remedies for consumer protection. American Economic Review 71 (2): 410

    Google Scholar 

  • Becker Gary, S. 1976. The economic approach to human behavior.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ben-Shahar, Omri, and Carl E. Schneider. 2010. The failure of mandated disclosure, University of Chicago, The Law School John M. Olin Law & Economics Research Paper no. 516.

    Google Scholar 

  • Benartzi, Shlomo, and Richard H. Thaler. 2007. Heuristics and biases in retirement savings ­behavior. Journal of Economic Perspectives 21 (3): 81.

    Google Scholar 

  • Beshears, John, James Choi, David Laibson, and Brigitte Madrian. 2009. How does simplified disclosure affect individual’s mutual fund choices? NBER working paper no. 14859.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bowles, Samuel, and Herbert Gintis. 2000. Walrasian economics in retrospect. Quaterly Journal of Economics 115:1411–1413.

    Google Scholar 

  • Camerer, Colin F., and George Loewenstein. 2004. Behavioral economics: Past, present, future. In Advances in behavioral economics, ed. Colin F. Camerer et al. Princeton University Press and Russell Sage Foundation.

    Google Scholar 

  • Chater, Nick, Steffen Huck, and Roman Inderst. 2010. Consumer decision-making in retail investment services. a behavioural economics perspective. EU Report. http://ec.europa.eu/consumers/archive/strategy/docs/final_report_en.pdf. Accessed April 2014.

  • Choi, James J, et al. 2006. Saving for retirement on the path of least resistance. In Behavorial Public Finance 304:335–37. ed. Edward J. McCaffrey and Joel Slemrod. Russell Sage Foundation.

    Google Scholar 

  • Coates, John, and Glenn Hubbard. 2007. Competition in the mutual fund industry: Evidence and implications for policy. Harvard Law and Economics Discussion Paper no. 592.

    Google Scholar 

  • Coffee, John C. Jr. 1984. Market failure and the economic case for a mandatory disclosure system. Virginia Law Review. 70 (4): 717–753.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Durkin, Thomas, and Gregory Elliehausen. 2002. Disclosure as a consumer protection. In The impact of public policy on consumer credit, eds. Thomas A. Durkin and Michael E. Staten. Springer Science & Business Media (109, 110).

    Google Scholar 

  • Fischer, Jill E., and Tess Willkinson-Ryan. 2014. Why do retail investors make costly mistakes? An experiment on mutual fund choice. University of Pennsylvania Law Review 162:605.

    Google Scholar 

  • Fox, Jonathan et al. 2005. Building the case for financial education. Journal of Consumer Affairs 39 (1): 195–197.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fung, Archong, Mary Graham, and David Weil. 2013. Targeting transparency. Science 340 (6139): 1410–1411.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gilovich, Thomas, Dale Griffin, and Daniel Kahneman, eds. 2002. Heuristics and biases: The psychology of intuitive judgment. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hernstein, Richard, George Loewenstein, Drazen Prelec, and William Vaughan. 1993. Utility maximization and melioration: Internalities in individual choice. Journal of Behavior Decision Making 6:149–185.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hershey, Douglas A., et al. 1998. Challenges of training pre-retirees to make sound financial planning decisions. Educational Gerontology 24:447–467.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hertwig, Ralph, and Andreas Ortmann. 2001. Experimental practices in economics: A methodological challenge for psychologists? Behavioral and Brain Sciences 24:383–451.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hirshleifer, David A., and Tyler Shumway. 2003. Good day sunshine: Stock returns and the weather. Journal of Finance 58:1009.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Howells, Geraint. 2005. The potential and limits of consumer empowerment by information. Journal of Law and Society 32 (3): 349–363.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Huang, Peter H. 2005. Regulating irrational exuberance and anxiety in securities markets. In The law and economics of irrational behaviour, ed. Francesco Parisi and Vernon L. Smith, 501. San Francisco: Stanford Economics and Finance.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hüsser, Andreas, and Werner Wirth. 2013. Gravitation toward prior performance in mutual fund advertisings: Do consumer investors’ processing abilities account for biased information processing? The Journal of Consumer Affairs 47 (Summer 2013): 219–242.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Issacharoff, Samuel. 2010. Disclosure, Agents and Consumer Protection, New York University Law and Economics Working Papers, Paper 228.

    Google Scholar 

  • Iyengar, Sheena S., and Mark R. Lepper. 2000. When choice is demotivating: Can one desire too much of a good thing? Journal of Personality and Social Psychology 79:995–996.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Johnson, Devon, and Kent Grayson. 2005. Cognitive and affective trust in service relationships. Journal of Business Research 58:500–507.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jovanovic, Boyan. 1982. Truthful disclosure of information. The Bell Journal of Economics 13 (1): 36–44.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kahneman, Daniel. 2011. Thinking, fast and slow. Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Karlsson, Niklas, George Loewenstein, and Duane Seppi. 2009. The ostrich effect: Selective avoidance of information. Journal of Risk and Uncertainty 38 (2): 95–115.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Langevoort, Donald C. 1996. Selling hope, selling risk: Some lessons for law from behavioral economics about stockbrokers and sophisticated customers. California Law Review 84 (627): 682–685.

    Google Scholar 

  • Leventhal, Howard. 1971. Fear, appeals and persuasion: The differentiation of a motivational construct. American Journal of Public. Health 61:1208–1224.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Locked, Karen. 1996. A funny thing happened! The management of consumer emotions in service encounters. Organization Science 7 (1): 40–59.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Loeber, Sabine, Sabine Vollstadt-Klein, Sophia Wilden, Sven Schneider, and Christine Rockenbach. 2011. The effect of pictorial warnings on cigarette packages on attentional bias of smokers. Pharmacology Biochemistry and Behavior 98 (2): 292–98.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Loewestein, George, Cass. R. Sunstein, and Robert Golman. 2013. Disclosure: Psychology changes everything. Annual Review of Economics 6:391–419.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Marotta-Wurgler, Florencia. 2010. Does disclosure matter? NYU Center for Law, Economics and Organization, Working Paper No. 10–54.

    Google Scholar 

  • Meier, Stephan, and Charles Sprenger. 2007. Selection into financial literacy programs: Evidence from a field study 10–13 (Fed. Reserve Bank of Boston, Public Policy Discussion Paper No. 07–5).

    Google Scholar 

  • Mercer, Molly, Alan Palmiter, and Ahmed Taha. 2010. Worthless warnings? Testing the effectiveness of disclaimers in mutual fund advertisements. Journal of Empirical Legal Studies 7 (3): 429–459.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Oren, Bar-Gill. 2008. The behavioral economics of consumer contracts. Minnesota Law Review 92:749.

    Google Scholar 

  • Osovsky, Adi. 2014. The misconception of the consumer as homo economicus: A behavioral economic approach to consumer protection in the credit reporting system (working paper available on SSRN).

    Google Scholar 

  • Peyrefitte, Alain. 1995. La société de confiance. Paris: Odile Jacob.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rempel, John K., John G. Holmes, and Mark P. Zanna. 1985. Trust in close relationships. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology 49 (1): 95–112.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ripken, Susanna. 2006. The dangers and drawbacks of the disclosure antidote: Toward a more substantive approach to securities regulation. Baylor Law Review 58 (1): 139–204.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rogers, Ronald W. 1975. A protection motivation theory of fear appeals and attitude change. Journal of Psychology 91 (1): 93–114.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sah, Sunita, George Loewenstein, and Daylian Cain. 2012. The burden of disclosure: Increased compliance with distrusted advice. Journal of Personality and social Psychology: Interpersonal Rel. and Group Processes 104 (2): 289–304.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sah, Sunita, George Loewenstein, and Daylian Cain. 2013. Insinuation anxiety: increased pressure to follow less trusted advice after disclosure of a conflict of interest. http://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=1970961. Accessed April 2014.

  • Schiller, Robert. 2012. Finance and the good society. Princeton: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Secretary of the Treasury Paul O’Neill. 2002. The State of Financial Literacy and Education in America: Hearing Before the S. Comm. on Banking, Housing, and Urban Affairs, 107th Cong. (testimony of Paul O’Neill, Secretary of the U.S. Department of the Treasury).

    Google Scholar 

  • Sharot, Tara. 2011. The optimistic bias. Pantheon.

    Google Scholar 

  • Shiller, Robert. 2003. From efficient markets to behavioral finance. Journal of Economic Perspectives 17 (1): 83–104.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sicherman, Nachum, George Loewenstein, Duane Seppi, and Stephen Utkus. 2012. To Look or Not to Look: Financial Attention and Online Account Logins. http://www8.gsb.columbia.edu/sites/financialstudies/files/files/financialattn.pdf. Accessed April 2014.

  • Staten Michael E., and Fred H. Cate. 2004. Does the fair credit reporting act promote accurate credit reporting? Building assets, building credit: A symposium on improving financial services in low-income communities.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sunstein, Cass. 2011. Empirically informed regulation University of Chicago Law Review 78:1349.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sunstein, Cass. 2014. Nanny statecraft. Yale: Yale University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Thaler, Richard H. 2000. Toward a positive theory of consumer choice. In Choices, values, and frames, ed. Daniel Kahneman and Amos Tversky, 269–287. Yale: Cambride University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Thaler, Richard, and Cass R Sunstein. 2008. Nudge: Improving decisions about health, wealth, and happiness. Princeton: Yale University Press, at 124.

    Google Scholar 

  • Todd, Richard M. 2002. Financial literacy education: A potential tool for reducing predatory lending? The Region (Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis) 16:6.

    Google Scholar 

  • Willis, Lauren E. 2008. Against financial literacy education, Iowa Law Review 94:197, 22§-27, at 284.

    Google Scholar 

  • Wright, Joshua D. 2007. Behavioral law and economics, paternalism, and consumer contracts: An empirical perspective. NYU Journal of Law and Liberty 2:470.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Geneviève Helleringer .

Editor information

Editors and Affiliations

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2015 Springer International Publishing Switzerland

About this chapter

Cite this chapter

Helleringer, G. (2015). Retail Investors and Disclosure Requirements. In: Mathis, K. (eds) European Perspectives on Behavioural Law and Economics. Economic Analysis of Law in European Legal Scholarship, vol 2. Springer, Cham. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-319-11635-8_10

Download citation

Publish with us

Policies and ethics