Skip to main content

Reflexivity of Anticipations in Economics and Political Economy

  • Living reference work entry
  • First Online:
Handbook of Anticipation

Abstract

When the social reality is changing, we need to know also the following: What exactly is changing and why? To what extent is reflexivity involved in changes that take part in making the future uncertain and open? For instance, an announced policy change can become a self-altering prediction (or involve such a prediction), which is subject to contradictory and complementary determination, resulting either in net self-fulfilling or self-denying tendency. I approach these questions also by analyzing two significant real-world historical examples, the Euro crisis and global financial crises. Both examples involve reflexive predictions, reflexive feedback loops, and performativity. What I find particularly striking is how the capitalist market economy – with all the historical shifts and changes in its institutions, regulations, and political structures – has managed to retain at least some of its recurrent economic patterns. Further, I examine the general methodological problem of the absence of decisive tests between theories. This has consequences: normative and ideological positions evolve easily and tend to fortify themselves rapidly; and actors can modify, perhaps inadvertently, their public anticipations in line with their interests or normative aims. In the final section, I argue that the main aim of social sciences is not to predict accurately but to bring about desirable outcomes, explaining how to move from strategic actions and reflexive ideologies to emancipation.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Institutional subscriptions

References

  • Alker, H. (1996). Rediscoveries and reformulations. Humanistic methodologies for international studies. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Apel, K. (2001). The response of discourse ethics to the moral challenge of the human situation as such and especially today. Leuven: Peeters.

    Google Scholar 

  • Atkinson, A., & Brandolini, A. (2009). On data: A case study of the evolution of income inequality across time and across countries. Cambridge Journal of Economics, 3(3), 381–404.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Barro, R. (1974). Are government bonds net wealth? Journal of Political Economy, 82(6), 1095–1117.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bhaskar, R. (1998). The possibility of naturalism. A philosophical critique of the contemporary human sciences (3rd ed.). London/New York: Routledge.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bigo, V., & Negru, I. (2014). Mathematical modelling in the wake of the crisis: A blessing or a curse? What does the economics profession say? Cambridge Journal of Economics, 38(2), 329–347.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bronk, R. (2013). Reflexivity unpacked: Performativity, uncertainty and analytical monocultures. Journal of Economic Methodology, 20(4), 343–349.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Centre for Research on Multinational Corporations. (2011). Newsletter – EU financial reforms, part of the project towards a global finance system at the Service of Sustainable Development. http://somo.nl/dossiers-en/sectors/financial/eu-financial-reforms/newsletters.

  • Chao, H. (2000). Milton Friedman and the emergence of the permanent income hypothesis, LSE Centre for Philosophy of Natural and Social Science Measurement in Physics and Economics, Technical report 9/2000. http://www.lse.ac.uk/CPNSS/pdf/DP withCoverMeasurement/Meas-DP%2009%2000.pdf.

  • Chick, V., & Dow, S. (2005). The meaning of open systems. Journal of Economic Methodology, 12(3), 363–381.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Clements, M. P., & Hendry, D. F. (1999). On winning forecasting competitions in economics. Spanish Economic Review, 1(2), 123–160.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Council of the European Union. (2012). Treaty on stability, coordination, and governance in the economic and monetary union. https://www.consilium.europa.eu/media/20399/st00tscg26_en12.pdf.

  • Courakis, A. (Ed.). (1981). Inflation, depression, and economic policy in the west. Totowa: Barnes & Noble Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Dequech, D. (2011). Uncertainty: A typology and refinements of existing concepts. Journal of Economic Issues, 45(3), 621–640.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Duesenberry, J. S. (1949). Income, saving and the theory of consumer behaviour. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • European Commission. (2018). Spring 2018 Economic Forecast – Statistical annex. https://ec.europa.eu/info/files/economy-finance/spring-2018-economic-forecast-statistical-annex_en.

  • Fama, E. (1970). Efficient capital markets: A review of theory and empirical work. Journal of Finance, 25(2), 383–417.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Friedman, M. (1957). A theory of the consumption function. Princeton: Princeton University Press. http://papers.nber.org/books/frie57-1.

  • Giddens, A. (1979). Central problems in social theory. Los Angeles: University of California Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Goodhart, C. (1981). Problems of monetary management: The U.K. experience. In A. S. Courakis (Ed.), Inflation, depression, and economic policy in the west (pp. 111–146). Totowa: Barnes & Noble Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gordon, R. J. (1976). Can econometric policy evaluations be salvaged? – A comment. Carnegie-Rochester Conference Series on Public Policy, 1, 47–61.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Grunberg, E., & Modigliani, F. (1954). The predictability of social events. Journal of Political Economy, 62(6), 465–478.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Habermas, J. (1990). Moral consciousness and communicative action (trans: Lenhardt, C., & Nicholsen, S.W.). Cambridge, MA: The MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hendry, D. F. (1983). On Keynesian model building and the rational expectations critique: A question of methodology. Cambridge Journal of Economics, 7, 69–75.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hendry, D. F. (1985). Monetary economic myth and econometric reality. Oxford Review of Economic Policy, 1(1), 72–84.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hendry, D. F. (1997). The econometrics of macroeconomic forecasting. Economic Journal, 107(444), 1330–1357.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Henshel, R. L. (1993). Do self-fulfilling prophecies improve or degrade predictive accuracy? How sociology and economics can disagree and both be right. The Journal of Socio-Economics, 22(2), 85–104.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Herman, E. S. (1995). Triumph of the market: Essays on economics, politics and the media. Boston: South End Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • International Monetary Fund. (2016). Global financial stability report – Fostering stability in a low-growth, low-rate era. Washington, DC: International Monetary Fund.

    Google Scholar 

  • International Monetary Fund. (2017). Global financial stability report: Is growth at risk? Washington, DC: International Monetary Fund.

    Google Scholar 

  • International Monetary Fund. (2018). Global financial stability report: A bumpy road ahead. Washington, DC: International Monetary Fund.

    Google Scholar 

  • Keynes, J. M. 1961/1936. The general theory of employment, interest and money. London: Macmillan.

    Google Scholar 

  • Keynes, J. M. 2008/1920. A treatise on probability. London: Rough Draft Printing/MacMillan.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kindleberger, C. (1978). Manias, panics, and crashes: A history of financial crises. London: Macmillan.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Lagerspetz, E. (1988). Reflexive predictions and strategic actions. Social Science Information, 27(2), 307–320.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lawson, T. (1997). Economics and reality. London: Routledge.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Lawson, T. (2015). The nature and state of modern economics. London: Routledge.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Lucas, R. E. (1972). Expectations and the neutrality of money. Journal of Economic Theory, 4(2), 103–124.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lucas, R. E. (1976). Econometric policy evaluation: A critique. In K. Brunner & A. Meltzer (Eds.), The Phillips curve and labor markets (pp. 19–46). Amsterdam: North Holland Publishing Company.

    Google Scholar 

  • MacKenzie, D. (2006). An engine, not a camera: Finance theory and the making of markets. Cambridge: MIT Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • MacKenzie, D., Muniesa, F., & Siu, L. (2007). Do economist make markets? On the performativity of economics. Princeton: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mackinnon, L. (2005). Ideational reflexivity in economic systems. In L. Mackinnon (Ed.), The social construction of economic man: The genesis, spread, impact and institutionalisation of economic ideas. Unpublished doctoral dissertation, University of Queensland, Brisbane, Ch 11. https://espace.library.uq.edu.au/view/UQ:8777

  • Martins, N. O. (2018). Critical realism, economics, and heterodox economics. In F. S. Lee, B. Cronin, & E. Elgar (Eds.), Handbook of research methods and applications in heterodox economics (pp. 222–236). Cheltenham/Northampton: Edward Elgar Publishing.

    Google Scholar 

  • Merton, R. K. (1948). The self-fulfilling prophecy. The Antioch Review, 8(2), 193–210.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Minsky, H. (1982). Can “it” happen again? Essays on instability and finance. Armonk: M.E. Sharpe.

    Google Scholar 

  • Minsky, H. (2008). Stabilizing and unstable economy (2nd ed.). New York: McGraw Hill.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mirowski, P. (2014). Never let a serious crisis go to waste. How neoliberalism survived the financial meltdown. London: Verso.

    Google Scholar 

  • Morgan, J. (2015). Is economics responding to critique? What do the UK 2015 QAA subject benchmarks indicate? Review of Political Economy, 27(4), 518–538.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nasir, A., & Morgan, J. (2018). The unit root problem: Affinities between ergodicity and stationarity, its practical contradictions for central Bank policy, and some consideration of alternatives. Journal of Post Keynesian Economics, first online 10 Apr 2018, https://doi.org/10.1080/01603477.2017.1387060.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Palley, T. I. (2013). Financialization: What it is and why it matters. In Financialization (pp. 17–40). London: Palgrave Macmillan.

    Google Scholar 

  • Patomäki, H. (2001). Democratising globalisation. The leverage of the Tobin tax. London: Zed Books.

    Google Scholar 

  • Patomäki, H. (2002). After international relations. Critical realism and the (re)construction of world politics. London/New York: Routledge.

    Google Scholar 

  • Patomäki, H. (2006). Global justice: A democratic perspective. Globalizations, 3(2), 99–120.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Patomäki, H. (2010). What next? An explanation of the 2008-9 slump and two scenarios of the shape of things to come. Globalizations, 7(1), 67–84.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Patomäki, H. (2013). The great eurozone disaster: From crisis to global new deal. London/New York: Zed Books.

    Google Scholar 

  • Patomäki, H. (2017). Capitalism: Competition, conflict, crisis. Journal of Critical Realism, 16(5), 537–543.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Patomäki, H. (2018). Disintegrative tendencies in global political economy: Exits and conflicts. London/New York: Routledge.

    Google Scholar 

  • Patomäki, H. (forthcoming). The ideal of competitive markets. On the social psychology and politics of neoclassical theory, resubmitted after major revisions to Cambridge Journal of Economics in June 2018, pending for final decision.

    Google Scholar 

  • Perelman, C. (1963). The idea of justice and the problem of argument. London: Routledge & Kegan Paul.

    Google Scholar 

  • Pratten, S. (2005). Economics as progress: The LSE approach to econometric modelling and critical realism as programmes for research. Cambridge Journal of Economics, 29(2), 179–205.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rawls, J. (1971). A theory of justice. The original edition. Cambridge, MA: The Belknap Press of Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Reid, J., Nicol, C., Burns, N., & Chanda, S. (2017). Long-term asset return study: The next financial crisis. London: Deutsche Bank Markets Research.

    Google Scholar 

  • Robinson, J. (1980). Time in economic theory. Kyklos, 33(2), 219–229.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sargent, T., & Wallace, N. (1975). “Rational” expectations, the optimal monetary instrument and the optimal money supply rule. Journal of Political Economy, 83(2), 231–254.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sayer, A. (2011). Why things matter to people. Social science, values and ethical life. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Schumpeter, J. (1939). Business cycles (Vol. 1). New York/London: McGraw-Hill.

    Google Scholar 

  • Schweickart, D. (1993). A democratic theory of economic exploitation dialectically developed. In R. Gottlieb (Ed.), Radical philosophy. Tradition, counter-tradition, politics (pp. 101–122). Philadelphia: Temple University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Shaikh, A. (2013). On the role of reflexivity in economic analysis. Journal of Economic Methodology, 20(4), 439–445.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Shaikh, A. (2016). Capitalism: Competition, conflict, crises. New York: Oxford University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Simon, H. A. (1954). Bandwagon and underdog effects and the possibility of election predictions. Public Opinion Quarterly, 18(3), 245–253.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sims, C. A., Goldfeld, S. M., & Sachs, J. D. (1982). Policy analysis with econometric models. Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 1982(1), 107–164.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Soros, G. (1998). The crisis of global capitalism: Open society endangered. London: Little, Brown.

    Google Scholar 

  • Soros, G. (2008). The crash of 2008 and what it means: The new paradigm for financial markets. Melbourne: Scribe.

    Google Scholar 

  • Soros, G. (2013). Fallibility, reflexivity, and the human uncertainty principle. Journal of Economic Methodology, 20(4), 309–329.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Stiglitz, J. E. (2010). Lessons from the global financial crisis of 2008. Seoul Journal of Economics, 23(3), 321–339. https://www8.gsb.columbia.edu/faculty/jstiglitz/sites/jstiglitz/files/2010_Lessons_Global_Financial_Crisis_Seoul.pdf.

  • Van der Zwan, N. (2014). Making sense of financialization. Socio-Economic Review, 12(1), 99–129.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wilcox, D. (1989). Social security benefits, consumption expenditure, and the life cycle hypothesis. Journal of Political Economy, 97(2), 288–304.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Heikki Patomäki .

Editor information

Editors and Affiliations

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2019 Springer Nature Switzerland AG

About this entry

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this entry

Patomäki, H. (2019). Reflexivity of Anticipations in Economics and Political Economy. In: Poli, R. (eds) Handbook of Anticipation. Springer, Cham. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-319-31737-3_16-1

Download citation

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-319-31737-3_16-1

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Publisher Name: Springer, Cham

  • Print ISBN: 978-3-319-31737-3

  • Online ISBN: 978-3-319-31737-3

  • eBook Packages: Springer Reference Religion and PhilosophyReference Module Humanities and Social SciencesReference Module Humanities

Publish with us

Policies and ethics