Skip to main content

The Role of (Quasi) Analyticity in Establishing Completeness of Financial Markets Equilibria

  • Chapter
  • First Online:
Social Design

Part of the book series: Studies in Economic Design ((DESI))

  • 532 Accesses

Abstract

Existence of equilibrium in a continuous-time securities market in which the securities are endogenously dynamically complete has been proved only recently. Given the fundamental nature of this result various extensions have been proposed. In the present paper we prove all results under optimal condition. Namely, we only assume quasi-analyticity rather than analyticity of the basic economic ingredients, and we prove everything based solely on this hypothesis.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Chapter
USD 29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD 129.00
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Hardcover Book
USD 169.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Notes

  1. 1.

    Some of the results in Kramkov and Predoiu (2014) and in the supplement of Hugonnier et al. (2012) are obtained using only time analyticity. However, as stated in Kramkov and Predoiu (2014), their assumption on the terminal condition is stronger. Such extensions are treated with our method in a forthcoming paper.

  2. 2.

    Actually, to pass from separate analyticity in space and time variables one needs a stronger form of real analyticity, involving, e.g., suitable local extendibility such as in Hugonnier et al. (2012).

References

  • Anderson, R. M., & Raimondo, R. C. (2008). Equilibrium in continuous-time financial markets: Endogenously dynamically complete markets. Econometrica, 76(4), 841–907.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bierstone, E., & Milman, P. D. (2004). Resolution of singularities in Denjoy-Carleman Classes. Selecta Mathematica 10(1), 1–28.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Borel, E. (1901). Sur les séries depolynomes et de fractions rationnelles. Acta Mathematica, 24, 309–382.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Browning, M., Hansen, L. P., & Heckman, J. J. (1999). Micro data and general equilibrium models. In J. B. Taylor & M. Woodford (Eds.), Handbook of macroeconomics (vol. 1, Part A, pp. 543–633). Amsterdam: Elsevier.

    Google Scholar 

  • Dana, R. A. (1993). Existence and uniqueness of equilibria when preferences are additively separable. Econometrica, 61, 953–957.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dana, R. A., & Jeanblanc, M. (2002). Financial markets in continuous time. Springer: Berlin.

    Google Scholar 

  • Duffie, D. (1986). Stochastic equilibria: Existence, spanning number and the ‘No Expected Financial Gain From Trade’ hypothesis. Econometrica, 54, 1161–1183

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Duffie, D., & Huang, C.-F. (1985). Implementing arrow–debreu equilibria by continuous trading of few long–lived securities. Econometrica, 53, 1337–1356

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hörmander, L. (1990). The analysis of linear partial differential operators I (2nd edn.). Berlin: Springer.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hugonnier, J., Malamud, S., & Trubowitz, E. (2012). Endogenous completeness of diffusion driven equilibrium markets. Econometrica, 80, 1249–1270. Supplement: In econometrica supplementary material.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kannai, Y., & Raimondo, R. C. (2013). Quasi-analytic solutions of linear parabolic equations. Journal d’ Analyse Mathematique, 119, 115–145

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Karatzas, I., & Shreve, S. (1998). Methods of mathematical finance. New York: Springer.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Kramkov, D., & Predoiu, S. (2014). Integral representation of martingales motivated by the problem of endogenous completeness in financial models. Stochastic Processes and Their Applications, 124, 81–100.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Merton, R. C. (1973). An intertemporal capital asset pricing model. Econometrica, 41, 867–887.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Merton, R. C. (1990). A complete-markets general equlibrium theory of finance in continuous time. In R. C. Merton (Ed.), Continuous-time finance (chap. 16). Cambridge: Basil Blackwell. 524–576.

    Google Scholar 

  • Negishi, T. (1960). Welfare economics and existence of an equilibrium for a competitive economy. Metroeconomica, 12, 92–97.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Radner, R. (1972). Existence of equilibrium of planes, prices and price expectations in a sequence of markets. Econometrica, 40, 289–303.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Riedel, F., & Herzberg, F. (2013). Existence of financial equilibria in continuous time with potentially complete markets. Journal of Mathematical Economics, 49, 398–404.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tanabe, H. (1979). Equations of evolution. London: Pitman.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

Raimondo’s work was supported by grant DP0558187 from the Australian Research Council.

Parts of the research reported on in this paper were performed while Y. K. was visiting the University of Melbourne.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Yakar Kannai .

Editor information

Editors and Affiliations

Appendices

Appendix 1: Quasi-Analytic Functions of Several Variables

In this Appendix, we summarize the results on quasi-analytic functions of several variables used in our proofs.

Let the sequence of positive numbers \(\left \{ M_{k}\right \} _{k=0}^{\infty }\) satisfy the following conditions (see Tanabe, 1979): there exist positive numbers d 0, d 1, and d 2 such that

Let Ω be an open subset of \( \mathbb {R} ^{n}\). We denote by \(\mathcal {D}(\Omega ,\left \{ M_{k}\right \} )\) the set of all infinitely differentiable functions u defined on Ω such that for each compact set \(\mathfrak {K}\subset \Omega \) there exist positive constants C 0 and C so that for every multi-index α we have the inequality

$$\displaystyle \begin{aligned} \max_{x\in \mathfrak{K}}\left\vert D^{\alpha }u(x)\right\vert \leq C_{0}C^{\left\vert \alpha \right\vert }M_{\left\vert \alpha \right\vert }. {} \end{aligned} $$
(12)

The class \(\mathcal {D}(\Omega ,\left \{ k!\right \} )\) coincides with the class of real analytic functions on Ω. A class \(\mathcal {D}\) of functions defined on Ω is said to be quasi-analytic if the only function u in the class \(\mathcal {D}\) such that D α u(x 0) = 0 for all α for a fixed x 0 ∈ Ω is the identically zero function, u ≡ 0. It is well-known (Carleman-Denjoy Theorem) (see Hörmander, 1990 and Tanabe, 1979) that the class \( \mathcal {D}(\Omega ,\left \{ M_{k}\right \} )\) is quasi-analytic if and only if \(\sum _{k=0}^{\infty }\left ( M_{k}\right ) ^{-\frac {1}{k}}=\infty .\) The sequence \(M_{k}=\left ( k\log k\right ) ^{k}\) determines a non-real analytic, but a quasi-analytic, class and satisfies Q1 − Q5. The following class of functions which are nowhere real analytic in the real line but are nevertheless determined uniquely by the values of all the derivatives at one point was given by Borel (1901):

$$\displaystyle \begin{aligned} g(x)=\sum_{q=1}^{\infty }\sum_{p=-\infty }^{\infty }\sum_{p^{\prime }=-\infty }^{\infty }\frac{\varphi (p,p^{\prime },q^{\prime })}{x+i\sqrt{2}- \frac{p+ip^{\prime }}{q}} \end{aligned} $$

with

$$\displaystyle \begin{aligned} \left\vert \varphi (p,p^{\prime },q^{\prime })\right\vert <e^{-e^{p^{8}+p^{\prime 8}+q^{8}}} \end{aligned} $$

and the coefficients φ(p, p , q )s are nowhere zero (for real functions consider the class \(f(x)=\left \vert g(x)\right \vert ^{2}).\)

Note the well-known facts that if \(f\in \mathcal {D}(\Omega ,\left \{ M_{k}\right \} )\) then \(D^{\alpha }f\in \mathcal {D}(\Omega ,\left \{ M_{k}\right \} )\) for any α, and if \(f,g\in \mathcal {D}(\Omega ,\left \{ M_{k}\right \} )\) then the product \(f\cdot g\in \mathcal {D}(\Omega ,\left \{ M_{k}\right \} ).\) We are going to make a constant use of these facts.

Quasi-analytic functions of several variables have been studied extensively in Bierstone and Milman (2004). They prove an implicit function theorem for quasi-analytic functions.

Theorem 5 (The Quasi-Analytic Implicit Function Theorem)

Suppose that U is open in R n ×R p (with product coordinates (x, y) = (x 1, …, x n, y 1, …, y p)). Suppose that f 1, …, f p are quasi-analytic, (a, b) ∈ U, f(a, b) = 0 and

$$\displaystyle \begin{aligned} (\partial f/\partial y)(a,b) \end{aligned}$$

is invertible, where f = (f1, …, fp). Then there is a product neighborhood V × W of (a, b) in U and a quasi–analytic mapping g : V  W such that g(a) = b and

$$\displaystyle \begin{aligned} f\left( x,g(x)\right) =0\mathit{\ }\forall x\in V. \end{aligned}$$

The main subject of Bierstone and Milman (2004) is proving the possibility of resolution of singularities for quasi-analytic functions. As observed in Bierstone and Milman (2004, Corollary 5.13), if U is an open set in R n and f : U →R is quasi-analytic, then for every x 0 ∈ U, there exists a neighborhood \(V_{x_{0}}\) of x 0 such that either F(x) = 0 for all \(x\in V_{x_{0}}\) or \(\{x\in \mathcal {V}_{x_{0}}:F(x)=0\}\) is a finite union of quasi-analytic varieties of dimension < n. From this follows the following

Corollary 6

Let \(\mathcal {O}\subset {\mathbf {R}}^{n}\) be open and convex, \(f:\mathcal {O}\rightarrow \mathbf {R}\) is quasi-analytic. If \(\{x\in \mathcal {O}:f(x)=0\}\) has positive Lebesgue measure, then f is identically zero on \(\mathcal {O}\).

Proof

If f(x) = 0 for all \(x\in \mathcal {V}_{x_{0}}\) and \(y\in \mathcal {O}\), there is a ray that passes through \(\mathcal {V}_{x_{0}}\) then the function f has to vanish identically on the connected set \(\mathcal {O}\). On the other hand, if \( \{x\in \mathcal {V}_{x_{0}}:f(x)=0\}\) is a finite union of quasi-analytic varieties of dimension < n, \(\{x\in \mathcal {V}_{x_{0}}:F(x)=0\}\) has Lebesgue measure zero. There is a countable collection {x n : n ∈N} such that \(\cup _{n\in \mathbf {N}}\mathcal {V}_{x_{n}}\supset U\), so {x ∈ U : f(x) = 0} has Lebesgue measure zero. \(\blacksquare \)

Quasi-analyticity of solutions of parabolic partial differential equations such as those that are satisfied by securities prices has been obtained recently in Kannai and Raimondo (2013) in a form sufficient for establishing dynamic completeness. The relevant definitions and assumptions are stated explicitly in the cited paper.

Theorem 7

Let f(t, x) ∈ \(\mathcal {D}( \mathbb {R} ^{n\mathit{}}\times \left ( 0,T\right ) ,\left \{ M_{k}\right \} )\) , \(u_{0}(x)\in L_{\mathit{\text{loc}}}^{1}( \mathbb {R} ^{n})\) be such that for every δ > 0

$$\displaystyle \begin{aligned} \int \left\vert u_{0}(x)\right\vert \exp \left( -\delta \sum_{i=1}^{n}\left\vert x_{i}\right\vert ^{\frac{m}{m-1}}\right) dx<\infty , {} \end{aligned} $$
(13)

and there exist constants C 0, C such that

$$\displaystyle \begin{aligned} \int \left\vert \left( \frac{\partial }{\partial t}\right) ^{k}f(t,x)\right\vert \exp \left( -\delta \sum_{i=1}^{n}\left\vert x_{i}\right\vert ^{\frac{m}{m-1}}\right) dx<C_{0}C^{k}M_{k} {} \end{aligned} $$
(14)

uniformly in \(\left [ 0,T\right ] ,\) for every non-negative integer k. Let A satisfy the assumptions of Lemma 3 of Kannai and Raimondo ( 2013 ). Then the solution u(t, x) of the differential equation

$$\displaystyle \begin{aligned} \frac{\partial u}{\partial t}+Au=f \end{aligned} $$
(15)

with the initial condition

$$\displaystyle \begin{aligned} u(x,0)=u_{0}\end{aligned} $$
(16)

given by the formula

$$\displaystyle \begin{aligned} u(x,t)=\int_{ \mathbb{R} ^{n\mathit{}}}U(x,t,y,0)u_{0}(y)dy+\int_{0}^{t}\int_{ \mathbb{R} ^{n\mathit{}}}U(x,t,y,s)f(s,y)dyds\end{aligned} $$
(17)

is quasi-analytic in \( \mathbb {R} ^{n}\times \left ( 0,T\right ) \).

Observe that in our case m = 2.

Appendix 2: Sketch of Proof of Main Theorem

Proof

Here we only sketch the proof, as it follows the one in Anderson and Raimondo (2008), emphasizing only the points where we differ. In order to prove existence we observe that (see Dana, 1993) the consumption is given by the solution of the social planner’s problem

$$\displaystyle \begin{aligned} \max_{\sum_{i=1,..,I}c_{i}\leq e}\sum_{i=1}^{I}\lambda _{i}U_{i}(c_{i}), \end{aligned}$$

where the parameters λ i are Negishi weights. Since we have von Neumann-Morgenstern utility functions the solution is equivalent to the solutions of the problem state-by-state. Therefore the solution is given by

$$\displaystyle \begin{aligned} u(\lambda _{1},\ldots,\lambda _{I},t,x)=\max_{\sum_{i=1,..,I}x_{i}\leq x}\sum_{i=1}^{I}\lambda _{i}h_{i}(t,x_{i})\end{aligned} $$

and this is equivalent to the solution of the following (Lagrange multipliers) system

$$\displaystyle \begin{aligned} \left\{ \begin{array}{cc} \lambda _{1}\frac{\partial h_{1}}{\partial c} & =\widetilde{\mu } \\ \lambda _{2}\frac{\partial h_{2}}{\partial c} & =\widetilde{\mu } \\ \vdots & \\ \lambda _{I}\frac{\partial h_{I}}{\partial c} & =\widetilde{\mu } \\ \sum_{i=1,..,I}x_{i} & =x \end{array} \right. \end{aligned}$$

The Implicit Function Theorem of Bierstone and Milman (2004, see theorem 5 in Appendix 1) implies that there exist quasi-analytic functions \(x_{1},\ldots ,x_{I},\widetilde {\mu }\) which are solutions of the system and this implies, by a well-known result (Dana, 1993), that

$$\displaystyle \begin{aligned} \left( c_{1},\ldots,c_{I},p_{C}\right) =\left( x_{1}(t,e),\ldots,c_{I}(t,e), \widetilde{\mu }(t,e)\right) \end{aligned}$$

is a contingent Arrow Debreu equilibrium with quasi-analytic data, in particular the relative price of consumption at equilibrium p C(t, x) is quasi-analytic. It follows that the securities prices \(p_{A}(t,X)=\left ( p_{A_{0}}(t,X),\ldots ,p_{A_{K}}(t,X)\right ) \) are given by the expectations (8) and satisfy the partial differential equation (2) with the final condition

$$\displaystyle \begin{aligned} p_{Aj}(T,x)=D_{j}(T,X(T))p_{C}(T,x) {} \end{aligned} $$
(18)

and Theorem 7 of Appendix 1 applies. Hence the security prices are quasi-analytic.

Finally quasi-analyticity and non-degeneracy of the dispersion of the final lump dividend (7), together with corollary (6), imply the non-degeneracy of the price dispersion matrix. Hence (see Karatzas and Shreve, 1998) the equilibrium is dynamically complete. \(\blacksquare \)

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2019 Springer Nature Switzerland AG

About this chapter

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this chapter

Kannai, Y., Raimondo, R.C. (2019). The Role of (Quasi) Analyticity in Establishing Completeness of Financial Markets Equilibria. In: Trockel, W. (eds) Social Design. Studies in Economic Design. Springer, Cham. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-319-93809-7_11

Download citation

Publish with us

Policies and ethics