Skip to main content

Elasticities of Substitution

  • Living reference work entry
  • First Online:
Handbook of Production Economics

Abstract

This chapter lays out the theoretical foundation of the measurement of the degree of substitutability among inputs utilized in a production process. It proceeds from the well-settled (Hicksian) notion of this measure for two inputs (typically labor and capital) to the more challenging conceptualization for technologies with more than two inputs (most notably, Allen-Uzawa and Morishima elasticities). Dual elasticities of substitution (also called elasticities of complementarity) and gross elasticities of substitution (measuring substitutability for non-homothetic technologies taking account of output changes) are also covered. Also analyzed are functional representations of two-input technologies with constant elasticity of substitution (CES) and of n-input technologies with constant and identical elasticities for all pairs of inputs. Finally, the chapter explores the relationship between elasticity values and the comparative statics of factor income shares and the relationships between certain elasticity identities and separability conditions rationalizing consistent aggregation of subsets of inputs.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Institutional subscriptions

Notes

  1. 1.

    This concept was independently formulated by Cambridge University economist Joan Robinson [69] in her comparably classic book on The Economics of Imperfect Competition. Abba Lerner [60] and A. C. Pigou [68] also contributed to the understanding of the concept at its genesis.

  2. 2.

    While the use of the word “curvature” in this quote conveys the appropriate intuition, it is nevertheless technically incorrect, in part because curvature, formally defined, is a unit-dependent mathematical concept. See de la Grandville [29] for a clear exposition of this point.

  3. 3.

    As pointed out by Blackorby and Russell [14, p. 882], “[O]nly if the two variables were separable from all other variables would [this elasticity] provide information about shares; if we were to require all pairs to have this property, the production function would be additive. When combined with homotheticity (an assumption maintained in all these studies …) this implies that the production function is CES, in which case [the elasticities] are constant for all pairs of inputs.”

  4. 4.

    The Morishima elasticity is a generalization of Robinson’s [69] characterization of the two-input elasticity and for this reason is called the “Robinson elasticity of substitution” by Kuga and Murota [54] and Kuga [53].

  5. 5.

    See Footnote 2 above.

  6. 6.

    It is dual, not to the Morishima elasticity, but to McFadden’s [61] shadow elasticity of substitution.

  7. 7.

    Separability is also a necessary condition for decentralization of an optimization problem (as in, e.g., two-stage budgeting). See Blackorby et al. [15, Ch. 5] for a thorough exposition of the connection between separability and decentralized decision-making.

  8. 8.

    As we shall see in Digression: Dual Representations of Multiple-Input, Multiple-Output Technologies the homotheticity assumption can be dropped when the elasticity concept is formulated in the dual.

  9. 9.

    We could extend our analysis to all of \({\mathbf {R}}^2_{+}\) by employing directional derivatives at the boundary but instead leave this technical detail to the interested reader.

  10. 10.

    Subscripts on functions indicate differentiation with respect to the specified variable. The relation, = , should be interpreted as an identity throughout this chapter (i.e., as holding for all allowable values of the variables). Also, A := B means the relation defines A, and A =: B means the relation defines B.

  11. 11.

    The Cobb-Douglas production function was well-known at the time of the SMAC derivation, having been proposed much earlier [25]. The (CES2) production function made its first appearance in Solow’s [73] classic economic growth paper, but the functional form had appeared much earlier in the context of utility theory: Bergson (Burk) [20] proved that additivity of the utility function and linear Engel curves (expenditures on individual goods proportional to income for given prices) implies that the utility function belongs to the CES family. As the SMAC authors point out, the function (CES2) itself was long known in the functional-equation literature (see Hardy et al. [41, p. 13]) as the “mean value of order ρ.”

  12. 12.

    The SMAC theorem is easily generalized to homothetic technologies, in which case the production function is a monotonic transformation of (CES2) or (CD2); in the limiting case as σ → 0 it is a monotonic transformation of (L2).

  13. 13.

    Because the Allen elasticities are now typically exposited in the dual, they are often called the “Allen-Uzawa elasticities,” and I resort to that nomenclature on occasion as well. Uzawa’s approach was later extended by Blackorby and Russell [11, 13].

  14. 14.

    Thorough expositions of duality theory can be found in, e.g., Blackorby et al. [15], Chambers [22], Cornes [26], Diewert [30, 31], Färe and Primont [36], Fuss and McFadden [37], and Russell [71].

  15. 15.

    These assumptions are stronger than needed for much of the conceptual development that follows, but in the interest of simplicity I maintain them throughout.

  16. 16.

    Vector notation: \(\bar y\ge y\) if \(\bar y_j\ge y_j\) for all j; \(\bar y> y\) if \(\bar y_j\ge y_j\) for all j and \(\bar y\ne y\); and \(\bar y\gg y\) if \(\bar y_j> y_j\) for all j.

  17. 17.

    We restrict the domain of the distance function to assure that it is globally well defined. An alternative approach (e.g., Färe and Primont [36]) is to define D on the entire non-negative (n + m)-dimensional Euclidean space and replace “max” with “sup” in the definition. See Russell [71, footnote 12] for a comparison of these approaches.

  18. 18.

    Whatever is not there can be found in Diewert [30] or the Fuss/McFadden [37] volume.

  19. 19.

    pC(p, y) := 〈 C(p, y)∕∂p1, …, ∂C(p, y)∕∂pn〉.

  20. 20.

    See Färe and Grosskopf [34] and Russell [71] for analyses of the distance function and associated shadow prices.

  21. 21.

    See Blackorby and Russell [11, 13, 14] for a discussion of this asymmetry, which (as pointed out by Stern [76]) was recognized much earlier by Pigou [68] in his analysis of Robinson’s [69] less-formal characterization of this elasticity concept.

  22. 22.

    “Own” Morishima elasticities are identically equal to zero and hence uninteresting, as one might expect to be the case for a sensible elasticity of substitution.

  23. 23.

    These notions are referred to as “p-substitutes” and “p-complements” in much of the literature (see Stern [76] and the papers cited there), as distinguished from “q-substitutes” and “q-complements,” which I call dual substitutes and complements in section “Dual Elasticities of Substitutionł::bel sec:dual”.

  24. 24.

    McFadden [61] showed that his direct elasticities of substitution are constant and identical if and only if

    $$\displaystyle \begin{aligned}F(x)=\Bigg(\sum_{s=1}^S\alpha_sF^s(x^s)\Bigg)^{1/\rho},\quad 0\ne \rho<1/n^*,\quad 0\le\rho<1/n^*,\quad \alpha_s>0\ \forall\ s,\end{aligned} $$

    or

    $$\displaystyle \begin{aligned}F(x)=\alpha_0\prod_{s=1}^SF^s(x^s)^{\alpha_s/n^*},\quad \alpha_s>0\ \forall\ s,\quad {\mathrm{and}}\quad n^*=\max_s\{n_s\}\end{aligned} $$

    where

    $$\displaystyle \begin{aligned}F^s(x^s)=\prod_{i=1}^{n_s}x_i,\quad s=1,\ldots , m:\end{aligned} $$

    that is, if and only if the production function can be written as a CES or Cobb-Douglas function of (specific) Cobb-Douglas aggregator functions .

  25. 25.

    Note the “self-duality” of this structure, a concept formulated by Houthakker [46] in the context of dual consumer preferences: the cost-function structure in prices mirrors the CES/Cobb-Douglas structure of the production function in input quantities.

  26. 26.

    I am unaware of similar explorations of possible generalizations of the results on constancy of the Allen-Uzawa elasticities, but intuition suggests that similar results would go through there as well.

  27. 27.

    Blackorby and Russell [13] proved that the dependence on y of the corresponding coefficients, βi, i = 1, …n, in (18) leads to a violation of positive monotonicity of the cost function in y. Thus, generalization to non-homothetic technologies does not expand the Cobb-Douglas technologies consistent with constancy of the MES.

  28. 28.

    See Bertoletti [10], Kim [50], and Stern [76].

  29. 29.

    Yet another possible assignation is “shadow elasticity of substitution,” since this dual concept is formulated in terms of shadow prices.

  30. 30.

    Of course, the Allen and Morishima elasticities of complementarity are identical when n = 2, as is the case with Allen and Morishima elasticities of substitution.

  31. 31.

    While shadow prices and dual elasticities are well defined even if the input requirement sets are not convex, the comparative statics of income shares using these elasticities requires convexity (as well, of course, as price-taking, cost-minimizing behavior), which implies concavity of the distance function in x. By way of contrast, convexity of input requirement sets is not required for the comparative statics of income shares using dual elasticities, since the cost function is necessarily concave in prices. See Russell [71] for a discussion of these issues.

  32. 32.

    See also Hicks [44], Sato and Koizumi [72], and Stern [76] for discussions of these issues.

  33. 33.

    The concept was independently conceived by Leontief [57, 58] and Sono [74]. See Blackorby et al. [15] for a comprehensive development of the concept and its applications and for citations to the literature extending the Leontief-Solo concept.

  34. 34.

    In fact, the concept is abstract: it can be applied to any (multiple variable) function.

  35. 35.

    In the case where m = 1, D(x, F(x)) = 1 on the isoquant for output F(x). Differentiate this identity with respect to xi and xj and take the ratio to obtain this equivalence.

  36. 36.

    Proofs of these and other results in this section can be found in Blackorby et al. [15].

  37. 37.

    Don’t ask. Or if you can’t resist, I refer you to Section 4.6 of Blackorby et al. [15] on “Sono independence” and additivity in a binary partition.

  38. 38.

    Analogous to the case (13), \(\rho (y)={{\hat \rho (y)}/\big ({\hat \rho (y)-1\big )}}\).

  39. 39.

    In fact, as first pointed out by Antras [3], the pre-1980 constancy of income shares does not imply unitary elasticity of substitution when one takes into account the empirical evidence of aggregate labor-saving technological change, which would tend to increase the share of capital, offsetting its declining share owing to a increasing capital intensity and an elasticity of substitution below one.

  40. 40.

    Karabarbounis and Neiman [48] estimate an elasticity of substitution greater than one, but Acemoglu and Robinson [1] argues that their use of cross-country data makes their estimates more likely to correspond to endogenous-technology elasticities.

  41. 41.

    Some of this discussion is based on a working paper by Mundra and Russell [65].

  42. 42.

    Follow-ups of the Griliches study can be found in Johnson [47], Kugler et al. [55], and Welch [80].

  43. 43.

    See, e.g., the analysis of the substitutability between a “good” and a “bad” output (in this case, electricity and sulfur dioxide) in Färe et al. [35].

  44. 44.

    This may be an unfair oversimplification: Stern [76], building on Mundlak [63], proposes a related but somewhat different and more comprehensive taxonomy of the elasticities. (Nevertheless, I’m reminded of a (private) comment made by a prominent social choice theorist back in the heyday of research in his area: “The problem with social choice theory is that there are more axioms than there are ideas.” Well, perhaps we have reached the point where there are more elasticity-of-substitution concepts than there are ideas.)

References

  1. Acemoglu D and Robinson JA (2015) The rise and decline of general laws of capitalism. J Econ Perspect 29:3–28

    Google Scholar 

  2. Allen RGD (1938) Mathematical analysis for economists. Macmillan, London

    Google Scholar 

  3. Antras P (2004) Is the U.S. aggregate production function Cobb-Douglas? New estimates of the elasticity of substitution. Contrib Macroecon 4:1–34

    Google Scholar 

  4. Arrow KJ, Chenery HP, Minhaus BS, Solow RM (SMAC) (1961) Capital-labor substitution and economic efficiency. Rev Econ Stat 63:225–250

    Google Scholar 

  5. Barnett WM, Fisher D, Serletis A (1992) Consumer theory and the demand for money. J Econ Lit 30:2086–2119

    Google Scholar 

  6. Berndt ER, Christensen L (1973) The internal structure of functional relationships: separability, substitution, and aggregation. Rev Econ Stud 40:403–410

    Google Scholar 

  7. Berndt ER, Christensen L (1973) The translog function and the substitution of equipment, structures, and labor in U.S. manufacturing 1929–68. J Econ 1:81–114

    Google Scholar 

  8. Berndt ER, Wood DO (1975) Technology, prices, and the derived demand for energy. Rev Econ Stat 57:259–268

    Google Scholar 

  9. Bertoletti P (2001) The Allen/Uzawa elasticity of substitution as a measure of gross input substitutability. Rivista Italiana Degli Economisti 6:87–94

    Google Scholar 

  10. Bertoletti P (2005) Elasticities of substitution and complementarity a synthesis. J Prod Anal 24:183–196

    Google Scholar 

  11. Blackorby C, Russell RR (1975) The partial elasticity of substitution. Discussion Paper No. 75-1, Department of Economics, University of California, San Diego

    Google Scholar 

  12. Blackorby C, Russell RR (1976) Functional structure and the Allen partial elasticities of substitution: an application of duality theory. Rev Econ Stud 43:285–292

    Google Scholar 

  13. Blackorby C, Russell RR (1981) The Morishima elasticity of substitution: symmetry, constancy, separability, and its relationship to the Hicks and Allen elasticities. Rev Econ Stud 48:147–158

    Google Scholar 

  14. Blackorby C, Russell RR (1989) Will the real elasticity of substitution please stand up? A comparison of the Allen/Uzawa and Morishima elasticities. Am Econ Rev 79:882–888

    Google Scholar 

  15. Blackorby C, Primont D, Russell RR (1978) Duality, separability, and functional structure: theory and economic applications. North-Holland, New York

    Google Scholar 

  16. Blackorby C, Primont D, Russell RR (2007) The Morishima gross elasticity of substitution. J Product Anal 28:203–208

    Google Scholar 

  17. Borjas GJ (1994) The economics of immigration. J Econ Lit 32:1667–1717

    Google Scholar 

  18. Borjas GJ, Freeman RB, Katz LF (1992) On the labor market effects of immigration and trade. In: Borjas G, Freeman R (eds) Immigration and the work force. University of Chicago Press, Chicago

    Google Scholar 

  19. Borjas GJ, Freeman RB, Katz LF (1996) Searching for the effect of immigration on the labor market. AEA Pap Proc 8:246–251

    Google Scholar 

  20. Burk (Bergson) A (1936) Real income, expenditure proportionality, and Frisch’s ‘new methods of measuring marginal utility’. Rev Econ Stud 4:33–52

    Google Scholar 

  21. Cass D (1965) Optimum growth in an aggregative model of capital accumulation. Rev Econ Stud 32:233–240

    Google Scholar 

  22. Chambers R (1988) Applied production analysis. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  23. Chirinko RS (2008) σ: the long and short of it. J Macroecon 30:671–686

    Google Scholar 

  24. Chirinko RS, Mallick D (2016) The substitution elasticity, factor shares, and the low-frequency panel model. Am Econ J Macroecon 9:225–253

    Google Scholar 

  25. Cobb CW, Douglas PH (1928) A theory of production Am Econ Rev 18:23–34

    Google Scholar 

  26. Cornes R (1992) Duality and modern economics. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  27. Davis GC, Gauger J (1996) Measuring substitution in monetary-asset demand systems. J Bus Econ Stat 14:203–209

    Google Scholar 

  28. Davis GC, Shumway CR (1996) To tell the truth about interpreting the Morishima elasticity of substitution. Can J Agric Econ 44:173–182

    Google Scholar 

  29. de la Grandville O (1997) Curvature and the elasticity of substitution: straightening it out. J Econ 66:23–34

    Google Scholar 

  30. Diewert WE (1974) Applications of duality theory. In: Intriligator M, Kendrick D (eds) Frontiers of quantitative economics, vol 2. North-Holland, Amsterdam

    Google Scholar 

  31. Diewert WE (1982) Duality approaches to microeconomic theory. In: Arrow K, Intriligator M (eds) Handbook of mathematical economics, vol II. North-Holland, New York

    Google Scholar 

  32. Dixit AK, Stiglitz JE (1977) Monopolistic competition and optimum product diversity. Am Econ Rev 67:297–308

    Google Scholar 

  33. Ewis NA, Fischer D (1984) The translog utility function and the demand for money in the United States. J Money Credit Bank 16:34–52

    Google Scholar 

  34. Färe R, Grosskopf S (1990) A distance function approach to price efficiency. J Pol Econ 43:123–126

    Google Scholar 

  35. Färe R, Grosskopf S, Noh D-W, Weber W (2005) Characteristics of a polluting technology: theory and practice. J Econ 126:469–492

    Google Scholar 

  36. Färe R, Primont D (1995) Multi-output production and duality theory: theory and applications. Kluwer Academic Press, Boston

    Google Scholar 

  37. Fuss M, McFadden D (eds) (1978) Production economics; a dual approach to theory and applications. North-Holland, Amsterdam

    Google Scholar 

  38. Griliches Z (1969) Capital-skill complementarity. Rev Econ Stat 51:465–468

    Google Scholar 

  39. Grossman J (1982) The substitutability of natives and immigrants in production. Rev Econ Stat 64:596–603

    Google Scholar 

  40. Hall RE (1988) Intertemporal substitution in consumption. J Polit Econ 96:339–357

    Google Scholar 

  41. Hardy GH, Littlewood JE, Pólya G (1934) Inequalities. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  42. Hicks JR (1932) The theory of wages. MacMillan Press, London

    Google Scholar 

  43. Hicks JR (1936) Distribution and economic progress: A revised version. Rev Econ Stud 4:1–12

    Google Scholar 

  44. Hicks JR (1970) Elasticity of substitution again: substitutes and complements. Oxford Econ Pap 22:289–296

    Google Scholar 

  45. Hicks JR, Allen RGD (1934) A reconsideration of the theory of value, part II. Economica 1:196–219. N.S

    Google Scholar 

  46. Houthakker HS (1965) A note on self-dual preferences. Econometrica 33:797–801

    Google Scholar 

  47. Johnson GE (1970) The demand for labor by educational category. South Econ J 37:190–204

    Google Scholar 

  48. Karabarbounis L, Neiman B (2014) The global decline of the labor share. Q J Econ 129:61–103

    Google Scholar 

  49. Kohli U (1999), Trade and migration: a production theory approach. In: Faini R, de Melo J, Zimmermann KF (eds) Migration: the controversies and the evidence. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  50. Kim HY (2000) The Antonelli versus Hicks elasticity of complementarity and inverse input demand systems. Aust Econ Pap 39:245–261

    Google Scholar 

  51. Klump R, de la Grandville O (2000) Economic growth and the elasticity of substitution: two theorems and some suggestions. Am Econ Rev 90:282–291

    Google Scholar 

  52. Koopmans TC (1965) On the concept of optimal economic growth. In: The econometric approach to development planning. North Holland (for Pontificia Academic Science), Amsterdam

    Google Scholar 

  53. Kuga K (1979) On the symmetry of Robinson elasticities of substitution: the general case. Rev Econ Stud 46:527–531

    Google Scholar 

  54. Kuga K, Murota T (1972) A note on definition of elasticity of substitution. Macroeconomica 24:285–290

    Google Scholar 

  55. Kugler P, Müller U, Sheldon G (1989) Non-neutral technical change, capital, white-collar and blue-collar labor. Econ Lett 31:91–94

    Google Scholar 

  56. Lau L (1978) Applications of profit functions. In: Fuss M, McFadden D (eds) Production economics: a dual approach to theory and applications. North-Holland, Amsterdam, pp 133–216

    Google Scholar 

  57. Leontief WW (1947) A note on the interrelation of subsets of independent variables of a continuous function with continuous first derivatives. Bull Am Math Soc 53:343–350

    Google Scholar 

  58. Leontief WW (1947) Introduction to a theory of the internal structure of functional relationships. Econometrica 15:361–373

    Google Scholar 

  59. Leontief WW (1953) Domestic production and foreign trade: the American capital position re-examined. Proc Am Philos Soc 97:331–349

    Google Scholar 

  60. Lerner AP (1933) Notes on the elasticity of substitution II: the diagrammatical representation. Rev Econ Stud 1:68–70

    Google Scholar 

  61. McFadden D (1963) Constant elasticity of substitution production functions. Rev Econ Stud 30:73–83

    Google Scholar 

  62. Morishima M (1967) A few suggestions on the theory of elasticity (in Japanese). Keizai Hyoron (Econ Rev) 16:144–150

    Google Scholar 

  63. Mundlak Y (1968) Elasticities of substitution and the theory of derived demand. Rev Econ Stud 35:225–236

    Google Scholar 

  64. Mundra K (2013) Direct and dual elasticities of substitution under non-homogeneous technology and nonparametric distribution. Indian Growth Dev Rev 6:204–218

    Google Scholar 

  65. Mundra K, Russell RR (2004) Dual elasticities of substitution. Discussion Paper 01-26, Department of Economics, University of California, Riverside

    Google Scholar 

  66. Murota T (1977) On the symmetry of Robinson elasticities of substitution: a three-factor case. Rev Econ Stud 42:79–85

    Google Scholar 

  67. Parks RW (1971) Price responsiveness of factor utilization in Swedish manufacturing, 1870–1950. Rev Econ Stud 53:129–139

    Google Scholar 

  68. Pigou AC (1934) The elasticity of substitution. Econ J 44:23–241

    Google Scholar 

  69. Robinson J (1933) Economics of imperfect competition. MacMillan, London

    Google Scholar 

  70. Russell RR (1975) Functional separability and partial elasticities of substitution. Rev Econ Stud 42:79–85

    Google Scholar 

  71. Russell RR (1997) Distance functions in consumer and producer theory. Essay 1. In: Färe R, Grosskopf S (eds) Index number theory: essays in honor of Sten Malmquist. Kluwer Academic Publishers, Boston, pp 7–90

    Google Scholar 

  72. Sato R, Koizumi T (1973) On the elasticities of substitution and complementarity. Oxford Econ Pap 25:44–56

    Google Scholar 

  73. Solow RM (1956) A contribution to the theory of economic growth. Q J Econ 65:65–94

    Google Scholar 

  74. Sono M (1945, 1961) The effect of price changes on the demand and supply of separable goods. Int Econ Rev 2:239–271 (Originally published in Japanese In: Kokumin Keisai Zasshi 74:1–51)

    Google Scholar 

  75. Stern DI (2010) Derivation of the Hicks, or direct, elasticity of substitution from the input distance function. Econ Lett 108:349–351

    Google Scholar 

  76. Stern DI (2011) Elasticities of substitution and complementarity. J Prod Anal 36:79–89

    Google Scholar 

  77. Syrquin M, Hollender G (1982) Elasticities of substitution and complementarity: the general case. Oxford Econ Pap 34:515–519

    Google Scholar 

  78. Thompson P, Taylor TG (1995) The capital-energy substitutability debate: a new look. Rev Econ Stat 77:565–569

    Google Scholar 

  79. Uzawa H (1962) Production functions with constant elasticities of substitution. Rev Econ Stud 29:291–299

    Google Scholar 

  80. Welch F (1970) Education in production. J Polit Econ 78:35–59

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to R. Robert Russell .

Editor information

Editors and Affiliations

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2020 Springer Nature Singapore Pte Ltd.

About this entry

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this entry

Russell, R. (2020). Elasticities of Substitution. In: Ray, S., Chambers, R., Kumbhakar, S. (eds) Handbook of Production Economics. Springer, Singapore. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-981-10-3450-3_10-1

Download citation

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/978-981-10-3450-3_10-1

  • Published:

  • Publisher Name: Springer, Singapore

  • Print ISBN: 978-981-10-3450-3

  • Online ISBN: 978-981-10-3450-3

  • eBook Packages: Springer Reference Economics and FinanceReference Module Humanities and Social SciencesReference Module Business, Economics and Social Sciences

Publish with us

Policies and ethics