Skip to main content
Log in

Sibling size and investment in children’s education: an asian instrument

  • OriginalPaper
  • Published:
Journal of Population Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

This study estimates the trade-off between child quantity and quality by exploiting exogenous variation in fertility under son preferences. Under son preferences, both sibling size and fertility timing are determined depending on the first child’s gender, which is random as long as parents do not abort girls at their first childbearing. For the sample South Korean households, I find strong evidence of unobserved heterogeneity in preferences for child quantity and quality across households. The trade-off is not as strong as observed cross-sectional relationships would suggest. However, even after controlling for unobserved heterogeneity, a greater number of siblings have adverse effects on per-child investment in education, in particular, when fertility is high.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Interestingly, Gomes (1984) found for a household sample from Kenya that children from a larger family are more likely to complete grades. The reason is that parents in Kenya control their eldest child’s earnings and younger children benefit from this extra source of family resources. This suggests that the relationship between child quantity and quality take different forms across different cultures. Cross-country comparative studies are demanded.

  2. On the other hand, economists have also tried to develop theoretical explanations for the observed trade-off. The major novelty here is that, even without assuming unusual substitutability between child quantity and quality in preferences, the trade-off may exist due to their interaction due to budget constraints (Becker and Lewis 1973).

  3. There are a few recent papers using a similar empirical strategy. For example, see Chun and Oh (2002); Black et al. (2005); Conley and Glauber (2005); and Angrist et al. (2005).

  4. School supplies and reference books are likely to account for most of the rest of total expenses. In particular, most students study with some “unrequired” reference books that are quite expensive. Tuition and other school fees are relatively small. For example, in 2005, annual high-school tuition and fees were around US $1,500.

  5. Why South Korean parents are strongly concerned about children’s education is an important question but beyond the scope of this paper. It might be because of strong intergenerational ties or increasing demand for skilled workers. Refer to Seth (2002) for a historical perspective on the origin of “education fever” in South Korea.

  6. An earlier version of this paper proved these results and is available from the author upon request.

  7. Investment in education might depend on the sex composition of children due to pure cost differences in education across girls and boys. After controlling for sibling size, Lundberg and Rose (2004) find no significant difference in educational costs by gender in the United States.

  8. The number of observations for each case is interesting. For example, there are only six observations with three sons and no daughters, which implies that most households stop further childbearing when they have two sons. Also the number of households with two daughters only is disproportionately small, which suggests that households are likely to have another child when they have two daughters.

  9. The returns to college education are even higher for women; the college wage premium, measured by the average wage gap between high-school and college graduates as a proportion of high-school graduates’ average wage, was 65% for women but only 44% for men in 1997. In addition, there is no gender gap in the employment rate for both high school and college graduates.

  10. Kim and Lee (2002) found that parents invest slightly more in private tutoring for daughters. They interpret this finding as a result of the fact that girls are more likely to take private tutoring in music and arts, which tend to be more expensive. Their finding suggests that our estimates might be overestimated in absolute terms. To address this issue, we experimented with a different dependent variable, total investment in education except for private tutoring, which does not significantly change our results below.

  11. Including the time-invariant random effect that is orthogonal to explanatory variables does not make any significant difference. Also, I ran a regression of educational investment directly on the first child’s sex (or overall sex composition) with other controls. Even though the estimates are potentially biased, if the sex mattered in a significant way, I should have found some direct effects of the first child’s sex (or sex composition). But I found no significant effect. Those variables are significant only if we lower the number of children.

  12. The IV estimates in this study are interpreted as local average treatment effects (Imbens and Angrist 1994). That is, my results show the marginal effects of the number of siblings for those who would change their childbearing decisions depending upon the first child’s sex. The monotonicity assumption is likely to hold for the current study because defiers (those with “daughter preferences”) are rare.

  13. Mother age and mother age squared are insignificant in Table 6 where the dependent variable in the first-stage regression is a continuous measure of fertility (number of children). The two contrasting age profiles of the marginal effects are mixed in Table 6.

  14. For robustness, I also experimented with a different instrument—the occurrence of twinning at the first birth. The validity condition in this study seems questionable, as the costs of educating children would differ for two singletons and two twins. Having two children at the same time may decrease per-child investment, in particular, when the household faces borrowing constraints. The estimate turns out to be significantly negative.

References

  • Angrist JD, Evans W (1998) Children and their parents’ labor supply: evidence from exogenous variation in family size. Am Econ Rev 88(3):450–477

    Google Scholar 

  • Angrist JD, Lavy V, Schlosser A (2005) New evidence on the causal link between the quantity and quality of children. NBER Work Pap no.11835

  • Becker G, Lewis G (1973) Interaction between quantity and quality of children. J Polit Econ 81(2):S279–S288

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Black SE, Devereux PJ, Salvanes KG (2005) The more the merrier? The effect of family size and birth order on children’s education. Q J Econ 120(2):669–700

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Blake J (1989) Family size and achievement. University of California Press, Los Angeles

    Google Scholar 

  • Bound J, Jaeger D, Baker R (1995) Problems with instrumental variables estimation when the correlation between the instruments and the endogenous explanatory variable is weak. J Am Stat Assoc 90(430):443–450

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Browning M (1992) Children and household economic behavior. J Econ Lit 30(3):1434–1475

    Google Scholar 

  • Chun H, Oh J (2002) An instrumental variable estimate of the effect of fertility on the labor force participation of married women. Appl Econ Lett 9(10):631–634

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Conley D, Glauber R (2005) Parental educational investment and children’s academic risk: estimates of the impact of sibship size and birth order from exogenous variation in fertility. NBER Work Pap no.11302

  • Davies J, Zhang J (1995) Gender bias, investments in children, and bequests. Int Econ Rev 36(3):795–818

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gomes M (1984) Family size and educational attainment in Kenya. Popul Dev Rev 10(4):647–660

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Goodkind D (1996) On substituting sex preference strategies in East Asia: does prenatal sex selection reduce postnatal discrimination? Popul Dev Rev 22(1):111–125

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hanushek E (1992) The trade-off between child quantity and quality. J Polit Econ 100(1):84–117

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Iacovou M (2001) Fertility and female labor force participation. Institute for social and economic research working paper no.2001-19. University of Essex, Colchester, UK

    Google Scholar 

  • Imbens G, Angrist JD (1994) Identification and estimation of local average treatment effects. Econometrica 62(2):467–475

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kim S, Lee JH (2002) Private tutoring and demand for education in South Korea. Working paper, Department of Economics, University of Wisconsin at Milwaukee

  • Lundberg S, Rose E (2004) Investments in sons and daughters: evidence from the consumer expenditure survey. In: Kalil A, DeLeire T (eds) Family investment in children: resources and behaviors that promote success. Lawrence Erlbaum Associates, pp 163–180

  • Park CB, Cho NH (1995) Consequences of son preference in a low-fertility society: imbalance of the sex ratio at birth in Korea. Popul Dev Rev 21(1):59–84

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rosenzweig M, Schultz TP (1987) Fertility and investments in human capital: estimates of the consequence of imperfect fertility control in Malaysia. J Econom 36:163–184

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rosenzweig M, Wolpin K (1980) Testing the quantity-quality fertility model: the use of twins as a natural experiment. Econometrica 48:227–240

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Seth MJ (2002) Education fever: society, politics, and the pursuit of schooling in South Korea. University of Hawaii Press, Honolulu

    Google Scholar 

  • Staiger D, Stock JH (1997) Instrumental variables regression with weak instruments. Econometrica 65(3):557–586

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • World Bank (1994) Population and development: implications for the world bank. Washington, DC

Download references

Acknowledgment

I would like to thank Daniel Hamermesh for his comments and guidance during this study. Also, I would like to thank the editor Junsen Zhang, anonymous referees, Steve Bronars, Robert Crosnoe, Gordon Dahl, Stephen Donald, Gerald Oettinger, Steve Trejo, and seminar participants at the University of Texas at Austin and at the 2003 annual meetings of the Society of Labor Economists.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Jungmin Lee.

Additional information

Responsible editor: Junsen Zhang

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Lee, J. Sibling size and investment in children’s education: an asian instrument. J Popul Econ 21, 855–875 (2008). https://doi.org/10.1007/s00148-006-0124-5

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s00148-006-0124-5

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation