Skip to main content
Log in

Intergenerational income immobility in Finland: contrasting roles for parental earnings and family income

  • Original Paper
  • Published:
Journal of Population Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

An intergenerational model is developed, nesting heritable earning abilities and credit constraints limiting human capital investments in children. Estimates on a large, Finnish data panel indicate very low transmission from parental earnings, suggesting that the parameter of inherited earning ability is tiny. Family income, particularly during the phase of educating children, is shown to be much more important in shaping children’s lifetime earnings. This influence of parental incomes on children’s earnings rises as the children age because the returns to education rise. Despite Finland’s well-developed welfare state, persistence in economic status across generations is much higher than previously thought.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Becker and Tomes (1979, 1986), Behrman et al. (1995). Easterlin et al. (1980) expressed the third alternative in terms of fertility outcomes, though it may be applied equally to quality rather than just quantity of children. Excellent surveys are provided in Behrman (1997), Solon (1999), Björklund and Jäntti (2009), Björklund and Salvanes (2010), and Black and Devereux (2010).

  2. Contributions include Cameron and Heckman (1998, 2001), Behrman and Rosenzweig (2002), Carneiro and Heckman (2002), Plug and Vijverberg (2003, 2005), Black et al. (2005), Belley and Lochner (2007), Lochner and Monge-Naranjo (2011), and Pronzato (2012).

  3. See also Duncan et al. (2005), Sacerdote (2007), Liu and Zeng (2009), and Behrman et al. (2011).

  4. See, for example, Gustaffson (1994), Björklund and Jäntti (1997), Österbacka (2001), Björklund et al. (2002), Jäntti et al. (2007).

  5. In a related paper, Oreopoulos et al. (2008) show that earnings are lower among a group of Canadians, whose fathers lost their jobs in plant closings, than among a measurably comparable group whose fathers were not retrenched. See also Eide and Showalter (2000).

  6. These correspond to the high-resource and low-resource family cases in Behrman et al. (1995).

  7. In Eq. 5, the partial derivative of H c with respect to G c has the same sign as η, thus being negative (positive) for elasticities of substitution <1 (or >1).

  8. For example, Altonji and Dunn (1991) and Zimmerman (1992) both apply GMM estimators to their panel data, while Lillard and Kilburn (1997) maximize a joint likelihood function derived from an ARMA structure in transitory earnings.

  9. Exploratory results in the present context suggest that the use of instrumental variables increases the estimated transmission from family income but not from parental earnings, though identifying appropriate instruments is, as always, a difficult task and this route is not followed in the present paper.

  10. “A family consists of a married or cohabiting couple and their children living together; or a parent and his or her children living together; or a married or cohabiting couple without children. Persons living in the household-dwelling unit who are not members of the nuclear family are not included in the family population, even if they are related” (Statistics Finland 1995, p. 16).

  11. Whether the adults with whom the child was living in a 1970 nuclear family are the biological parents is not known. Children recorded in the family unit comprise biological and adopted children of either spouse, though foster children and children in the care of the family are not classified as part of the family.

  12. Among the children ages 0–16 in our database, less than three quarters of 1 % are not living with their family and hence omitted from the family-based sample. This very low fraction is in accord with a report by The Population Research Institute (1995), which shows that in the mid-1980s Finnish children continued to live with their parents even beyond age 16 more frequently than did children in the other Nordic countries: 95 % of boys ages 16–19 were still at home in Finland as were 88 % of girls.

  13. “Income subject to state taxation does not include scholarships and grants received from the public corporations for study or research, earned income from abroad if the person has worked abroad for at least six months, part of the social security benefits received from the public sector and tax-exempt interest income” (Statistics Finland 1995, p. 18). Since 1985 taxable income in Finland does, however, include child, maternity, and unemployment benefits.

  14. Most estimates of the intergenerational correlation in incomes are based on sample survey data, though a few studies have also extracted income measures from tax registers (Corak and Heisz 1999, on Canada; Österberg 2000, on Sweden; and Mazumder 2005, who uses the US Social Security Administration’s Summary Earnings Records). Register-based data, whether derived from employer or tax records, have some advantages over survey responses, particularly where the survey respondent is not the person employed. Yet register-based data also have some limitations. The Finnish data lack information on hours worked, for example, and hence are inadequate to examine hourly rates of pay and preclude computation of full income. The information on self-employment earnings also has some drawbacks. The usual caveats apply with respect to the role of capital income components within self-employment earnings. Moreover, given progressive taxes on each individual, an incentive exists to spread family self-employment income across family members where possible. Nonetheless, self-employment is not a major source of earnings for young people. For only 5.2 % of sons and 5 % of daughters are more than 90 % of their earnings, in an average year, derived from self-employment. For the remaining sons and daughters, self-employment earnings represent only 7 and 4.4 % of their earnings, respectively.

  15. This literature also presumes a single child. An extension to multiple children is to be the subject of a separate paper, though preliminary findings indicate that the results in the present paper prove robust to including controls for family size.

  16. Certainly, the majority of empirical studies, both of the USA and elsewhere, seek to relate sons’ earnings to earnings of their fathers. A much smaller number of studies correlate the earnings of daughters and of fathers, and a handful of studies have considered the mothers’ earnings. See Solon (1999), Tables 3, 4, 5 and 6 for a summary of estimates for both sons and daughters. Subsequent estimates of intergenerational income transmission for daughters include Österbacka (2001) and Chadwick and Solon (2002).

  17. The appendices to this paper are available as Boston University Institute for Economic Development Discussion Paper No. 221 at http://www.bu.edu/econ/files/2011/09/Lucas_Kerr.pdf.

  18. Source: Österbacka (2001Table 3 ). t statistics for a zero null hypothesis are shown in parentheses, calculated from the reported standard errors. In addition, Österbacka explores estimates within quintiles of parents’ earnings and the correlations between siblings’ earnings, while also undertaking a decomposition of the intergenerational correlations. See also Jäntti and Österbacka (How much of the variance in income can be attributed to family background? Empirical Evidence from Finland, unpublished).

  19. See Tables 2 and 9 in Jäntti et al. (2007). t statistics for a zero null hypothesis are shown in parentheses, calculated from the reported confidence intervals.

  20. The age range varies considerably over which earnings of children are included in prior studies. Solon (1992) imposes a lower bound at age 25 in his study of sons’ earnings, while the lower bound in Zimmerman (1992) is 29, and Dearden et al. (1997) look at UK sons and daughters when they are 33. Although only children who are at least 25 in 1985 are included in our initial analysis in Section 4, any earlier positive earnings (or wages) of these children are included in computing mean earnings, provided the son or daughter was at least 20 at the time of observation in the 1975 or 1980 census. To the role of age in these estimates, Section 5 returns.

  21. Any distinction between this mean age measure, the mean age over which the individual is observed, or age at a specific point in time, is not always drawn in this context. However, in practice, the distinction has relatively little impact on the estimates.

  22. Projecting to age 40 and censoring earnings data, Jäntti et al. (2007) obtain slightly higher estimates for sons. The following section returns to the issue of an age interaction.

  23. Given the strong similarity in the results for earnings and wages in Table 2, for brevity, only results for the case of earnings are reported in the remainder of the paper. The specifications in family income include mean age of the father during periods when he reports positive income and a similar measure for the mother, both in polynomials through the fourth power, plus dummy variables for cases where no father or mother is initially present.

  24. Several US studies also estimate transmission from family income to be larger than from parental earnings measures (see the review in Solon 1999). However, these studies uniformly concentrate upon transmission from parents’ family income to child’s family income, the latter presumably reflecting assortative mating in addition to the considerations in Section 1. As far as we are aware, no study incorporates both family income and parental earnings as regressors. A test for equality of all coefficients between the two stages of sampling within our data, based on the last specification in Table 3, gives F(17, 14,105) = 0.937 for sons and F(17, 13,611) = 0.564 for daughters. Pooling the subsamples appears not to be problematic.

  25. Restricting the specification to be linear, as opposed to the far more parsimonious form, generates an F statistics for sons of F(97, 14,251) = 1.646 and for daughters F(97, 13,747) = 1.114. A least absolute deviation estimate at the median also generates only a slightly lower value for transmission from family income than does the estimate at the mean. See Electronic supplementary material—Appendix B.

  26. Behrman and Taubman (1985) test a three-generational, schooling equivalent to Eq. 22 on a US sample. The same data set is used in Behrman and Taubman (1989) for a three-generational test of the Easterlin et al. (1980) fertility hypothesis. See also Robertson and Roy (1982), Warren and Hauser (1997), and Jeon and Shields (2005).

  27. See the discussion in Card (1999) for instance.

  28. Such an effect has previously been detected in the US context by Reville RT (Intertemporal and life cycle variation in measured intergenerational earnings mobility, unpublished), though Lee and Solon (2009) find less clear-cut patterns with respect to an age interaction. Equation 26 may be thought of as a specific form of the model developed in Haider and Solon (2006) which notes the potential age dependence of parameters such as β 1 and β 2 in Eq. 18. See also Jenkins (1987).

  29. For example, although all of the sons and daughters were potential beneficiaries of the guaranteed student loan scheme introduced in 1959 and explicitly subsidized after 1969, only the younger cohorts tended to benefit from the massive expansion in this system after the mid-1980s. Moreover, the various cohorts encountered the effects of the deep recession of the early 1990s at different ages (Hämäläinen and Hämäläinen 2005).

  30. Tests, using the t-bar statistics suggested by Im et al. (2003), reject with very high levels of confidence unit roots in the panel earnings data. See Electronic supplementary material—Appendix E.

  31. Pekkala and Lucas (2007) adopt more flexible forms of the cohort interaction and confirm the absence of any clear trend in family income transmission across cohorts born between 1954 and 1970 in Finland, though a downward decline is apparent among earlier cohorts born from 1930 to 1950.

  32. Controls are included, but not tabulated, for the terms \(a_{ct}^{-1}\), A ct , A , and A /a ct from Eq. 26.

  33. The instruments available include the following: the proportions of school-age children in a region living 0–3, 3–5, or more than 5 km from a school in 1959 and in 1969; a dummy variable for whether the child was affected by the conversion to a comprehensive system, which was introduced on a rolling basis throughout the country, roughly from north to south, between 1972 and 1976 (cf. Black et al. 2005, on Norway; on the Finnish reform, see Pekkarinen et al. 2009); a dummy variable for whether the child’s region of residence at age 18 contained a university town and, if not, distance to such a region (see Conneely and Uusitalo 1998). The partial F statistics for the seven available measures, in a first-stage regression including controls for \(a_{ct}^{-1}\) and A ct , are F(7, 31,501) = 3.98 for sons and F(7, 30,227) = 2.81 for daughters.

  34. Mulligan (1999: S197). The portions in brackets are converted into notation of the present paper.

References

  • Abul Naga RH (2002) Estimating the intergenerational correlation of incomes: an errors-in-variables framework. Economica 69(273):69–91

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Altonji JG, Dunn TA (1991) Relationships among the family incomes and labor market outcomes of relatives. In: Ehrenberg R (ed) Research in labor economics. JAI Press, Greenwich, pp 269–310

    Google Scholar 

  • Baker M, Solon G (2003) Earnings dynamics and inequality among Canadian men, 1976–1992: evidence from longitudinal income tax records. J Labor Econ 21(2):289–321

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Becker GS (1972) Schooling and inequality from generation to generation: comment. J Polit Econ 80(3):S252–S255

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Becker GS, Tomes N (1979) An equilibrium theory of the distribution of income and intergenerational mobility. J Polit Econ 87(6):1153–1189

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Becker GS, Tomes N (1986) Human capital and the rise and fall of families. J Labor Econ 4(3):s1–s39

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Behrman JR (1997) Intrahousehold distribution and the family. In: Rosenzweig MR, Stark O (eds) Handbook of population and family economics, vol 1A. Elsevier, Amsterdam, pp 125–187

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Behrman JR, Kohler H-P, Jensen VM, Pedersen D, Petersen I, Bingley P, Christensen K (2011) Does more schooling reduce hospitalization and delay mortality? New evidence based on Danish twins. Demography 48(4):1347–1375

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Behrman JR, Rosenzweig MR (2002) Does increasing women’s schooling raise the schooling of the next generation? Am Econ Rev 92(1):323–334

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Behrman JR, Taubman P (1985) Intergenerational earnings mobility in the United States: some estimates and a test of Becker’s intergenerational endowments model. Rev Econ Stat 67(1):144–151

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Behrman JR, Taubman P (1989) A test of the Easterlin fertility model using income for two generations and a comparison with the Becker model. Demography 26(1):117–123

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Behrman JR, Taubman P (1990) The intergenerational correlation between children’s adult earnings and their parents’ income: results from the Michigan panel survey of income dynamics. Rev Income Wealth 36(2):115–127

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Behrman JR, Pollak RA, Taubman P (1995) The wealth model: efficiency in education and distribution in the family. In: Behrman JR, Pollak RA, Taubman P (eds) From parent to child: intrahousehold allocations and intergenerational relations in the United States. University of Chicago Press, Chicago, pp 113–138

    Google Scholar 

  • Belley P, Lochner L (2007) The changing role of family income and ability in determining educational achievement. J Hum Cap 1(1):37–89

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Björklund A, Jäntti M (1997) Intergenerational income mobility in Sweden compared to the United States. Am Econ Rev 87(5):1009–1018

    Google Scholar 

  • Björklund A, Jäntti M (2009) Intergenerational income mobility and the role of family background. In: Salverda W, Nolan B, Smeeding TM (eds) The Oxford handbook of economic inequality. Oxford University Press, Oxford, pp 491–521

    Google Scholar 

  • Björklund A, Eriksson T, Jäntti M, Raaum O, Österbacka E (2002) Brother correlations in earnings in Denmark, Finland, Norway and Sweden compared to the United States. J Popul Econ 15(4):757–772

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Björklund A, Jäntti M, Solon G (2005) Influences of nature and nurture on earnings variation: a report on a study of various sibling types in Sweden. In: Bowles S, Gintis H, Osborne Groves M (eds) Unequal chances: family background and economic success. Princeton University Press, Princeton, pp 145–164

    Google Scholar 

  • Björklund A, Salvanes KG (2010) Education and family background: mechanisms and policies. In: Hanushek E, Machin S, Woessmann L (eds) Handbook of economics of education, vol 3. Elsevier, Amsterdam, pp 201–247

    Google Scholar 

  • Black SE, Devereux PJ (2010) Recent developments in intergenerational mobility. In: Ashenfelter O, Card D (eds) Handbook of labor economics, vol 4B. Elsevier, Amsterdam, pp 1487–1541

    Google Scholar 

  • Black SE, Devereux PJ, Salvanes KG (2005) Why the apple doesn’t fall far: understanding intergenerational transmission of human capital. Am Econ Rev 95(1):437–449

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Blomster P (2000) Yliopisto-opiskelijoiden Toimeentulo ja Opintotuki 1900-luvun Suomessa (The livelihood of university students and access to financial aid in 20th century Finland). Sosiaali-ja Terveysturvan Tutkimuksia: 56. Kansaneläkelaitos, Helsinki

    Google Scholar 

  • Böhlmark A, Lindquist MJ (2006) Life-cycle variations in the association between current and lifetime income: replication and extension for Sweden. J Labor Econ 24(4):879–896

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bowles S (1972) Schooling and inequality from generation to generation. J Polit Econ 80(3):S219–S251

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bratsberg B, Røed K, Raaum O, Naylor R, Jäntti M, Eriksson T, Österbacka E (2007) Nonlinearities in intergenerational earnings mobility: consequences for cross-country comparisons. Econ J 117(519):C72–C92

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cameron SV, Heckman JJ (1998) Life cycle schooling and dynamic selection bias: models and evidence for five cohorts of American males. J Polit Econ 106(2):262–333

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cameron SV, Heckman JJ (2001) The dynamics of educational attainment for Black, Hispanic and White males. J Polit Econ 109(3):455–499

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Card D (1999) The causal effect of education on earnings. In: Ashenfelter O, Card D (eds) Handbook of labor economics, vol 3A. Elsevier, Amsterdam, pp 1277–2097

    Google Scholar 

  • Carneiro P, Heckman JJ (2002) The evidence on credit constraints in post-secondary schooling. Econ J 112(482):705–734

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chadwick L, Solon G (2002) Intergenerational income mobility among daughters. Am Econ Rev 92(1):335–344

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Conneely K, Uusitalo R (1998) Estimating heterogeneous treatment effects in the Becker schooling model. Paper presented at the labor economics seminar series, industrial relations section. Princeton University, Princeton

    Google Scholar 

  • Corak M (2006) Do poor children become poor adults? Lessons from a cross country comparison of generational earnings mobility. Res Econ Inequal 13(1):143–188

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Corak M, Heisz A (1999) The intergenerational earnings and income mobility of Canadian men: evidence from longitudinal income tax data. J Hum Resour 34(3):504–533

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Couch KA, Lillard, DR (1998) Sample selection rules and the intergenerational correlation of earnings. Labour Econ 5(3):313–329

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dearden L, Machin S, Reed H (1997) Intergenerational mobility in Britain. Econ J 107(440):47–66

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Duncan G, Kalil A, Mayer SE, Tepper R, Payne MR (2005) The apple does not fall far from the tree. In: Bowles S, Gintis H, Osborne Groves M (eds) Unequal chances: family background and economic success. Princeton University Press, Princeton, pp 23–79

    Google Scholar 

  • Easterlin RA, Pollak RA, Wachter ML (1980) Toward a more general economic model of fertility determination: endogenous preferences and natural fertility. In: Easterlin RA (ed) Population and economic change in developing countries. University of Chicago Press, Chicago, pp 81–150

    Google Scholar 

  • Eide ER, Showalter MH (2000) A note on the rate of intergenerational convergence of earnings. J Popul Econ 13(1):159–162

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ekhaugen T (2009) Extracting the causal component from the intergenerational correlation in unemployment. J Popul Econ 22(1):97–113

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Eriksson T, Jäntti M (1997) The distribution of earnings in Finland: 1971–1990. Eur Econ Rev 41(9):1763–1779

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Erola J, Moisio P (2002) Did Finland stagnate? Social mobility and long-term unemployment in Finland 1970–1995. Sosiologia 39(3):185–199

    Google Scholar 

  • Galton F (1869) Hereditary genius: an inquiry into its laws and consequences. Macmillan, London

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Gaviria A (2002) Intergenerational mobility, sibling inequality and borrowing constraints. Econ Educ Rev 21(4):331–340

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Grawe ND (2004) Reconsidering the use of nonlinearities in intergenerational earnings mobility as a test for credit constraints. J Hum Resour 39(3):813–827

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Grawe ND (2006) Lifecycle bias in estimates of intergenerational earnings persistence. Labour Econ 13(5):551–570

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gustaffson B (1994) The degree and pattern of income immobility in Sweden. Rev Income Wealth 40(1):67–86

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Haider S, Solon G (2006) Life-cycle variation in the association between current and lifetime earnings. Am Econ Rev 96(4):1308–1320

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hämäläinen K, Hämäläinen U (2005) A lost generation? State dependence in unemployment among labour market entrants in different phases of business cycle. Paper presented at the European Society for Population Economics Conference, Paris

    Google Scholar 

  • Im KS, Pesaran MH, Shin Y (2003) Testing for unit roots in heterogeneous panels. J Econ 115(1):53–74

    Google Scholar 

  • Jäntti M, Bratsberg B, Røed K, Raaum O, Naylor R, Österbacka E, Björklund A, Eriksson T (2007) American exceptionalism in a new light: a comparison of intergenerational earnings mobility in the Nordic countries, the United Kingdom and the United States. The Warwick Economics Research Paper Series, Department of Economics, University of Warwick, Warwick

  • Jenkins S (1987) Snapshots versus movies: ‘lifecycle biases’ and the estimation of intergenerational earnings inheritance. Eur Econ Rev 31(5):1149–1158

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jeon Y, Shields MP (2005) The Easterlin hypothesis in the recent experience of higher-income OECD countries: a panel-data approach. J Popul Econ 18(1):1–13

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jürges H (2000) Of rotten kids and Rawlsian parents: the optimal timing of intergenerational transfers. J Popul Econ 13(1):147–157

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lee C-I, Solon G (2009) Trends in intergenerational income mobility. Rev Econ Stat 91(4):766–772

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Levine DI, Mazumder B (2002) Choosing the right parents: changes in the intergenerational transmission of inequality between 1980 and the early 1990s. Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago Working Paper 2002-8, Chicago

  • Lillard LA, Kilburn RM (1997) Assortative mating and family links in permanent earnings. Rand Corporation Report DRU/1578/NIA, Santa Monica

  • Liu H, Zeng J (2009) Genetic ability and intergenerational earnings mobility. J Popul Econ 22(1):75–95

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lochner LJ, Monge-Naranjo A (2011) The nature of credit constraints and human capital. Am Econ Rev 101(6):2487–2529

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mazumder B (2005) Fortunate sons: new estimates of intergenerational mobility in the United States using social security earnings data. Rev Econ Stat 87(2):235–255

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mulligan CB (1997) Parental priorities and economic inequality. University of Chicago Press, Chicago

    Google Scholar 

  • Mulligan CB (1999) Galton versus the human capital approach to inheritance. J Polit Econ 107(6):S184–S224

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Oreopoulos P, Page M, Stevens AH (2008) The intergenerational effects of worker displacement. J Labor Econ 26(3):455–83

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Österbacka E (2001) Family background and economic status in Finland. Scand J Econ 103(3):467–484

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Österberg T (2000) Intergenerational income mobility in Sweden: what do tax-data show? Rev Income Wealth 46(4):421–436

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pekkala SA, Lucas REB (2007) Differences across cohorts in Finnish intergenerational income mobility. Ind Relat Symp Trends Intergenerational Mobil 46(1):81–111

    Google Scholar 

  • Pekkarinen T, Uusitalo R, Kerr SP (2009) School tracking and intergenerational income mobility: evidence from the Finnish comprehensive school reform. J Public Econ 93(7–8):965–973

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Plug E, Vijverberg W (2003) Schooling, family background, and adoption: is it nature or is it nurture? J Polit Econ 111(3):611–641

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Plug E, Vijverberg W (2005) Does family income matter for schooling outcomes? Using adoptees as a natural experiment. Econ J 115(506):879–906

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Population Research Institute (1995) Lapsi-Perhe Suomessa (Child families in Finland). Population Research Institute, Helsinki

    Google Scholar 

  • Pronzato C (2012) An examination of paternal and maternal intergenerational transmission of schooling. J Popul Econ 25(2):591–608

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Restuccia D, Urrutia C (2004) Intergenerational persistence of earnings: the role of early and college education. Am Econ Rev 94(5):1354–1378

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Robertson M, Roy AS (1982) Fertility, labor force participation and the relative income hypothesis: an empirical test of the Easterlin-Wachter model on the basis of Canadian experience. Am J Econ Sociol 41(4):339–350

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sacerdote B (2007) How large are the effects from changes in family environment? A study of Korean American adoptees. Q J Econ 122(1):119–157

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Solon G (1992) Intergenerational income mobility in the United States. Am Econ Rev 82(3):393–408

    Google Scholar 

  • Solon G (1999) Intergenerational mobility in the labor market. In: Ashenfelter O, Card D (eds) Handbook of labor economics, vol 3A. Elsevier, Amsterdam, pp 1761–1800

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Solon G (2002) Cross-country differences in intergenerational earnings mobility. J Econ Perspect 16(3):59–66

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Statistics Finland (1995) Population census: 1995 handbook. Statistics Finland, Helsinki

    Google Scholar 

  • Warren JR, Hauser RM (1997) Social stratification across three generations: new evidence from the Wisconsin longitudinal study. Am Sociol Rev 62(4):561–572

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Zimmerman DJ (1992) Regression toward mediocrity in economic stature. Am Econ Rev 82(3):402–429

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

The authors are most grateful to the Academy of Finland for the partial funding of this study under project number 52198. The paper has benefitted considerably from the constructive comments and suggestions of an anonymous referee as well as those of Joshua Angrist, David Autor, Markus Jäntti, Kevin Lang, and Dilip Mookherjee.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Robert E. B. Lucas.

Additional information

Responsible editor: Alessandro Cigno

Electronic Supplementary Material

Below is the link to the electronic supplementary material.

(PDF 155 KB)

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Lucas, R.E.B., Kerr, S.P. Intergenerational income immobility in Finland: contrasting roles for parental earnings and family income. J Popul Econ 26, 1057–1094 (2013). https://doi.org/10.1007/s00148-012-0442-8

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s00148-012-0442-8

Keyword

JEL Classification

Navigation