Skip to main content
Log in

Optimal licensing under incomplete information: the case of the inside patent holder

  • Research Article
  • Published:
Economic Theory Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

We reconsider the inside patent holders’ optimal licensing problem of non-drastic and (super-) drastic innovations under incomplete information, taking into account restrictions concerning royalty rates and the use of exclusive licenses implied by antitrust rules. We employ methods developed in the analysis of license auctions with downstream interaction and optimal control theory. Our analysis differs from the literature which assumed particular patterns of cost reductions across firms induced by the innovation and either complete information or particular probability distributions.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. See also Calvert (1964), Taylor and Silberston (1973), Macho-Stadler et al. (1996), and Vishwasrao (2007) on foreign technology licensing to Indian firms.

  2. An extension of this analysis to three firms is in Wang et al. (2013).

  3. This symmetry assumption is not essential and used only to simplify the notation.

  4. By the well-known revelation principle, using a direct mechanism is simply a methodological device to solve optimal mechanisms. The optimal mechanism is equivalent to an indirect mechanism that offers a menu of contracts, (rf), from which the licensee can choose freely, without asking the licensee to report his unit cost.

  5. In the present framework, the rival’s output can be inferred. Inspection is only necessary if demand is subject to shocks or if there are more than two firms. However, inspection may be necessary in order to be prepared for the event of litigation.

  6. According to the Antitrust Guidelines for the Licensing of Intellectual Property in the U.S.: “Generally, an exclusive license may raise antitrust concerns only if the licensees themselves, or the licensor and its licensees, are in a horizontal relationship. Examples of arrangements involving exclusive licensing that may give rise to antitrust concerns include ...acquisitions of intellectual property rights” (US Department of Justice and Federal Trade Commission 1995, Section 4.1.2).

  7. Licensing agreements for intellectual property are typically illegal if they involve naked price-fixing, output restrictions, or market division (US Department of Justice and Federal Trade Commission 1995).

  8. To the best of our knowledge, the upper-bound constraint is generally used in the literature that deals with licensing in oligopoly markets and cares about antitrust concerns. The constraint is not invoked when a license is awarded to a firm that is already a monopoly, as in Macho Stadler and Pérez-Castrillo (1991, Sec. 3) and Sen (2005). We also mention that some authors allow for slightly negative royalty rates (see, for example, Liao and Sen 2005; Anderson 2014).

  9. “Quite appropriately, contracts of this form would likely be held to be illegal by antitrust authorities” (Katz and Shapiro 1985, p. 513).

  10. This procedure is similar to the solution method employed in the analysis of license auctions with downstream interaction (see Das Varma (2003), Goeree (2003) and Fan et al. (2013, 2014)).

  11. The explicit statement of the f function requires tedious case distinctions concerning \(\hat{x}\), and is therefore relegated to the “Appendix A.1”. Nevertheless, (17) fully explains all properties of f(x) stated in Proposition 1.

  12. For example, in the theory of price discrimination by Maskin and Riley (1984) screening requires the use of two state-dependent variables: price and quantity.

  13. The exact values are: \(\left( x_1, x_2, \hat{x}\right) = \left( 0.025, \, 0.058, \, 0.134 \right) \), and \((r(x),f(x))=\left( 0 , \,\, {57917}/{720000} - {5x}/{36}+{x^2}/{9} \right) \) for \(x \le x_1\), \((r(x),f(x))= \left( 5 x - {1}/{8},\,\, {12463}/{80000}\right. \) \(\left. - {7 x}/{2} +14 x^2 \right) \) for \(x_1 \le x \le x_2\), and \((r(x),f(x))= \left( {850 -3 \sqrt{35259}/}{1600} - {x}/{4}, \,\,0 \right) \) for \(x \ge x_2\).

  14. The no distortion at the top is a typical feature in standard adverse selection problems. However, in the present framework, with downstream interaction, it cannot occur if \(\underline{x} \ge d \).

  15. However, the distribution function of a non-negative random variable cannot be log-convex everywhere (Block et al. 1998, Corollary 2.1).

  16. This result generalizes Heywood et al. (2014) who use a binary model and assume that the patentee is at least as efficient as the potential licensee with probability one.

  17. The detailed proof is in an earlier version of our paper which is available on request from the authors.

  18. Note, we consider a particular mechanism that is restricted to implement a monopoly (see the restriction (19) below). If we allowed for implementing a duopoly in some states, the analysis would be far more complicated.

  19. Note, if only non-exclusive licenses were permitted, constraint (19) would have to be replaced by: \(r(x) \le 2d- 1-x\).

  20. According to the Antitrust Guidelines: “If the Agencies conclude ...that a restraint in a licensing arrangement is unlikely to have an anticompetitive effect, they will not challenge the restraint” (US Department of Justice and Federal Trade Commission 1995, Section 4.2).

  21. The proof is straightforward and hence omitted.

  22. The present control problem is subject to inequality constraints concerning the state variables and some free and fixed endpoints. The corresponding conditions for optimality can be found in (Kamien and Schwartz 1991, p. 230ff.).

  23. We extend G outside its support in the obvious way. Therefore the equation has a solution, which may however be below \(\underline{x}\).

  24. In one case we prove incentive compatibility by showing that \(\Pi _2(x,z)\) is pseudoconcave in z. The function \(\Pi _2(x,z)\) is “pseudoconcave” in z if, for all x, it is increasing to the left of its stationary point and decreasing to the right. Due to the first-order condition for incentive compatibility \(\Pi _2(x,z)\) has a stationary point at \(z=x\), i.e., for all x. Evidently, pseudoconcavity assures that the stationary points are global maxima.

References

  • Amir, R., Encaoua, D., Lefouili, Y.: Optimal licensing of uncertain patents in the shadow of litigation. Games Econ. Behav. 88, 320–338 (2014)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Anderson, F.: Licensing to a more efficient rival. Manch. Sch. 82, 653–676 (2014)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bagnoli, M., Bergstrom, T.: Log-concave probability and its applications. Econ. Theory 26, 445–469 (2005)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Beggs, A.: The licensing of patents under asymmetric information. Int. J. Ind. Organ. 10, 171–191 (1992)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Block, H., Savits, T., Singh, H.: The reversed hazard rate function. Probab. Eng. Inf. Sci. 12, 69–90 (1998)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brousseau, E., Coeurderoy, R., Chaserant, C.: The governance of contracts: empirical evidence on technology licensing agreements. J. Inst. Theor. Econ. 163, 205–235 (2007)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Calvert, R.: The Encyclopedia of Patent Practice and Invention Management. Reinhold, New York (1964)

    Google Scholar 

  • Choi, J.: Technology transfer with moral hazard. Int. J. Ind. Organ. 19, 249–266 (2001)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Das Varma, G.: Bidding for a process innovation under alternative modes of competition. Int. J. Ind. Organ. 21, 15–37 (2003)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Encaoua, D., Lefouili, Y.: Licensing ‘weak’ patents. J. Ind. Econ. 57, 492–525 (2009)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fan, C., Jun, B., Wolfstetter, E.: Licensing process innovations when losers’ messages determine royalty rates. Games Econ. Behav. 82, 388–402 (2013)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fan, C., Jun, B., Wolfstetter, E.: Licensing a common value innovation in oligopoly when signaling strength may backfire. Int. J. Game Theory 43, 215–244 (2014)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Farrell, J., Shapiro, C.: How strong are weak patents? Am. Econ. Rev. 98, 1347–1369 (2008)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gallini, N., Wright, B.: Technology transfer under asymmetric information. RAND J. Econ. 21(1), 147–160 (1990)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Giebe, T., Wolfstetter, E.: License auctions with royalty contracts for (winners and) losers. Games Econ. Behav. 63, 91–106 (2008)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Goeree, J.: Bidding for the future: signaling in auctions with an aftermarket. J. Econ. Theory 108, 345–364 (2003)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Heywood, J., Li, J., Ye, G.: Per unit vs. ad valorem royalties under asymmetric information. Int. J. Ind. Organ. 37, 38–46 (2014)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jones, M.: Kumaraswamy’s distribution: a beta-type distribution with some tractability advantages. Stat. Methodol. 6, 70–81 (2009)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kamien, M.: Patent licensing. In: Aumann, R., Hart, S. (eds.) Handbook of Game Theory, vol. I, pp. 331–354. Elsevier, Amsterdam (1992)

    Google Scholar 

  • Kamien, M., Schwartz, N.: Dynamic Optimization: The Calculus of Variations and Optimal Control in Economics and Management, 2nd edn. North-Holland, Amsterdam (1991)

    Google Scholar 

  • Kamien, M., Tauman, Y.: The private value of a patent: a game theoretic analysis. J. Econ. 4, 93–118 (1984)

    Google Scholar 

  • Kamien, M., Tauman, Y.: Fee versus royalties and the private value of a patent. Q. J. Econ. 101, 471–491 (1986)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kamien, M., Tauman, Y.: Patent licensing: the inside story. Manch. Sch. 70, 7–15 (2002)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Katz, M., Shapiro, C.: On the licensing of innovations. RAND J. Econ. 16(4), 504–520 (1985)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kumaraswamy, P.: A generalized probability density function for double-bounded random processes. J. Hydrol. 46, 79–88 (1980)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lemley, M., Shapiro, C.: Probabilistic patents. J. Econ. Perspect. 19, 75–98 (2005)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Liao, H., Sen, D.: Subsidy in licensing: optimality and welfare implications. Manch. Sch. 73, 281–299 (2005)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Macho-Stadler, I., Pérez-Castrillo, D.: Contrats de licences et asymétrie d’information. Ann. Econ. Stat. 24, 189–208 (1991)

    Google Scholar 

  • Macho-Stadler, I., Martínez-Giralt, X., Pérez-Castrillo, D.: The role of information in licensing contract design. Res. Policy 25, 25–41 (1996)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Maskin, E., Riley, J.: Monopoly with incomplete information. RAND J. Econ. 15, 171–196 (1984)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Milgrom, P.: Auction theory. In: Bewley, T.E. (ed.) Advances in Economic Theory, Econometric Society Monographs, vol. 12, pp. 1–32. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge (1987)

    Google Scholar 

  • Poddar, S., Sinha, U.: Patent licensing from a high-cost firm to a low-cost firm. Econ. Rec. 86, 384–395 (2010)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rostoker, M.: A survey of corporate licensing. IDEA 24, 59–92 (1984)

    Google Scholar 

  • Seierstad, A., Sydstæter, K.: Sufficient conditions in optimal control theory. Int. Econ. Rev. 18, 367–391 (1977)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sen, D.: On the coexistence of different licensing schemes. Int. Rev. Econ. Finance 14, 393–413 (2005)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sen, D., Tauman, Y.: General licensing schemes for a cost-reducing innovation. Games Econ. Behav. 59, 163–186 (2007)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Shapiro, C.: Patent licensing and R&D rivalry. Am. Econ. Rev. Pap. Proc. 75(2), 25–30 (1985)

    Google Scholar 

  • Taylor, C., Silberston, Z.: The Economic Impact of the Patent System. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge (1973)

    Google Scholar 

  • US Department of Justice and Federal Trade Commission: Antitrust Guidelines for Licensing of Intellectual Property. Washington, DC. (1995)

  • Vishwasrao, S.: Royalties vs. fees: How do firms pay for foreign technology? Int. J. Ind. Organ. 25, 741–759 (2007)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wang, K., Liang, W., Chou, P.: Patent licensing under cost asymmetry among firms. Econ. Model. 31, 297–307 (2013)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wang, X.: Fee versus royalty licensing in a Cournot duopoly model. Econ. Lett. 60, 55–62 (1998)

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

We thank the anonymous referees for detailed and constructive comments and suggestions.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Cuihong Fan.

Additional information

Financial support by the National Natural Science Foundation of China (Grant: 71371116), Korea University (Grant: K1509111), and the Deutsche Forschungsgemeinschaft (SFB Transregio 15, “Governance and Efficiency of Economic Systems”) is gratefully acknowledged.

A Appendix

A Appendix

1.1 A.1 Proof of Proposition 1

As a preliminary, note that it is optimal to adopt the highest possible fixed fee. This allows us to replace the participation constraint (13) by

$$\begin{aligned} f(\hat{x})=\pi _2(q_1^*(\hat{x}), q_2^*(\hat{x});\hat{x}+r(\hat{x}))- \Pi _2^N. \end{aligned}$$
(A.1)

Step 1:   Consider the patentee’s maximization problem:

$$\begin{aligned} \max _{r,f, \hat{x}} \Pi _1= & {} \int _{\underline{x} }^{\hat{x} } \left( \pi _1^*(x) + r(x) q_2^*(x)+f(x)\right) dG(x) \nonumber \\&+ \pi _{1}\left( q_{1}^N, q_{2}^N;d\right) (1-G(\hat{x} )) \end{aligned}$$
(A.2)

s.t. (10), (14), (15), (A.1).

We solve (A.2) as an optimal control problem for given \(\hat{x}\), then characterize the optimal \(\hat{x}\), and confirm that the ignored constraint is never binding.

To translate (A.2) into an optimal control problem define the control variable, \(u(x){:}=r'(x)\), the state variables r(x), f(x), the constraint functions \(g_1, g_2, k_1, k_2\), the co-state variables, \(\lambda _1(x)\), \(\lambda _2(x)\), \(\eta _1(x)\), \(\eta _2(x)\) and the Hamiltonian, \(H(x, r,f,u,\lambda _1, \lambda _2, \eta _1, \eta _2)\):

$$\begin{aligned}&H(x,r,f,u,\lambda _1,\lambda _2,\eta _1, \eta _2): = h(x, r, f) + \lambda _1(x) g_1 + \lambda _2(x) g_2\nonumber \\&\quad +\, \eta _1(x)k_1 + \eta _2(x)k_2 \end{aligned}$$
(A.3)
$$\begin{aligned}&h {:}= \left( \left( \frac{1-2d+x+r(x)}{3}\right) ^2 +r(x) \frac{1-2 x - 2 r(x)+d }{3} +f(x)\right) G'(x)\qquad \qquad \end{aligned}$$
(A.4)
$$\begin{aligned}&g_1{:}= u(x), \quad g_2 {:}= - \frac{1}{9} \left( 1 + d - 2 x - 2 r(x) \right) (1 + 4 u(x)) \end{aligned}$$
(A.5)
$$\begin{aligned}&k_1{:}=r(x), \quad k_2{:}= c- \frac{3 \hat{x}+x}{4}-r(x). \end{aligned}$$
(A.6)

There, \(g_2\) corresponds to the incentive compatibility conditions (10), and \(k_1, k_2\) to the constraints, (14), (15). The endpoints \(f(\hat{x})\) and \(r(\hat{x})\) are not free (see A.1) and the endpoints \(f(\underline{x})\), \(r(\underline{x})\) are free.

The maximum principle requires that the following conditions are satisfied:Footnote 22

$$\begin{aligned} 0= & {} \partial _u H = \lambda _1(x) - \frac{4 \lambda _2(x)}{9} \left( 1 + d - 2 x - 2 r(x) \right) \end{aligned}$$
(A.7)
$$\begin{aligned} \lambda _1'(x)= & {} - \partial _r H = -\eta _1+\eta _2 - \frac{2 \lambda _2(x) (1+ 4 u(x)) + (5-d-4 x -10 r(x)) G'(x)}{9} \nonumber \\ \end{aligned}$$
(A.8)
$$\begin{aligned} \lambda _2'(x)= & {} - \partial _{f} H = - G'(x) \quad \end{aligned}$$
(A.9)
$$\begin{aligned} r'(x)= & {} \partial _{\lambda _1} H = u(x) \end{aligned}$$
(A.10)
$$\begin{aligned} f'(x)= & {} \partial _{\lambda _2} H = - \frac{1}{9} \left( 1 + d - 2 x - 2 r(x) \right) (1 + 4 u(x)) \end{aligned}$$
(A.11)
$$\begin{aligned} f(\hat{x})= & {} \left( \frac{1-2(\hat{x}+r(\hat{x}))+d}{3} \right) ^2 - \left( \frac{1-2 c+d}{3} \right) ^2 \end{aligned}$$
(A.12)
$$\begin{aligned} \lambda _1(\underline{x})= & {} \lambda _2(\underline{x}) = 0 \end{aligned}$$
(A.13)
$$\begin{aligned} \eta _1(x)\ge & {} 0, \quad k_1=r(x) \ge 0, \quad \eta _1(x)k_1 = 0. \end{aligned}$$
(A.14)
$$\begin{aligned} \eta _2(x)\ge & {} 0, \quad k_2=c- \frac{3 \hat{x}+x}{4}-r(x) \ge 0, \quad \eta _2(x)k_2 = 0, \end{aligned}$$
(A.15)

Step 2: Deriving r(x). (A.9) and (A.13) yield \(\lambda _2(x)= -G(x)\). Inserting this into (A.7) yields

$$\begin{aligned} \lambda _1(x) = -\frac{4 G(x)}{9} \left( 1 + d - 2 x - 2 r(x) \right) . \end{aligned}$$
(A.16)

Differentiating (A.16) and equating with (A.8) yields:

$$\begin{aligned} r(x) = \frac{1-5 d+4 x}{2} + \frac{6 G(x)+9 (\eta _1- \eta _2)}{2 G'(x)}. \end{aligned}$$
(A.17)

Define \(\eta {:}=(\eta _1,\eta _2)\) and:

(A.18)

Consider the function . Because , by (18), the equation has a unique solution denoted by \(x_1\) and:Footnote 23

(A.19)

Similarly, consider the function . Because , the equation has a unique solution denoted by \(x_2\) (which may be above \(\hat{x}\) or even \(\bar{x}\)) and:

(A.20)

By the definition of \(x_1\) we have \(r_0(x_1)=0\); hence

(A.21)

which implies \(x_1 < x_2\).

Also we have

(A.22)
(A.23)

We now derive the asserted r(x) function.

r(x) is zero on \([\underline{x},x_1]\), increasing on \([x_1,x_2]\), which confirms that the ignored constraint is not binding there, and decreasing on \([x_2,\hat{x}]\), as asserted.

Step 3: Deriving f(x). Denote the unique solution to the equation \(c-x=r_0(x)\) by \(x_0\), then we have

(A.24)

We distinguish three cases: Case 1: \(\varvec{\hat{x}} \ge \varvec{x}_0\). In this case we have \(x_1\le x_2\le \hat{x}\) by (A.24) and \(r(\hat{x})=c-\hat{x}\). Thus \(f(\hat{x})=0\).

$$\begin{aligned} x \in [x_2, \hat{x}]\Rightarrow & {} 1+4 r'(x) =0 \Rightarrow f'(x)=0 \Rightarrow f(x) = f(\hat{x}) \\&- \int _{x}^{\hat{x}}f'(y)dy= f(\hat{x})= 0\\ x \in [x_1, x_2]\Rightarrow & {} f'(x)=-\frac{1}{9} (1+d-2 x-2 r_0(x)) \left( 1+4 r_0'(x)\right) \\ {}= & {} -q_2^*(x) \left( 3+4 \Big (\frac{G(x)}{G'(x)}\Big )' \right) \\\Rightarrow & {} f(x)=f(x_2)+\int _{x}^{x_2} q_2^*(y) \left( 3+4 \Big (\frac{G(y)}{G'(y)}\Big )' \right) dy \\ {}= & {} \int _{x}^{x_2} q_2^*(y) \left( 3+4 \Big (\frac{G(y)}{G'(y)}\Big )' \right) dy\\ x \in [\underline{x},x_1]\Rightarrow & {} r(x)=r'(x) =0 \Rightarrow f'(x)=- \frac{1}{9} \left( 1 + d - 2 x\right) =-\frac{q_2^*(x)}{3}<0 \\\Rightarrow & {} f(x) = f(x_1) - \int _{x}^{x_1}f'(y)dy\\= & {} f(x_1)+\frac{1}{9}(x_1-x)(1+d-x_1-x). \end{aligned}$$

In this case f(x) is positive and decreasing on \([\underline{x}, x_2)\) and equal to zero on \([x_2,\hat{x}]\).

Case 2: \(\varvec{\hat{x}} <\varvec{x}_0~\text {and}~\varvec{\hat{x}}>\varvec{x}_1\). In this case we have \(x_1< \hat{x} <x_2\) by (A.24). Thus, \(k_2(\hat{x})>0\), which implies \(r(\hat{x})<c-\hat{x}\), and \(f(\hat{x})=\pi _2(q_1^*(\hat{x}), q_2^*(\hat{x});\hat{x}+r(\hat{x}))- \Pi _2^N>0\).

$$\begin{aligned} x \in [x_1, \hat{x})\Rightarrow & {} f'(x)=-\frac{1}{9} (1+d-2 x-2 r_0(x)) \left( 1+4 r_0'(x)\right) \\= & {} -q_2^*(x) \left( 3+4 \Big (\frac{G(x)}{G'(x)}\Big )' \right) \\\Rightarrow & {} f(x)=f(\hat{x})+\int _{x}^{\hat{x}} q_2^*(y) \left( 3+4 \Big (\frac{G(y)}{G'(y)}\Big )' \right) dy \\ x \in [\underline{x},x_1]\Rightarrow & {} r(x)=r'(x) =0 \Rightarrow f'(x)=- \frac{1}{9} \left( 1 + d - 2 x\right) \\\Rightarrow & {} f(x) = f(x_1) - \int _{x}^{x_1}f'(y)dy\\= & {} f(x_1)+\frac{1}{9}(x_1-x)(1+d-x_1-x). \end{aligned}$$

In this case f(x) is positive and decreasing on \([\underline{x}, \hat{x}]\).

Case 3: \(\varvec{\hat{x}} <\varvec{x}_0~\text {and}~\varvec{\hat{x}}\le \varvec{x}_1~(\le \varvec{x}_2)\). In this case we have \(f(\hat{x})=\pi _2(q_1^*(\hat{x}), q_2^*(\hat{x});\hat{x}+r(\hat{x}))- \Pi _2^N\).

$$\begin{aligned} x \in [\underline{x},\hat{x}]\Rightarrow & {} r(x)=r'(x) =0 \Rightarrow f'(x)=- \frac{1}{9} \left( 1 + d - 2 x\right) \\\Rightarrow & {} f(x) = f(\hat{x}) - \int _{x}^{\hat{x}}f'(y)dy =f(\hat{x}) +\frac{1}{9}(\hat{x}-x)(1+d-\hat{x}-x). \end{aligned}$$

In this case f(x) is positive and decreasing.

Step 4: Global incentive compatibility and second-order conditions.

Next, we confirm incentive compatibility.Footnote 24

  1. (a)

    For \(x,z \ge x_2\), we have \(\Pi _2(x,x) = \Pi _2(x,z)=\frac{1}{36} (2-4 c+2 d+3 \hat{x}-3 x)^2\).

  2. (b)

    For \(x,z \in [x_1, x_2]\), we have \(\partial _{zx}\Pi _2(x,z)=\frac{1}{6} \left( 1+4 r'(z)\right) >0\).

  3. (c)

    For \(x_1\le z<x_2\le x\), we have \(\Pi _2(x_2,x_2)-\Pi _2(x_2,z)\ge 0\) from (b) and

    $$\begin{aligned} \left( \Pi _2(x,x)-\Pi _2(x,z)\right) -\left( \Pi _2(x_2,x_2)-\Pi _2(x_2,z)\right) = \frac{2}{3} (x-x_2)k_2(z) \ge 0, \end{aligned}$$

    which implies \(\Pi _2(x,x)-\Pi _2(x,z)\ge 0\).

  4. (d)

    For \(x_1 \le x<x_2\le z\), we have \(\Pi _2(x,x)\ge \Pi _2(x,x_2)=\Pi _2(x,z)\).

  5. (e)

    For \(x,z \le x_1\), we have \(\Pi _2(x,z) =\frac{1}{36} (2+2 d-3 x-z)^2-f(x_1)-\frac{1}{9}(x_1-z)(1+d-x_1-z)\). Thus, \(\partial _{zx} \Pi _2(x,z) ={1}/{6}>0\).

  6. (f)

    For \(x\le x_1 <z \le x_2\), we have \(\Pi _2(x_1,x_1)-\Pi _2(x_1,z)\ge 0\) from (b) and

    $$\begin{aligned}&\left( \Pi _2(x,x)-\Pi _2(x,z)\right) -\left( \Pi _2(x_1,x_1)-\Pi _2(x_1,z)\right) \\&= \frac{x_1-x}{12}\left( 8r_0(z)+ 2z-x_1-x\right) \ge 0, \end{aligned}$$

    which implies \(\Pi _2(x,x)-\Pi _2(x,z)\ge 0\).

  7. (g)

    For \(z< x_1 \le x \le x_2\), we have \(\Pi _2(x,x)\ge \Pi _2(x,x_1)=\Pi _2(x,z) +\frac{x_1-z}{12}\left( 2x-x_1-z\right) > \Pi _2(x,z)\).

  8. (h)

    For \(x\le x_1, z \ge x_2\), we have \(\Pi _2(x_1,x_1)-\Pi _2(x_1,z)\ge 0\) from (d) and

    $$\begin{aligned}&\left( \Pi _2(x,x)-\Pi _2(x,z)\right) -\left( \Pi _2(x_1,x_1)-\Pi _2(x_1,z)\right) \\&= \frac{x_1-x}{12}\left( 8r_2(z)+ 2z-x_1-x\right) \ge 0, \end{aligned}$$

    which implies \(\Pi _2(x,x)-\Pi _2(x,z)\ge 0\).

  9. (i)

    For \(x\ge x_2, z\le x_1\), we have \(\Pi _2(x_2,x_2)-\Pi _2(x_2,z)\ge 0\) from (b) and (g) and

    $$\begin{aligned} \left( \Pi _2(x,x)-\Pi _2(x,z)\right) -\left( \Pi _2(x_2,x_2)-\Pi _2(x_2,z)\right) = \frac{x-x_2}{6} (4 c-3 \hat{x}-z) \ge 0, \end{aligned}$$

    which implies \(\Pi _2(x,x)-\Pi _2(x,z)\ge 0\).

Therefore, incentive compatibility is satisfied.

The Arrow Sufficiency Theorem (Seierstad and Sydstæter 1977, Theorem 3) applies, because, at the optimum, \(\lambda _1 g_1 + \lambda _2 g_2 =0\) and \(H^*{:}=\max _u H\) is concave in r and f.

Step 5: \(\hat{x}> \underline{x}\). Denote the maximum expected payoff of the patentee by \(\Pi _1^*(\hat{x})\). We now prove that a contract is awarded with positive probability by showing

(A.25)

We consider three cases: (i) \(\underline{x} \ge x_2\), (ii) \(\underline{x} \in [x_1,x_2)\), (iii) \(\underline{x}<x_1\).

Case (i): If \(\underline{x} \ge x_2\), then \(r(\underline{x})=r_2(\underline{x})\) and we have

(A.26)

Case (ii): If \(\underline{x} \in [x_1,x_2)\), then \(r(\underline{x})=r_0(\underline{x})\) and we have

(A.27)

because the second term in the big bracket is a concave function of d which takes the minimum value 0 at \(d=2c-1\) on \([2c-1,c]\).

Case (iii): If \(\underline{x} <x_1\), then \(r(\underline{x})=0\) and we have

(A.28)

Depending upon the parameters, the optimal \(\hat{x}\) is either a corner solution, \(\hat{x}= \bar{x}\) (no-exclusion), or an interior solution (exclusion). \(\square \)

1.2 A.2 Supplement to the proof of Proposition 2

Here, we supplement the proof of Proposition 2 and show that \(\Pi _1^*(\hat{x})\) increases on \([x_1,x_2)\).

On the interval \([x_1,x_2)\) one has \(r(x)=r_0(x)\). First, suppose \(x_1 < \underline{x}\). Then, the patentee’s expected revenue can be written as

$$\begin{aligned} \Pi _1^*(\hat{x})&=\int _{\underline{x}}^{\hat{x}}\Big (r_0(y)q_2^*(y) + f(y) + \pi _1^*(y) \Big ) dG(y) + (1 - G(\hat{x}))\Pi _1^N. \end{aligned}$$
(A.29)

Its derivative with respect to \(\hat{x}\) is

$$\begin{aligned} {\Pi _1^*}'(\hat{x})= & {} \frac{1}{36G'(\hat{x})}\Big (36 G(\hat{x})^2-72 (d-\hat{x}) G(\hat{x}) G'(\hat{x}) \Big . \nonumber \\&\Big .+\big (1-20 c^2+25 d^2+8 c (1+4 d)+36 \hat{x}^2-2 d (5+36 \hat{x})\big ) G'(\hat{x})^2\Big )\nonumber \\= & {} \frac{1}{36G'(\hat{x})}\Big (36 \big (G(\hat{x})- (d-\hat{x}) G'(\hat{x}) \big )^2 \nonumber \\&+\,(1 + 10 c - 11 d) (d- 2 c +1) G'(\hat{x})^2 \Big ), \end{aligned}$$
(A.30)

which is positive because \(d>2c-1\).

Next, suppose \(x_1 \ge \underline{x}\). Then, \(r(x)=r_1(x)\) on \([\underline{x},x_1]\), and \(\Pi _1\) can be written as

$$\begin{aligned} \Pi _1^*(\hat{x})= & {} \int _{\underline{x}}^{x_1}\Big (r_1(y)q_2^*(y) + f(x_1) + \pi _1^*(y) \Big ) dG(y) \nonumber \\&+ \int _{x_1}^{\hat{x}}\Big (r_0(y)q_2^*(y) + f(y) + \pi _1^*(y) \Big ) dG(y) + (1 - G(\hat{x}))\Pi _1^N.\qquad \quad \end{aligned}$$
(A.31)

The derivative of \(\Pi _1^*(\hat{x})\) with respect to \(\hat{x}\) is exactly the same as above, which completes the proof. \(\square \)

1.3 A.3 Supplement to the proof of Proposition 3

By Proposition 1 it is sufficient to show that \(x_2 \le \underline{x}\). This holds true if and only if , which confirms as follows:

(A.32)

\(\square \)

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Fan, C., Jun, B.H. & Wolfstetter, E.G. Optimal licensing under incomplete information: the case of the inside patent holder. Econ Theory 66, 979–1005 (2018). https://doi.org/10.1007/s00199-017-1077-5

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s00199-017-1077-5

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation