Skip to main content
Log in

‘One and a Half Dimensional’ Preferences and Majority Rule

  • Original Paper
  • Published:
Social Choice and Welfare Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

I examine a model of majority rule in which alternatives are described by two characteristics: (1) their position in a standard, left-right dimension, and (2) their position in a good-bad dimension, over which voters have identical preferences. I show that when voters’ preferences are single-peaked and concave over the first dimension, majority rule is transitive, and the majority’s preferences are identical to the median voter’s. Thus, Black’s (The theory of committees and elections, 1958) theorem extends to such a “one and a half” dimensional framework. Meanwhile, another well-known result of majority rule, Downs’ (An economic theory of democracy, 1957) electoral competition model, does not extend to the framework. The condition that preferences can be represented in a one-and-a-half-dimensional framework is strictly weaker than the condition that preferences be single-peaked and symmetric. The condition is strictly stronger than the condition that preferences be order-restricted, as defined by Rothstein (Soc Choice Welf 7:331–342;1990).

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

References

  • Alvarez M, Nagler J (1998) When politics and models collide: estimating models of multi-candidate elections. Am J Pol Sci 42:131–150

    Google Scholar 

  • Ansolabehere S, Snyder JM, Jr. (2000) Valence politics and equilibrium in spatial election models. Pub Choice 103:327–336

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Aragones E, Palfrey T (2002) Mixed equilibrium in a downsian model. J Econ Theory 103: 131–161

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Aragones E, Palfrey T (2005) Electoral competition between two candidates of different quality: the effects of candidate ideology and private information. In: Austen-Smith D, Duggan J (eds) Social choice and strategic decisions: essays in Honor of Jeffey S Banks. Springer, Berlin Heiderberg Neywork, pp 93–112

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Austen-Smith D (1987) Interest groups, campaign contributions, and pluralistic voting. Pub Choice 54:123–137

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Austen-Smith D, Banks J (1999) Positive political theory I: collective preference. University of Michigan Press, Ann Arbor

    Google Scholar 

  • Banks J, Sundaram RK (1993) Moral hazard and adverse selection in a model of repeated elections. In: Barnett WA, Hinich MJ, Schofield NJ (eds) Political economy: institutions, competition, and representation. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Berger MM, Munger MC, Potthoff RF (2000) The Downsian model predicts divergence. J Theorl Polit 12:228–240

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bernhardt MD, Ingberman DE (1985) Candidate reputations and the ‘Incumbency Effect’. J Pub Econ 27:47–67

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Black D (1958) The theory of committees and elections. Cambridge University Press, London

    Google Scholar 

  • Butler D, Stokes D (1969) Political change in Britain. St. Martin’s Press, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Calvert RL (1985) Robustness of the multidimensional voting model: candidate motivations, uncertainty, and convergence. Am J Pol Sci 29:69–95

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cameron CM, Enelow JM (1992) Assymetric policy effects, campaign contributions, and spatial theory of elections. Math Comput Model 16:117–132

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cukierman A (1991) Asymmetric information and the electoral momentum of public opinion polls. Pub Choice 70:181–213

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Denzau AT, Parks RP (1975) The continuity of majority-rule equilibrium. Econometrica 43: 853–866

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Denzau AT, Parks RP (1983) Existence of voting-market equilibria. J Econ Theory 30:243–65

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Downs A (1957) An economic theory of democracy. Harper & Row, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Dunz K (1989) Some comments on majority rule equilibria in local public good economies. J Econ Theory 47:228–234

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Enelow JM, Endersby JW, Munger MC (1993) A revised probabilistic spatial model of elections: theory and evidence. In: Grofman B (eds) Information, participation, and choice: an economic theory of democracy in perspective. The University of Michigan Press, Ann Arbor

    Google Scholar 

  • Enelow JM, Hinich MJ (1981) A new approach to voter uncertainty in the downsian model. Am J Pol Science 25:483–493

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Enelow JM, Hinich MJ (1982) Nonspatial candidate characteristics and electoral competition. J Polit 44:115–130

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Enelow JM, Hinich MJ (1984) The spatial theory of voting: an introduction. Cambridge University Press, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Fiorina M (1977) Representives, roll-Calls, and constituencies. Lexington Books, Lexington

    Google Scholar 

  • Fiorina M (1981) Retrospective voting in American national elections. Yale University Press, New Haven

    Google Scholar 

  • Gans JS, Smart M (1996) Majority voting with single-crossing preferences. J Pub Econ 59: 219–237

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gersbach H (1995) Competing for donors. Alfred-Weber-Institute, Heidelberg

    Google Scholar 

  • Groseclose T (2001a) A model of candidate location when one candidate has a valence advantage. Am J Pol Sci 45:862–886

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Groseclose T (2001b) A Model of candidate location when one candidate has a Valence advantage – extended version. http://www.polisci.ucla.edu/faculty/groseclose/Working.Papers/Model.of.Candidate.Extended.Vers.pdf

  • Harrington JE Jr, Hess GD (1996) A spatial theory of positive and negative campaigning. Games Econ Behav 17:209–229

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Heckman JJ, Snyder JM Jr (1997) Linear probability models of the demand for attibutes with an empirical application to estimating the preferences of legislators. RAND J Econ 28:S142–S189

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hinich MJ, Munger MC (1989) Political investment, voter perceptions, and candidate strategy: an equilibrium spatial analysis. In: Ordeshook PC (eds) Models of strategic choice in politics. University of Michigan Press, Ann Arbor

    Google Scholar 

  • Hinich MJ, Munger MC (1994) Ideology and the theory of political choice. University of Michigan Press, Ann Arbor

    Google Scholar 

  • Ingbergman DE (1992) Incumbant reputations and ideological campaign contributions in spatial competition. Math Comput Model 16:147–169

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kramer GH (1971) On a class of equilibrium conditions for majority rule. Econometrica 41: 285–297

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Londregan J (2000) Legislative institutions and ideology in chile. Cambridge University Press, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Londregan J, Romer T (1993) Polarization, incumbency, and the personal vote. In: Barnett WA, Hinich MJ, Schofield NJ (eds) Political Economy: institutions, competition, and representation. Cambridge University Press, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • McCarty NM, Poole KT (1995) An empirical analysis of executive and legislative bargaining from 1961–1986. J Law Econ Org 12:282–312

    Google Scholar 

  • Nechyba TJ (2003a) School finance, spatial income segregation and the nature of communities. J Urb Econ 54:61–88

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nechyba TJ (2003b) Centralization, fiscal federalism and private school attendance. Int Econ Rev 44:179–204

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nechyba TJ (2000) Mobility, targeting and private school vouchers. Am Econ Rev 90:130–46

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nechyba TJ (1999) School finance induced migration patterns: the impact of private school vouchers. J Pub Econ Theory 1:5–50

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nechyba TJ (1997a) Local property and state income taxes: the role of interjurisdictional competition and collusion. J Pol Economy 105:351–384

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nechyba TJ (1997b) Existence of equilibrium and stratification in local and hierarchical public Good Economies with property taxes and voting. Econ Theory 10:277–304

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ordeshook PC (1986) Game theory and political theory: an introduction. Cambridge University Press, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Plott CP (1967) A notion of equilibrium under majority rule. Am Econ Rev 57:787–806

    Google Scholar 

  • Poole KT, Rosenthal H (1997) Congress: a political-economic history of roll call voting. Oxford University Press, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Rogoff K (1990) Equilibrium political budget cycles. Am Econ Rev 80:21–396

    Google Scholar 

  • Rogoff K, Sibert A (1988) Elections and macroeconomic policy cycles. Rev Econ Stud 55:1–16

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rothstein P (1990) Order-restricted preferences and majority rule. Soc Choice Welf 7:331–342

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rothstein P (1991) Representative voter theorems. Pub Choice 72:193–212

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Saari DG (1999) The Geometry of Black’s Single Peakedness and Related Conditions. J Math Econ 32:429–56

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Schofield NJ (1983) Generic instability of majority rule. Rev Econ Stud 50:696–705

    Google Scholar 

  • Schofield NJ (2005) A valence model of political competition in britain: 1992–1997. Electoral Stud 24:347–370

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Schofield NJ (2005) Divergence in the spatial stochastic model of voting. Unpublished manuscript. Washington University in St. Louis

  • Schofield NJ, Martin A, Quinn K, Whitford A (1998) Multiparty electoral competitions in the Netherlands and Germany: a model based on multinomial probit. Pub Choice 97:257–293

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Schofield NJ, Sened I (2005) Multiparty competition in Israel: 1988–1996. Br J Pol Sci 35: 635–663

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Schofield NJ, Sened I, Nixon D (1998) Nash equilibrium in multiparty competition with stochastic voters. Ann Op Res 84:3–27

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sen A (1966) A possibility theorem on majority decisions. Econometrica 34:491–499

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sen A (1970) Collective choice and social welfare. Holden-Day Inc., San Francisco

    Google Scholar 

  • Stokes D (1992) Valence politics. In: Kavanagh D (eds) Electoral politics. Clarendon Press, Oxford, pp 141–164

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to T. Groseclose.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Groseclose, T. ‘One and a Half Dimensional’ Preferences and Majority Rule. Soc Choice Welfare 28, 321–335 (2007). https://doi.org/10.1007/s00355-006-0166-3

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s00355-006-0166-3

Keywords

Navigation