Skip to main content
Log in

Conformity and truthful voting under different voting rules

  • Original Paper
  • Published:
Social Choice and Welfare Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Those are my principles, and if you don’t like them...well, I have others.

Groucho Marx.

Abstract

We induce conformity in a binary-decision voting game in which one of the options require certain support (majority, supermajority or unanimity) to be the adopted decision. We consider heterogenous types of voters in that each of them prefer a different outcome in the voting game. We demonstrate theoretically that truthful voting is the unique equilibrium without conformity for each possible voting rule. Introducing conformity enlarges the set of equilibria, which includes voting profiles in which agents do not necessarily vote for their preferred option. If we account for the presence of non-conformist honest voters that vote truthfully for their preferred option, truthful voting is more pervasive for conformist voters in equilibrium. In our setting, the effects of conformity and honest voters on the likelihood of voting truthfully depend on the voting rule that determines whether or not voters are in a decisive group to implement one of the decisions. We provide empirical support for our theoretical predictions by means of a laboratory experiment. Our findings indeed suggest an interplay between the voting rule and the willingness to conform.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. In a binary-decision voting game, one agent instrumentally prefers A to B if she gets the highest possible payoff when option A is adopted.

  2. Agents can have incentives to form coalitions and coordinate their votes; see, e.g., Morelli (2004), Eguia (2011) and the references therein.

  3. We focus on the idea of normative conformity as the willingness to conform in our model stems from a desire to ’fit in’ or be liked. The literature on conformity considers also the possibility that agents follow others because they want to be correct in their decision (informational conformity). Our paper departs from this view because our agents have instrumental preferences over the two options in a way that each type of agent prefers one of the alternatives; i.e., there is no correct decision that will make it optimal for everyone to vote one of the options. Readers interested in informational conformity in voting can consult, among others, Anderson and Holt (1997), Morton and Williams (1999, 2000), Callander (2007), Morton et al. (2012, 2015), Hung and Plott (2001), or Goeree and Yariv (2015).

  4. This resembles the idea in Wright (1990) that “it may be ok to back the loser in a close battle because one has plenty of support in one’s position [but voting] for the loser in a landslide could leave the respondent feeling vulnerable and isolated”.

  5. In a context with private information, Feddersen and Pesendorfer (1998) or Battaglini et al. (2010) refer to these agents as partisan voters. In their setting, partisan voters will ignore any signal about the relevant state of the world to vote for their preferred option in an election. As voters do not receive any signal in our model, we avoid using their terminology.

  6. Importantly, we do not intend to test the existence or the type of conformity that agents may possess motivations to conform; e.g., ethical preferences or a desire to vote for the winner.

  7. Other papers that induce preferences over outcomes in a voting game include, among others, Gerber et al. (1998), Morton and Williams (1999), Kube and Puppe (2009), Battaglini et al. (2010), Bassi et al. (2011) or Van der Straeten et al. (2010, 2013, 2016).

  8. The participation decision in an election is not only affected by the pivot probability (Feddersen and Sandroni 2006; Levine and Palfrey 2007; Duffy and Tavits 2008) but can also be influenced by the willingness to conform (Blais and Hortala-Vallve 2016, 2017; Agranov et al. 2017).

  9. One might think that the preferred choice of agents (i.e., their instrumental preference) is to maximize their material payoff, while the alternative (i.e., their expressive preference) is to maximize the total payoffs or minimize inequality. Tyran and Sausgruber (2006) show that accounting for inequality aversion can explain voting in redistribution problems.

  10. There may be several ways of defining conformity (see Moreno and Ramos-Sosa 2017). For models that assume that agents experience a benefit or cost depending on whether they vote with the majority or for the winner of the election see, among others, Luzzati (1999), Hung and Plott (2001), Callander (2007),Morton et al. (2012), Battaglini et al. (2010), Bassi et al. (2011), Michaeli and Spiro (2015). In Supplementary Appendix B, we develop a simple model in which agents may want to conform for efficiency motives (Feddersen et al. 2009) and discuss the extent to which this model reconciles with the observed behaviour. Overall, we find that the efficiency motive is not the main determinant to conform, but voters may have a tendency to vote for the winning option.

  11. Moreno and Ramos-Sosa (2017) provide the number of honest agents that should vote truthfully within a group to guarantee the truthful outcome. Their results hold for any voting rule \(q\in \{1,n\},\) any number of agents n and any list of agents’ types t.

  12. We decided to have two subjects instead of the computer in the role of honest voters to avoid any concern about social preferences; e.g., type-A agents can vote differently depending on whether they impose an externality on the computer or on another human subject. For the effects of social preferences on bandwagon voting, see Morton and Ou (2015) or Corazzini and Greiner (2007).

  13. For the role of strategic uncertainty see also Bouton et al. (2017a).

  14. The reported p values refer to one-sided alternative. Our findings are robust to other statistical analyses; e.g., test of proportions, Mann–Whitney–Wilcoxon test or robust rank-order test (Feltovich 2003).

  15. This result is robust when we perform the analysis at the individual level (see Supplementary Appendix C) and it is much in line with the comment made by Charles Plott to the authors in the sense that “the votes under majority-rule institutions are typically overwhelming majorities because the minority, when anticipating a loss on the vote, just go along with the majority.”

  16. We cannot rule out the possibility that some type-A agents fail to vote truthfully in the BL treatment because there is noise in our data. We believe, however, that our finding that more than 70% of the type-A agents vote for their preferred option in the BL provide enough support for the hypothesis of truthful voting, especially when we compare these figures with the behaviour of subjects in other voting experiments; e.g., in a simultaneous-voting game, Esponda and Vespa (2014) find that nearly 80% of subjects fail to behave optimally, because they have problems to anticipate the behavior of other voters. Van der Straeten et al. (2010) also find evidence of irrational behavior or noise in that some subjects fail to vote for the closest candidate to their position in the second round of the election in a two-round majority voting rule.

  17. Type-B agents are in the majority group, thus all of them will receive 100 ECUs if option B is elected. The remaining 50 ECUs are obtained by type-A agents under different conditions. For example, type-A agents get the 50 ECUs in BL, regardless of their votes. If \(q=3\), each type-A agent in CON can obtain the 25 ECUs if they both vote truthfully or if they both conform. If \(q=5\), then type-A agents need to conform to attain the maximum possible payoff for the group. If one of the agents votes for A, type-A agents will get 75 or 100 ECUs, but type-B agents will be worse off and the total surplus will not be maximized.

References

  • Abeler J, Nosenzo D, Raymond C (2016) Preferences for truth-telling: a meta study. Econometrica (forthcoming)

  • Agranov M, Goeree JK, Romero J, Yariv L (2017) What makes voters turn out: the effects of polls and beliefs. J Eur Econ Assoc 16(3):825–856

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Alvarez RM, Nagler J (2000) A new approach for modelling strategic voting in multiparty elections. Br J Polit Sci 30(1):57–75

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Anderson LR, Holt CA, Sieberg KK, Oldham AL (2015) An experimental study of jury voting behavior. In: Schofield N, Caballero G (eds) The political economy of governance: institutions, political performance and elections. Springer, Berlin, pp 157–178

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Anderson LR, Holt CA (1997) Information cascades in the laboratory. Am Econ Rev 87(5):847–862

    Google Scholar 

  • Azrieli Y, Chambers CP, Healy PJ (2018) Incentives in experiments: a theoretical analysis. J Polit Econ 126(4):1472–1503

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Battaglini M, Morton RB, Palfrey TR (2010) The swing voter’s curse in the laboratory. Rev Econ Stud 77(1):61–89

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Barberà S, Nicolò A (2016) Information disclosure under strategy-proof voting rules, Barcelona GSE Working Paper Series (2016-904)

  • Bartling B, Fischbacher U, Schudy S (2015) Pivotality and responsibility attribution in sequential voting. J Public Econ 128:133–139

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bassi A (2015) Voting systems and strategic manipulation: an experimental study. J Theor Polit 27(1):58–85

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bassi A, Morton RB, Williams KC (2011) The effects of identities, incentives, and information on voting. J Polit 73(02):558–571

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Blais A, Hortala-Vallve R (2016) Are people more or less inclined to vote when aggregate turnout is high? In: Blais A, Laslier JF, Van der Straeten K (eds) Voting experiments, pp 117–126

  • Blais A, Hortala-Vallve R (2017) Conformity and turnout, mimeo

  • Bouton L, Castanheira M, Llorente-Saguer A (2017a) Multicandidate elections: aggregate uncertainty in the laboratory. Games Econ Behav 101:132–150

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bouton L, Llorente-Saguer A, Malherbe F (2017b) Unanimous rules in the laboratory. Games Econ Behav 102:179–198

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brandts J, Charness G (2011) The strategy versus the direct-response method: a first survey of experimental comparisons. Exp Econ 14(3):375–398

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Callander S (2007) Bandwagons and momentum in sequential voting. Rev Econ Stud 74(3):653–684

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Coate S, Conlin M (2004) A group rule-utilitarian approach to voter turnout: theory and evidence. Am Econ Rev 94:1476–1504

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Corazzini L, Greiner B (2007) Herding, social preferences and (non-) conformity. Econ Lett 97(1):74–80

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Duffy J, Tavits M (2008) Beliefs and voting decisions: a test of the pivotal voter model. Am J Polit Sci 52(3):603–618

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dutta B, Sen A (2012) Nash implementation with partially honest individuals. Games Econ Behav 74(1):154–169

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Eguia JX (2011) Voting blocs, party discipline and party formation. Games Econ Behav 73(1):111–135

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Esponda I, Vespa E (2014) Hypothetical thinking and information extraction in the laboratory. Am Econ J Microecon 6(4):180–202

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Feddersen T, Gailmard S, Sandroni A (2009) Moral bias in large elections: theory and experimental evidence. Am Polit Sci Rev 103(02):175–192

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Feddersen T, Pesendorfer W (1998) Convicting the innocent: the inferiority of unanimous jury verdicts under strategic voting. Am Polit Sci Rev 92(01):23–35

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Feddersen T, Sandroni A (2006) A theory of participation in elections. Am Econ Rev 96(4):1271–1282

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Feltovich N (2003) Nonparametric tests of differences in medians: comparison of the Wilcoxon–Mann–Whitney and robust rank-order tests. Exp Econ 6(3):273–297

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fischbacher U (2007) z-Tree: Zurich toolbox for ready-made economic experiments. Exp Econ 10(2):171–178

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gerber ER, Morton RB, Rietz TA (1998) Minority representation in multimember districts. Am Polit Sci Rev 92(01):127–144

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Goeree JK, Yariv L (2015) Conformity in the Lab. J Econ Sci Assoc 1:15

  • Guarnaschelli S, McKelvey RD, Palfrey TR (2000) An experimental study of jury decision rules. Am Polit Sci Rev 94(02):407–423

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Höchtl W, Sausgruber R, Tyran JR (2012) Inequality aversion and voting on redistribution. Eur Econ Rev 56(7):1406–1421

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hung AA, Plott CR (2001) Information cascades: replication and an extension to majority rule and conformity-rewarding institutions. Am Econ Rev 91(5):1508–1520

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kube S, Puppe C (2009) (When and how) do voters try to manipulate? Public Choice 139:39–52

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Levine D, Palfrey T (2007) The paradox of voter participation? A laboratory study. Am Polit Sci Rev 101:143–158

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lundquist T, Ellingsen T, Gribbe E, Johannesson M (2009) The aversion to lying. J Econ Behav Organ 70(1):81–92

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Luzzati T (1999) Economic theory and conformism, vol 68. Edward Elgar Publishing, Cheltenham

    Google Scholar 

  • Michaeli N, Spiro D (2015) Norm conformity across societies. J Public Econ 132:51–65

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Morelli M (2004) Party formation and policy outcomes under different electoral systems. Rev Econ Stud 71(3):829–853

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Moreno B, Ramos-Sosa MP (2017) Conformity in voting. Social Choice Welf 48:519–543

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Morton RB, Muller D, Page L, Torgler B (2015) Exit polls, turnout, and bandwagon voting: evidence from a natural experiment. Eur Econ Rev 77:65–81

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Morton RB, Ou K (2015) What motivates bandwagon voting behavior: altruism or a desire to win? Eur J Polit Econ 40:224–241

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Morton RB, Piovesan M, Tyran JR (2012) The dark side of the vote: biased voters, social information, and information aggregation through majority voting. Harvard Business School Research Paper (13-017)

  • Morton RB, Williams KC (1999) Information asymmetries and simultaneous versus sequential voting. Am Polit Sci Rev 93(01):51–67

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Morton RB, Williams KC (2000) Learning by voting: sequential choices in presidential primaries and other elections. University of Michigan Press, 2000

  • Palfrey TR (2016) Experiments in political economy. In: Kagel J, Roth A (eds) The handbook of experimental economics. Princeton University Press, Princeton, pp 347–434

    Google Scholar 

  • Rivas J, Rodriguez-Alvarez C (2017) Deliberation, leadership and information aggregation. Manch Sch 85(4):395–429

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sanchez-Pages S, Vorsatz M (2007) An experimental study of truth-telling in a sender-receiver game. Games Econ Behav 61(1):86–112

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Selten R (1967) Die Strategiemethode zur Erforschung des eingeschränkt rationalen Verhaltens im Rahmen eines Oligopolexperiments. In: Sauermann H (ed) Beiträge zur experimentellen Wirtschaftsforschung. Mohr, Tübingen, pp 136–168

    Google Scholar 

  • Smith VL (1976) Experimental economics: induced value theory. Am Econ Rev 66(2):274–279

    Google Scholar 

  • Tyran JR (2004) Voting when money and morals conflict: an experimental test of expressive voting. J Public Econ 88(7):1645–1664

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tyran JR, Sausgruber R (2006) A little fairness may induce a lot of redistribution in democracy. Eur Econ Rev 50(2):469–485

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Van der Straeten K, Laslier JF, Sauger N, Blais A (2010) Strategic, sincere, and heuristic voting under four election rules: an experimental study. Social Choice Welf 35(3):435–472

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Van der Straeten K, Sauger N, Laslier JF, Blais A (2013) Sorting out mechanical and psychological effects in candidate elections: an appraisal with experimental data. Br J Polit Sci 43(4):937–944

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Van der Straeten K, Laslier JF, Blais A (2016) Patterns of strategic voting in run-off elections. In: Blais A, Laslier JF, Van der Straeten K (eds) Voting experiments, pp 215–236

  • Wright GC (1990) Misreports of vote choice in the 1988 NES senate election study. Legis Stud Q 15(4):543–563

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

We would like to thank two anonymous referees for their valuable feedback that really helped to shape the exposition of the paper. We also benefited from comments and suggestions provided by seminar and conferences participants at the Social Choice and Mechanism Design Workshop in Manchester, Middlesex University London, University of Hamburg (UHH). Special thanks to Aniol Llorente-Saguer, Matthias Weber, Paul J. Ferraro, Leeat Yariv, Charlie Plott, Rebecca B. Morton, Daniel Müller, Moti Michaeli, Gary Bolton, Ben Greiner, Collin Raymond, David Hugh-Jones, and Jonathan Lafky who provided very useful references and stimulated discussion through the ESA Group. Financial support from Junta de Andalucía (SEJ-5980) and the Spanish Ministry of Science and Technology (ECO2014-53767-P and ECO2014-58297-R) is gratefully acknowledged. Ismael Rodriguez-Lara wants to thank financial support from FEDER and the Ministerio de Economia y Competitividad under the project CO2017-87245-R.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to María del Pino Ramos-Sosa.

Additional information

Publisher's Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Electronic supplementary material

Below is the link to the electronic supplementary material.

Supplementary material 1 (docx 81 KB)

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Moreno, B., Ramos-Sosa, M.d.P. & Rodriguez-Lara, I. Conformity and truthful voting under different voting rules. Soc Choice Welf 53, 261–282 (2019). https://doi.org/10.1007/s00355-019-01182-w

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s00355-019-01182-w

Navigation