Skip to main content
Log in

Endogenous intangible resources and their place in the institutional hierarchy

  • Original Paper
  • Published:
Review of Regional Research Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

This paper seeks to find evidence for the impact of local culture on the share of intangible investments and the results for productivity per worker in the EU15 countries at the NUTS2 level during the period 2000–2008. The main scope of the paper is to explore the nature and consequences of intangible resources and their hierarchical relationship with culture, thus seeking to identify the genuine endogenous sources of local productivity beyond the standard Romer-type of models. In our study we use basic economic and social indicators from two main sources: the EUROSTAT Regional Database and the European Social Survey (ESS). Regression analysis, based on a pooled cross-section and on a balanced panel through a generalized method of moments (GMM) approach, shows evidence in support of: (i) the classical Tiebout hypothesis on cultural dependence of local public goods in the case of three different types of intangible investments: education, health care, and research and development; (ii) the impact of intangible investments on local productivity which confirms their treatment as investments rather than their usual treatment as a spending category in the national accounts. Clearly, the data set used has its limitations, but what remains most noticeable is the added value of the methodologically alternative measures of local culture employed in our analysis, i.e. a novel cultural attitudes Herfindahl Index, a cultural attitudes Segregation Index, and a CBD (Culture-Based Development) two-vector approach (living culture and cultural heritage). The results generated depict a confirmative picture of the hierarchical relationship between intangible investments, culture and productivity at the regional scale in Europe.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. In another stream of literature this was explained as the result of a Median Voter preference in the locality, i.e. a locally-specific aggregate choice.

  2. This dependence is captured in the CBD notion of cultural gravity. For more details, please see Tubadji and Nijkamp (2015c).

  3. The CBD framework, in general and in this particular case, is always an augmentation and opening of the neo-classical paradigm to additional important previously under-considered or completely overlooked factors. Therefore, we use a model for tapping on tangible capital, by adding to it the tapping on intangible capital as well. Thus a complete, more realistic model is achieved.

  4. The list of intangible investment starts with these three most essential types but is by no means exhausted by them. As clarified in the Introduction, intangible investment, is defined by any public good or mixed-good creating investment. As Sect. 2 demonstrated however, even these three main types of intangible resources, though more or less established as understanding to be essential, are far from being dealt with in a systematic structured way together as intangible investments as special type of investment. The aim of our current work is to illustrate conceptually and empirically the hierarchy between culture and intangible investments per se, by approximating it with the hierarchical relationship between culture and these three main types of intangible investments. This we hope both fills in a gap in the literature in viewing them together as a common type of investment and also paves the road for the understanding of the dependence and treatment of such types of investments in relation to culture.

  5. Like World Value Survey, the ESS dataset has a wealth of cultural attitudes addressed in its questionnaires. The ESS data however, is gathered every second year and continues to augment as a database ever since 2000. Therefore, in spite of its limitations of being representative only on national level, with careful statistical transformations, this data can be brought to being useful for certain quantitative approximation of cultural attitudes across the European regions. In our study, we acknowledge the limitations of the data and do not overemphasize on its interpretative significance. Yet, we use it to demonstrate the operationalization of our CBD conceptual propositions and in specific the novel methodological approach for computing a cultural Herfindahl Index and a cultural Segregation Index.

  6. Clearly, the best variable here would be wages. This data however is not available. The only available closest approximation, with all theoretical and empirical limitations that it is subject to, is this variable—income.

  7. The shares are formed by the available number of people sharing a particular attitude and the total number of people interviewed on NUTS2 level in the locality. The limitations of this approximation are accounted for and therefore, we do not involve the cultural variables in the second causal inquiry part of the study.

  8. We also considered the exploration of two additional measures of cultural diversity—called the fault lines approach (see Dawson 2010) and the Hurst Index (as used in a Tiebout Hypothesis estimation context in Kubiliusa and Mishurab 2012). For both measures, however, no adequate data was found to be available.

  9. As the GMM estimation can handle only models of one equation, we have to express the simultaneous equation model (5) into a model of one equation that is a most close approximation of it. To do so, we take the lagged Y variable from the first equation in model (5) which brings an important endogeneity component in it and has also a logical place from estimation methodology point of view as a lagged outcome variable. We also do not have the cultural variables here. So we do not face collinearity, as the intangible investment II is dependent exogenously only on the cultural factor. Moreover, we do not have a variable to approximate the quality of human capital, therefore we substitute it in equation three with its formants from equation two of model (5). Namely, we use II and W as regressants in our model (10) to express the QHC, which is otherwise unquantifiable with our data. Finally, actually we u the standard model for tapping on local economic capitals—equation three of model (5) and just augment it with the relevant variables from equation one—the lagged Y, and from Eq. 2– the formants of QHC—II and W and thus we arrive at our testable with GMM method model (10). K is not available as a measure, but our control variable for economic structure are used to counter balance for that.

  10. Cambridge mixed method for triangulation. See: Downward and Mearman (2007).

  11. See Appendix (Table 8) for a summary table of the variables used in the estimations that follow.

  12. The Hurst Index was already employed in the context of the Tiebout Hypothesis in Kubiliusa and Mishurab (2012).

References

  • Acemoglu D, Robinson J (2010) The role of institutions in growth and development. Rev Econ Inst 1(2):1–33

    Google Scholar 

  • Alesina A, Baqir R, Easterly W (1999) Public goods and ethnic divisions. Q J Econ MIT Press, 114(4):1243–1284

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Alfano G, Marwell G (1981) Experiments on the provision of public goods III: non-divisibility and free riding in ‘real’ groups. Soc Psychol Q 43:300–309

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Arellano M, Bond S (1991) Some tests of specification for panel data: Monte Carlo evidence and an application to employment equations. Rev Econ Stud 58:277–97

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Arellano M, Bover O (1995) Another look at the instrumental variables estimation of error components models. J Econ 68:29–51

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Arrow K (1962) Economic welfare and the allocation of resources for invention, NBER Chapters. In: The rate and direction of inventive activity: economic and social factors. National Bureau of Economic Research, Inc. pp 609–626

  • Axelrod R (1997) The dissemination of culture: a model with local convergence and global polarization. J Confl Resolut 41(2):203–226

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bairam EI, McRae SD (1999) Testing the convergence hypothesis: a new approach. Econ Lett 64(3):351–355

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Banzhaf H, Walsh R (2008) Do people vote with their feet? An empirical test of Tiebout. Am Econ Rev 98(3):843–63

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Barro R, McCleary RJ (2003) Religion and economic growth across countries. Am Soc Rev 68(5):760–781

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Barro R, McCleary RJ (2005) Which countries have state religions?. Q J Econ 120(4):1331–1370

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Baycan T, Nijkamp P (2012) A socio-economic impact analysis of urban cultural diversity: pathways and horizons. In: Nijkamp P, Poot J, Sahin M (eds) Migration impact assessment: new horizons. Edward Elgar Publishing, Cheltenham, pp 175–202

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Becker G (1964) Human capital: a theoretical and empirical analysis, with special reference to education. University of Chicago Press, Chicago

    Google Scholar 

  • Besley T, Ghatak M (2001) Government versus private ownership of public goods. Q J Econ 116(4):1343–1372.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bewley T (1981) A critique of Tiebout’s theory of local public expenditures. Econometrica 49(1951):713–740

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bewley T (1999) Why wages don’t fall during a recession. Harvard University Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Blundell R, Bond S (1998) Initial conditions and moment restrictions in dynamic panel data models. J Econ 87:11–143

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Boadway R, Tremblay J (2010) Mobility and fiscal imbalance. Natl Tax J Natl Tax Assoc 63(4):1023–1053

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bourdieu P (1973) Cultural reproduction and social reproduction. In: Brown R (ed) Knowledge, education and social change: papers in the sociology of education. Tavistock Publications, Tavistock, pp 71–112

    Google Scholar 

  • Bourdieu P (1977) Cultural reproduction and social reproduction. In: Karabel J, Halsey AH (eds) Power and ideology in education. New York: Oxford University Press, pp 487–511

  • Bourdieu P (1986) The forms of capital. In: Richardson JG (ed) Handbook of theory and research for the sociology of education. Greenwood, New York, pp 241–258

    Google Scholar 

  • Bourdieu P, Passeron J (1977) Reproduction in education, society and culture (Richard Nice, Trans.). Sage, Beverly Hills

    Google Scholar 

  • Canibano L, Covarsi A, Sanchez M (1999) The value relevance and managerial implications of intangibles: a literature review. Paper presented at international symposium: measuring and reporting intellectual capital: experiences, issues and prospects, Amsterdam

  • Card D (1999) The causal effect of education on earnings. In Ashenfelter O, Card D (eds) The handbook of labor economics. Vol. 3 A, 1801–63. North-Holland Press, Amsterdam, pp 1801–1863

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Card D (2001) Estimating the return to schooling: progress on some persistent econometric problems. Econometrica 69(5):1127–1160

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Card D, Krueger A (1992) School quality and black/white relative earnings: a direct assessment. Q J Econ 107(2):151–200

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chiswick B, Huang J (2006) The earnings of American Jewish men: human capital, denomination and religiosity, IZA Discussion Papers 2301, Institute for the Study of Labor (IZA)

  • Christopoulos DK, Tsionas EG (2004) Convergence and regional productivity differences: evidence from Greek prefectures. Ann Reg Sci 38:387–396

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Crepon B, Duguet E, Mairesse J (1998) Research investment, innovation and productivity: an econometric analysis at the firm level. Econ Innov New Technol 7(2):115–58

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dawson J (2010) Diversity faultlines, shared objectives, and top management team performance. Hum Relat 64:307–336

    Google Scholar 

  • Downward P, Mearman A (2007) Retroduction as mixed-methods triangulation in economic research: reorienting economics into social science. Camb J Econ 31(1):77–99

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fang H, Gavazza A (2011) Dynamic inefficiencies in an employment-based health insurance system: theory and evidence, Am Econ Rev, Am Econ Assoc 101(7):3047–3077

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Florida R (2002a) The rise of the creative class: and how it’s transforming work, leisure, community, and everyday life. Basic Books, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Florida R (2002b) Bohemia and economic geography. J Econ Geogr 2:55–71

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Florida R (2005) The flight of the creative class: the new global competition for talent. Harper Collins, London

    Google Scholar 

  • Fritsch M, Wyrwich M (2012) The long persistence of regional entrepreneurship culture Germany 1925–2005, Deutsches Institut für Wirtschaftsforschung, Discussion Paper 1224

  • Galama T (2011) A contribution to health capital theory, RAND working paper: WR-831

  • Goldin C, Katz L (2009) The race between education and technology: the evolution of US educational wage differentials, 1890–2005. Belknap Press, USA

    Google Scholar 

  • Gramlich E, Rubinfeld D (1982) Micro estimates of public spending demand functions and tests of the Tiebout and median-voter hypotheses. J Polit Econ 90(3):536–560

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Griliches Z (1977) Economic problems of measuring returns to research. In: Elkana Y et al. (eds) Toward a metric of science: the advent of science indicators. Wiley, New York, pp 171–179

    Google Scholar 

  • Guiso L, Sapienza P, Zingales L (2006) Does culture affect economic outcomes? J Econ Perspect 2:23–48

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Haas S, Glymour M, Berkman L (2011) Childhood health and labor market inequality over the life course. J Health Soc Behav 52(3):298–313

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hall P, Soskice D (2001) An introduction to the varieties of capitalism. In: Hall P, Soskice D (eds) Varieties of capitalism: the institutional basis of competitive advantage. Oxford University Press, Oxford, pp 1–70

  • Holland S (2014) The welfare implications of health capital investment, SSRN-id1696008

  • Holtermann SE (1972) Externalities and public goods. Economica New Ser 39(153):78–87

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hong L, Page SE (2001) Problem solving by heterogeneous agents. J Econ Theor 97(1):123–163

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kara O (2010) Comparing two approaches to the rate of return to investment in education. Educ Econ 18(2):153–165

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Katz L, Autor D (1999) Changes in the wage structure and earnings inequality. In: Ashenfelter O, Card D (eds) Handbook of labor economics, ed 1, Vol. 3, Ch. 26. Elsevier Science B.V., Amsterdam, Elsevier, pp 1463–1555 (Ch. 26.)

  • Koide H (1987) Spatial provision of local public goods with spillover effects. Reg Sci Urban Econ 18:283–305

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Krugman P (1979) Increasing returns, monopolistic competition and international trade. J Int Econ 9:469–479

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kubiliusa K, Mishurab Y (2012) The rate of convergence of Hurst index estimate for the stochastic differential equation. Stoch Process App 122:3718–3739

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Leeuwen G, Mohnen P (2013) Revisiting the porter hypothesis: an empirical analysis of green innovation for the Netherlands, MERIT Working Papers 002, United Nations University—Maastricht Economic and Social Research Institute on Innovation and Technology (MERIT)

  • Levaggi R, Moretto M, Pertile P (2010) Static and Dynamic Efficiency of Irreversible Health Care Investments under Alternative Payment Rules, FEEM Working Paper No. 130.2010

  • Lucas RE (1988) On the mechanics of economic development. J Monet Econ 22(1):3–42

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • McGrath K (2014) Does increased investment in responsible properties lead to better corporate performance? MPRA Working Paper 57767

  • Mincer J (1974) Schooling, experience and earnings. NBER Book, Columbia University Press

  • Myrdal G (1957) Rich lands and poor, the road to world prosperity. Harper and Row, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Offerman T, Sonnemans J, Schram A (1996) Value orientations, expectations and voluntary contributions in public goods. Econ J R Econ Soc 106(437):817–45

    Google Scholar 

  • Olson M (1971/1965) The logic of collective action: public goods and the theory of groups 2nd ed. Harvard University Press, Cambridge

  • Pan L (2014) The impacts of education investment on skilled and unskilled wage inequality and economic development in developing countries. Econ Model 39(1):174–181

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rebelo S (1991) Long-run policy analysis and long-run growth. J Polit Econ 99(3):500

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ritzen J, Soete L (2011) Research, higher education and innovation: redesigning multi-level governance within Europe in a period of crisis, UNU MERIT Working Paper 2011-056

  • Roodman D (2006) How to do xtabond2: an introduction to “Difference” and “System” GMM in Stata, Working Paper Number 103

  • Romer P (1986) Increasing returns and long-run growth. J Polit Econ 94(5):1002–1037

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Romer P (1987) Growth based on increasing returns due to specialization. Am Econ Rev Am Econ Assoc 77(2):56–62

    Google Scholar 

  • Romer P (1990a) Capital, labor and productivity, Bookings Papers on Economic Activity: Microeconomics, pp 337–367

  • Romer P (1990b) Endogenous technological change. J Polit Econ 98(5):71–102

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Samuelson P (1954) The pure theory of public expenditure. Rev Econ Stat 36(4):387–389

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Saure P (2009) Bounded love of variety and patterns of trade, Swiss National Bank Working Papers 2009-10

  • Sell J (1997) Gender, strategies, and contributions to public goods. Soc Psychol Q 60(3):252–265

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Shapiro M, Nugent J (2012) Institutions and the sources of innovation: the determinants and effects of international. Int J Public Policy 8(4–6):230–250

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Shiells ME (1990) Collective choice of working conditions: hours in British and U.S. iron and steel, 1890–1923. J Econ Hist 50(2):379–392

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Singleton JD (2013) Sorting Charles Tiebout: the construction and stabilization of postwar public good theory by John D. Singleton, CHOPE Working Paper No. 2013-20.

  • Smith, A (1759) The theory of moral sentiments. [English text, 2010], Penguin Classics, London

  • Suciu M, Avram R, Avram E, Eftimie R (2011) The potential of the investment in education in creating socio-economic development in the new economy and the knowledge-based society. Rev Econ Bus Stud 7(2011):255–264

    Google Scholar 

  • Tiebout C (1956) A pure theory of local expenditures. J Polit Econ 64(5):416–424

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tubadji A (2012) Culture-based development: culture as an encompassing economic factor—empirical evidence for Germany. Int J Soc Econ 39(9):690–703

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tubadji A (2013) Culture-based development—culture and institutions: economic development in the regions of Europe. Int J Soc Syst Sci 5(4):355–391

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tubadji A (2014) Was Weber right? The cultural capital roots of economic growth. Int J Manpower 35(1/2):56–88 (Special Issue on Culture and Labour)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tubadji A, Gnezdilova N (2014) The cultural root of the German job miracle, forthcoming in. Int J Soc Econ 41(11):1014–1037

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tubadji A, Nijkamp P (2014) Altruism to strangers for our own sake: immigration impact on productivity and its dependence on local culture. I J Manpower 35(1/2): 11–32 (Special Issue Culture and Labour)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tubadji A, Nijkamp P (2015a) The cultural percolation of new knowledge: a regional analysis for cultural impact on knowledge creation in the EU27. In: Bakens J, Poot J, Nijkamp P (eds) The economics of cultural diversity, Edward Elgar Publishing, (Cheltenham 2014. Forthcoming)

  • Tubadji A, Nijkamp P (2015b) Cultural capital and regional economic development: an impact assessment of local cultural capital in Greece applying partial least squares (PLS-PM). Ann Regional Sci. Forthcoming

  • Tubadji A, Nijkamp P (2015c) Cultural gravity among immigrants: a comparative analysis of the EU15, Economic Geography. Forthcoming

  • Tubadji A, Nijkamp P (2015d) Public goods trade-offs and house prices in a smart city: green online vs green offline preferences. SEPS Special Issue. Forthcoming.

  • Tubadji A, Pelzel F (2015) Culture-based development: measuring an invisible resource using the PLS-PM method. Int J Soc Econ. Forthcoming

  • Tubadji A, Osoba B, Nijkamp P (2014) Culture-based development in the USA: culture as a factor for economic welfare and social wellbeing at a county level. J Cult Econ 38(4). doi:10.1007/s10824-014-9232-3

  • Uzawa H (1986) Optimum technical change in an aggregative model of economic growth. Int Econ Rev 6(1):18–31

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Weber M (1904–1905/1930) The protestant ethic and the spirit of capitalism. Published in English in 1930. Unwin Hyman, London

  • Whitley R (1999) Divergent capitalisms: the social structuring and change of business systems. Oxford University Press, Oxford

    Google Scholar 

  • Whitley R (2002) Competing capitalisms: institutions and economies. Elgar, Cheltenham

    Google Scholar 

  • Whitley R (2007) Business systems and organizational capabilities: the institutional structuring of competitive competences. Oxford University Press, Oxford

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Windmeijer F (2005) A finite sample correction for the variance of linear efficient two-step GMM estimators. J Econ 126:25–51

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Annie Tubadji.

Appendix

Appendix

Table 8 Table of main dependent and explanatory variables used in the empirical analysis

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Tubadji, A., Angelis, V. & Nijkamp, P. Endogenous intangible resources and their place in the institutional hierarchy. Rev Reg Res 36, 1–28 (2016). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10037-015-0097-5

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10037-015-0097-5

Keywords

JEL classification

Navigation