Skip to main content
Log in

Does Religion Matter to Equity Pricing?

  • Published:
Journal of Business Ethics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

For a sample comprising 36,105 U.S. firm-year observations from 1985 to 2008, we find that firms located in more religious counties enjoy cheaper equity financing costs. This result is robust to a battery of sensitivity tests, including alternative assumptions and model specifications, additional controls for noise in analyst forecasts, and various approaches to addressing endogeneity. In another set of tests, we find that the equity pricing role that religion plays comes predominantly from Mainline Protestants. We also document that the effect of religiosity on firms’ cost of equity capital is larger for firms (periods) lacking alternative monitoring (regulation) mechanisms as measured by lower institutional ownership (the pre-SOX era), implying that religion plays a corporate governance role. Finally, we find that the importance of religion to equity pricing is concentrated in firms that suffer lower visibility, which tend to be more sensitive to local social and economic factors. By examining the links between religiosity and valuation at the firm level, we provide strong, robust evidence supporting the perspective that religion facilitates economic development.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Morse (1964), Andreski (1969), and Harrison (1985), among others, document a negative relation between Catholicism and economic progress. In the same vein, La Porta et al. (1999) and Stulz and Williamson (2003) report that Catholic countries have significantly weaker corporate governance and weaker protection of creditor rights than Protestant countries. In cross-country research, Grier (1997) provides evidence that the growth rate of Protestantism rises with real GDP growth, although the author fails to find any empirical support for Weber’s (1905) assertion that Protestantism accounts for all the differential development and growth between Catholic and Protestant countries.

  2. Religion is shown to affect, among other things, individuals’ wages (Chiswick 1983), level of education (Chiswick 1985; Gruber 2005), tendency toward suicide (Pescosolido and Georgianna 1989), drug and alcohol use (Cochran and Akers 1989), health (Ellison 1991), criminal behavior (Evans et al. 1995), risk aversion (Miller and Hoffmann 1995; Halek and Eisenhauer 2001), and social ethics (Arruñada 2010). See Iannaccone (1998) for a review of this literature.

  3. See also Chava and Purnanandam (2010) and Chen et al. (2011) for recent discussions in the finance literature motivating the use of implied cost of equity instead of realized returns.

  4. See Vitell (2009) for a recent review of the empirical literature.

  5. This prediction finds further support from recent evidence that the influence of local religious norms on financial institutions is more pronounced in smaller organizations (Kumar et al. 2011).

  6. Several studies report that, to improve their visibility, firms hire investor relations (IR) firms to elicit more extensive analyst and media coverage as well as larger equity stakes held by institutional investors (e.g., Lang and Lundholm 1996; Brennan and Tamarowski 2000; Bushee and Noe 2000; Hong and Huang 2005; Bushee and Miller 2011).

  7. Prior research suggests that financial institutions, investment bankers, and analysts are typically located in central areas and tend to neglect remote firms (e.g., Malloy 2005; Loughran and Schulz 2006; Loughran 2007, 2008).

  8. All evidence on our predictions is almost identical when we synchronize the data by retaining only firms with December fiscal year-ends. Given that we estimate the cost of equity capital at the same date for all firms, this ensures that variation in the release of their financial statements does not drive our results. Fama and French (1992) find that the vast majority of firms comply with SEC rules by filing their financial statements within 90 days of fiscal year-end.

  9. In an unreported test, we run our regressions using only the years for which we have direct survey data on religiosity (1990 and 2000). Though the sample size is much smaller, the significant results suggest that our linear interpolation and extrapolation does not create systematic noise in the sample.

  10. Some stress that studies failing to provide evidence that religiosity affects ethical behavior using one-dimensional measures of religiosity reinforce the importance of relying on multi-dimensional proxies. However, in using such a one-dimensional proxy, we provide evidence that is statistically strong and robust as well as economically material that firms in more religious counties attract cheaper equity financing.

  11. Throughout the article, we use the terms cost of equity capital, implied cost of equity, and equity risk premium synonymously.

  12. By taking the average across four models, we help dispel concern that our main evidence stems from the unique characteristics of any single model. However, we continue to find evidence that firms located in more religious counties enjoy cheaper equity financing costs when re-estimating our regressions using each individual model, the median, or the first principal component of the four (e.g., Chen et al. 2009). Indeed, recent evidence reinforces the importance of not specifying a single implied cost of capital estimate when examining the determinants of equity pricing (e.g., Botosan and Plumlee 2005; Guay et al. 2011; Dhaliwal et al. 2006; Francis et al. 2008).

  13. It follows that the delegated monitoring by regulatory authorities that utilities experience reduces their asset substitution (Jensen and Meckling 1976) and under-investment (Myers 1977) problems, which, in turn, may shape the link between religion and equity pricing. In unreported sensitivity tests, none of our core inferences are sensitive to excluding utilities (SIC codes 4900-4999) from the analysis. More generally, none of our inferences are materially sensitive to recursively removing firms from each of the 48 Fama and French (1997) industries from the samples, or replacing the industry dummies with the 1-year lagged average industry risk premium after Gebhardt et al. (2001) and Dhaliwal et al. (2005).

  14. Despite that this naturally admits data attrition, our core evidence is materially insensitive to re-estimating the regressions on a balanced panel to dispel any concern that our inferences spuriously reflect shifts in the sample composition over time.

  15. Our tabulations diverge from Grullon et al. (2010) in that we report summary statistics for our estimation sample, while they report summary statistics at the county level for the survey years.

  16. If we restrict our sample to the years before 2002 (the year in which the Sarbanes–Oxley Act was passed), then ADH comes through at the 1% level.

  17. We define the mining industry to broadly encompass the following activities: precious metals, non-metallic and industrial metal mining, coal, and petroleum and natural gas.

  18. Several studies suggest that institutional investors provide valuable monitoring (e.g., McConnell and Servaes 1990; Nesbitt 1994; Smith 1996; Del Guercio and Hawkins 1999; Gillan and Starks 2000; Parrino et al. 2003).

  19. We follow Gaspar et al. 2005 in classifying and calculating long-term and short-term institutional ownership.

  20. We define firm age as the number of years since the firm first appeared in the CRSP database.

  21. ILLIQ is defined as the average over the fiscal year of the square root of the daily absolute stock return over the corresponding daily dollar volume. However, in untabulated results, we find that our conclusions hold when we replace ILLIQ with the average effective bid-ask spread (Roll 1984) over the fiscal year.

References

  • Admati, A. R., Pfleiderer, P., & Zechner, J. (1994). Large shareholder activism, risk sharing, and financial market equilibrium. Journal of Political Economy, 102, 1097–1130.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Agarwal, S., & Hauswald, R. (2010). Distance and private information in lending. Review of Financial Studies, 23, 2757–2788.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Albuquerue, R., & Wang, N. (2008). Agency conflicts, investment, and asset pricing. Journal of Finance, 63, 1–40.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ali, A. J., Camp, R. C., & Gibbs, M. (2005). The concept of ‘free agency’ in monotheistic religions: Implications for global business. Journal of Business Ethics, 60, 103–112.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Amihud, Y. (2002). Illiquidity and stock returns: Cross-section and time-series effects. Journal of Financial Markets, 5, 31–56.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Andreski, S. (1969). Parasitism and subversion: The case of Latin America. New York: Schocken Books.

    Google Scholar 

  • Angelidis, J., & Ibrahim, N. (2004). An exploratory study of the impact of degree of religiousness upon an individual’s corporate social responsiveness orientation. Journal of Business Ethics, 51, 119–128.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Arruñada, B. (2010). Protestants and Catholics: Similar work ethic, different social ethic. Economic Journal, 120, 890–918.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Attig, N., Guedhami, O., & Mishra, D. (2008). Multiple large shareholders, control contests, and implied cost of equity. Journal of Corporate Finance, 14, 721–737.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Attig, N., Cleary, S. W., El Ghoul, S., & Guedhami, O. (2011). Institutional investment horizons and the cost of equity capital. Working Paper.

  • Baker, H. K., Nofsinger, J. R., & Weaver, D. G. (2002). International cross-listing and visibility. Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis, 37, 495–521.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Barro, R. J., & McCleary, R. M. (2003). Religion and economic growth across countries. American Sociological Review, 68, 760–781.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Barry, C. B., & Brown, S. J. (1985). Differential information and security market equilibrium. Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis, 20, 407–422.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Barth, M. E., Hodder, L. D., & Stubben, S. R. (2008). Fair value accounting for liabilities and own credit risk. The Accounting Review, 83, 629–664.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Becker, S. O., & Woessmann, L. (2009). Was Weber wrong? A human capital theory of Protestant economic history. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 124, 531–596.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Benjamin, D. J., Choi, J. J., & Fisher, G. (2010). Religious identity and economic behavior. Working paper.

  • Botosan, C. A., & Plumlee, M. A. (2005). Assessing alternative proxies for the expected risk premium. The Accounting Review, 80, 21–53.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Boyd, R., & Richerson, P. J. (1985). Culture and the evolutionary process. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Brammer, S., Williams, G., & Zinkin, J. (2007). Religion and attitudes to corporate social responsibility in a large cross-country sample. Journal of Business Ethics, 71, 229–243.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brennan, M. J., & Tamarowski, C. (2000). Investor relations, liquidity, and stock prices. Journal of Applied Corporate Finance, 12, 26–37.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bushee, B. J., & Miller, G. S. (2011). Investor relations, firm visibility, and investor following. Working paper.

  • Bushee, B. J., & Noe, C. F. (2000). Corporate disclosure practices, institutional investors, and stock return volatility. Journal of Accounting Research, 38, 171–202.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Butler, A. W. (2008). Distance still matters: Evidence from municipal bond underwriting. Review of Financial Studies, 21, 763–784.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chava, S., & Purnanandam, A. (2010). Is default risk negatively related to stock returns? Review of Financial Studies, 23, 2523–2559.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chen, K. C. W., Chen, Z., & Wei, K.-C. K. (2009). Legal protection of investors, corporate governance, and the cost of equity capital. Journal of Corporate Finance, 15, 273–289.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chen, K. C. W., Chen, Z., & Wei, K.-C. K. (2011). Agency costs of free cash flow and the effect of shareholder rights on the implied cost of equity capital. Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis, 46, 171–207.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chiswick, B. R. (1983). The earnings and human capital of American Jews. Journal of Human Resources, 18, 313–336.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chiswick, B. R. (1985). Review: Jewish adjustment in Western Countries. Contemporary Sociology, 14, 17–20.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Christoffersen, S. E., & Sarkissian, S. (2009). City size and fund performance. Journal of Financial Economics, 92, 252–275.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cialdini, R. B., & Goldstein, N. J. (2004). Social influence: Compliance and conformity. Annual Review of Psychology, 55, 591–621.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Claus, J., & Thomas, J. (2001). Equity premia as low as three percent? Evidence from analysts’ earnings forecasts for domestic and international stock markets. Journal of Finance, 56, 1629–1666.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cochran, J. K., & Akers, R. L. (1989). Beyond hellfire: An exploration of the variable effects of religiosity on adolescent marijuana and alcohol use. Journal of Research in Crime and Delinquency, 26, 198–225.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cohen, D. A., Dey, A., & Lys, T. Z. (2008a). Real and accrual-based earnings management in the pre- and post-Sarbanes–Oxley periods. The Accounting Review, 83, 757–787.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cohen, L., Frazzini, A., & Malloy, C. (2008b). The small world of investing: Board connections and mutual fund returns. Journal of Political Economy, 116, 951–979.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Coles, J. L., Loewenstein, U., & Suay, J. (1995). On equilibrium pricing under parameter uncertainty. Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis, 30, 347–364.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Coval, J. D., & Moskowitz, T. J. (1999). Home bias at home: Local equity preference in domestic portfolios. Journal of Finance, 54, 2045–2073.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Degryse, H. A., & Steven Ongena, R. G. (2005). Distance, lending relationships, and competition. Journal of Finance, 60, 231–266.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Del Guercio, D., & Hawkins, J. (1999). The motivation and impact of pension fund activism. Journal of Financial Economics, 52, 293–340.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dhaliwal, D., Heitzman, S., & Li, O. Z. (2006). Taxes, leverage, and the cost of equity capital. Journal of Accounting Research, 44, 691–723.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dhaliwal, D., Krull, L., Li, O. Z., & Moser, W. (2005). Dividend taxes and implied cost of equity capital. Journal of Accounting Research, 43, 675–708.

    Google Scholar 

  • Duggal, R., & Millar, J. A. (1999). Institutional ownership and firm performance: The case of bidder returns. Journal of Corporate Finance, 5, 103–117.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dyreng, S., Mayew, W. J., & Williams, C. D. (2010). Religious social norms and corporate financial reporting. Working paper.

  • Easton, P. D. (2004). PE ratios, PEG ratios, and estimating the implied expected rate of return on equity capital. The Accounting Review, 79, 73–95.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Easton, P. D. (2006). Use of forecasts of earnings to estimate and compare cost of capital across regimes. Journal of Business Finance & Accounting, 33, 374–394.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Easton, P. D., & Monahan, S. J. (2005). An evaluation of accounting-based measures of expected returns. The Accounting Review, 80, 501–538.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Easton, P. D., & Sommers, G. A. (2007). Effect of analysts’ optimism on estimates of the expected rate of return implied by earnings forecasts. Journal of Accounting Research, 45, 983–1015.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • El Ghoul, S., Guedhami, O., Ni, Y., Pittman, J. A., & Saadi, S. (2011, forthcoming). Does information asymmetry matter to equity pricing? Evidence from firm’s geographic location. Contemporary Accounting Research.

  • Ellison, C. G. (1991). Religious involvement and subjective well-being. Journal of Health and Social Behavior, 32, 80–99.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Elton, E. J. (1999). Expected return, realized return, and asset pricing tests. Journal of Finance, 54, 1199–1220.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Evans, T. D., Cullen, F. T., Dunaway, R. G., & Burton, V. S. (1995). Religion and crime reexamined: The impact of religion, secular controls, and social ecology on adult criminality. Criminology, 33, 195–224.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fama, E. F., & French, K. R. (1992). The cross-section of expected stock returns. Journal of Finance, 47, 427–465.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fama, E. F., & French, K. R. (1997). Industry costs of equity. Journal of Financial Economics, 43, 153–193.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Francis, B., Hasan, I., John, K., & Waisman, M. (2010). Urban agglomeration and CEO pay. Working paper.

  • Francis, J., LaFond, R., Olsson, P., & Schipper, K. (2005). The market pricing of accruals quality. Journal of Accounting and Economics, 39, 295–327.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Francis, J., Nanda, D., & Olsson, P. (2008). Voluntary disclosure, earnings quality, and cost of capital. Journal of Accounting Research, 46, 53–99.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • French, K. R., & Poterba, J. M. (1991). Investor diversification and international equity markets. American Economic Review, 81, 222–226.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gaspar, J.-M., Massa, M., & Matos, P. (2005). Shareholder investment horizons and the market for corporate control. Journal of Financial Economics, 76, 135–165.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gebhardt, W. R., Lee, C. M. C., & Swaminathan, B. (2001). Toward an implied cost of capital. Journal of Accounting Research, 39, 135–176.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Georgarakos, D., & Pasini, G. (2010). Trust, sociability and stock market participation. Working paper.

  • George, A. St., & McNamara, P. H. (1984). Religion, race and psychological well-being. Journal for the Scientific Study of Religion, 23, 351–363.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gillan, S. L., & Starks, L. T. (2000). Corporate governance proposals and shareholder activism: The role of institutional investors. Journal of Financial Economics, 57, 275–305.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gode, D., & Mohanram, P. (2003). Inferring the cost of capital using the Ohlson–Juettner model. Review of Accounting Studies, 8, 399–431.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gompers, P. A., & Metrick, A. (2001). Institutional investors and equity prices. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 116, 229–259.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gordon, J. R., & Gordon, M. J. (1997). The finite horizon expected return model. Financial Analysts Journal, 53, 52–61.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Grier, R. (1997). The effect of religion on economic development: A cross national study of 63 former colonies. Kyklos, 50, 47–62.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Grinblatt, M., & Keloharju, M. (2001). How distance, language, and culture influence stockholdings and trades. Journal of Finance, 56, 1053–1073.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gruber, J. H. (2005). Religious market structure, religious participation, and outcomes: Is religion good for you? NBER working paper.

  • Grullon, G., Kanatas, G., Weston, J. P. (2010). Religion and corporate (mis)behavior. Working paper.

  • Guay, W. R., Kothari, S. P., & Shu, S. (2011). Properties of implied cost of capital using analysts’ forecasts. Australian Journal of Management, 36, 125–149.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Guiso, L., Sapienza, P., & Zingales, L. (2003). People’s opium? Religion and economic attitudes. Journal of Monetary Economics, 50, 225–282.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Guiso, L., Sapienza, P., & Zingales, L. (2004). The role of social capital in financial development. American Economic Review, 94, 526–556.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Guiso, L., Sapienza, P., & Zingales, L. (2006). Does culture affect economic outcomes? Journal of Economic Perspectives, 20, 23–48.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Guiso, L., Sapienza, P., & Zingales, L. (2008). Alfred marshall lecture social capital as good culture. Journal of the European Economic Association, 6, 295–320.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hail, L., & Leuz, C. (2006). International differences in the cost of equity capital: Do legal institutions and securities regulation matter? Journal of Accounting Research, 44, 485–531.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hail, L., & Leuz, C. (2009). Cost of capital effects and changes in growth expectations around U.S. Cross-listings. Journal of Financial Economics, 93, 428–454.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Halek, M., & Eisenhauer, J. G. (2001). Demography of risk aversion. Journal of Risk and Insurance, 68, 1–24.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Harrison, L. E. (1985). Underdevelopment is a state of mind: The Latin American case. Lanham: University Press of America.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hilary, G., & Hui, K. W. (2009). Does religion matter in corporate decision making in America? Journal of Financial Economics, 93, 455–473.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hong, H., & Huang, M. (2005). Talking up liquidity: Insider trading and investor relations. Journal of Financial Intermediation, 14, 1–31.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hong, H., Kubik, J. D., & Stein, J. C. (2004). Social interaction and stock-market participation. Journal of Finance, 59, 137–163.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hong, H., Kubik, J. D., & Stein, J. C. (2008). The only game in town: Stock-price consequences of local bias. Journal of Financial Economics, 90, 20–37.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hout, M., & Greeley, A. (1998). What church officials’ reports don’t show: Another look at church attendance data. American Sociological Review, 63, 113–119.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Huberman, G. (2001). Familiarity breeds investment. Review of Financial Studies, 14, 659–680.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hutton, A. P., Marcus, A. J., & Tehranian, H. (2009). Opaque financial reports, R2, and crash risk. Journal of Financial Economics, 94, 67–86.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Iannaccone, L. R. (1998). Introduction to the economics of religion. Journal of Economic Literature, 36, 1465–1495.

    Google Scholar 

  • Inglehart, R., & Abramson, P. R. (1999). Measuring postmaterialism. American Political Science Review, 93, 665–677.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jensen, M. C., & Meckling, W. H. (1976). Theory of the firm: Managerial behavior, agency costs and ownership structure. Journal of Financial Economics, 3, 305–360.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • John, K., Knyazeva, A., & Knyazeva, D. (2011). Do shareholders care about geography? Journal of Financial Economics, 101, 533–551.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kedia, S., & Rajgopal, S. (2009). Geography and the incidence of financial misreporting. Working paper.

  • Knyazeva, A., Knyazeva, D., & Masulis, R. (2011). Effects of local director markets on corporate boards. Working paper.

  • Krause, N., & Wulff, K. M. (2005). Church-based social ties, a sense of belonging in a congregation, and physical health status. International Journal for the Psychology of Religion, 15, 73–93.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kumar, A., Page, J. K., & Spalt, O. G. (2011). Religious beliefs, gambling attitudes, and financial market outcomes. Journal of Financial Economics, 102, 671–708.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • La Porta, R., Lopez-de-Silanes, F., Shleifer, A., & Vishny, R. (1999). The quality of government. Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization, 15, 222–279.

    Google Scholar 

  • Landes, D. (1998). The wealth and poverty of nations. London: Little, Brown, and Company.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lang, M. H., & Lundholm, R. J. (1996). Corporate disclosure policy and analyst behavior. The Accounting Review, 71, 467–492.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lesmond, D. A., Ogden, J. P., & Trzcinka, C. (1999). A new estimate of transaction costs. Review of Financial Studies, 12, 1113–1141.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lewis, K. K. (1999). Trying to explain home bias in equities and consumption. Journal of Economic Literature, 37, 571–608.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Li, N. (2008). Religion, opportunism, and international market entry via non-equity alliances or joint ventures. Journal of Business Ethics, 80, 771–789.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lombardo, D., & Pagano, M. (1999). Legal determinants of the return on equity. Working paper.

  • Longenecker, J. G., McKinney, J. A., & Moore, C. W. (2004). Religious intensity, evangelical christianity, and business ethics: An empirical study. Journal of Business Ethics, 55, 371–384.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Loughran, T. (2007). Geographic dissemination of information. Journal of Corporate Finance, 13, 675–694.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Loughran, T. (2008). The impact of firm location on equity issuance. Financial Management, 37, 1–21.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Loughran, T., & Schultz, P. (2005). Liquidity: Urban versus rural firms. Journal of Financial Economics, 78, 341–374.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Loughran, T., & Schultz, P. (2006). Asymmetric information, firm location, and equity issuance. Working paper.

  • Lundblad, C. (2007). The risk return tradeoff in the long run: 1836–2003. Journal of Financial Economics, 85, 123–150.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Malloy, C. J. (2005). The geography of equity analysis. Journal of Finance, 60, 719–755.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • McCleary, R. M., & Barro, R. J. (2006). Religion and economy. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 20, 49–72.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • McConnell, J. J., & Servaes, H. (1990). Additional evidence on equity ownership and corporate value. Journal of Financial Economics, 27, 595–612.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • McGuire, S. T., Omer, T. C., & Sharp, N. Y. (2011). The impact of religion on financial reporting irregularities. The Accounting Review (in press).

  • Mehran, H., & Peristiani, S. (2009). Financial visibility and the decision to go private. Review of Financial Studies, 23, 519–547.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Merton, R. C. (1987). A simple model of capital market equilibrium with incomplete information. Journal of Finance, 42, 483–510.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Miller, A. S., & Hoffmann, J. P. (1995). Risk and religion: An explanation of gender differences in religiosity. Journal for the Scientific Study of Religion, 34, 63–75.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Morse, R. (1964). The heritage of Latin America. In L. Hartz (Ed.), The founding of new societies. New York: Harcourt, Brace, and World.

    Google Scholar 

  • Myers, S. C. (1977). Determinants of corporate borrowing. Journal of Financial Economics, 5, 147–175.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nesbitt, S. L. (1994). Long-term reward from shareholder activism: A study of the “CalPERS effect”. Journal of Applied Corporate Finance, 6, 75–80.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ohlson, J. A. (1995). Earnings, book values, and dividends in equity valuation. Contemporary Accounting Research, 11, 661–687.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ohlson, J., & Juettner-Nauroth, B. (2005). Expected EPS and EPS growth as determinants of value. Review of Accounting Studies, 10, 349–365.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Omer, T. C., Sharp, N. Y., & Wang, D. D. (2010). Do local religious norms affect auditors going concern decisions? Working paper.

  • Parboteeah, K. P., Hoegl, M., & Cullen, J. (2008). Ethics and religion: An empirical test of a multidimensional model. Journal of Business Ethics, 80, 387–398.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Parrino, R., Sias, R. W., & Starks, L. T. (2003). Voting with their feet: Institutional ownership changes around forced CEO turnover. Journal of Financial Economics, 68, 3–46.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pastor, D., Sinha, M., & Swaminathan, B. (2008). Estimating the intertemporal risk-return tradeoff using the implied cost of capital. Journal of Finance, 63, 2859–2897.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pescosolido, B. A., & Georgianna, S. (1989). Durkheim, suicide, and religion: Toward a network theory of suicide. American Sociological Review, 54, 33–48.

    Google Scholar 

  • Putnam, R. D. (1993). Making democracy work: Civic traditions in modern Italy. Princeton: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Renneboog, L., & Spaenjers, C. (2011). Religion, economic attitudes, and household finance. Oxford Economic Papers.

  • Roll, R. (1984). A simple implicit measure of the effective bid-ask spread in an efficient market. Journal of Finance, 39, 1127–1139.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Seul, J. R. (1999). ‘Ours is the way of God’: Religion, identity, and intergroup conflict. Journal of Peace Research, 36, 553–569.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Shleifer, A., & Vishny, R. W. (1986). Large shareholders and corporate control. Journal of Political Economy, 94, 461–488.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Shu, T., Sulaeman, J., & Yeung, E. (2010). Local religious beliefs and organizational risk-taking behaviors. Working paper.

  • Smith, M. P. (1996). Shareholder activism by institutional investors: Evidence from CalPERS. Journal of Finance, 51, 227–252.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Stulz, R. M. (1999). Globalization of equity markets and the cost of capital. Working paper.

  • Stulz, R. M., & Williamson, R. (2003). Culture, openness, and finance. Journal of Financial Economics, 70, 313–349.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tesar, L. L., & Werner, I. M. (1995). U.S. equity investment in emerging stock markets. World Bank Economic Review, 9, 109–129.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Torgler, B., & Schneider, F. (2009). The impact of tax morale and institutional quality on the shadow economy. Journal of Economic Psychology, 30, 228–245.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Uysal, V. B., Kedia, S., & Panchapagesan, V. (2008). Geography and acquirer returns. Journal of Financial Intermediation, 17, 256–275.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Vitell, S. J. (2009). The role of religiosity in business and consumer ethics: A review of the literature. Journal of Business Ethics, 90, 155–167.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Vitell, S. J., Bing, M. N., Davison, H. K., Ammeter, A. P., Garner, B. L., & Novicivec, M. M. (2009). Religiosity and moral identity: The mediating role of self-control. Journal of Business Ethics, 88, 601–613.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Vitell, S. J., Paolillo, J. G. P., & Singh, J. (2005). Religiosity and consumer ethics. Journal of Business Ethics, 57, 175–181.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Vitell, S. J., Singh, J., & Paolillo, J. G. P. (2007). Consumers’ ethical beliefs: The roles of money, religiosity and attitude toward business. Journal of Business Ethics, 73, 369–379.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Weber, M. (1905). The Protestant ethic and the spirit of Capitalism. London: Allen & Unwin.

    Google Scholar 

  • Welch, M. R., Sikkink, D., & Loveland, M. T. (2007). The radius of trust: Religion, social embeddedness and trust in strangers. Social Forces, 86, 23–46.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Winter, M., & Short, C. (1993). Believing and belonging: Religion in rural England. The British Journal of Sociology, 44, 635–651.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgments

The authors would like to thank Najah Attig, Narjess Boubakri, Lamia Chourou, Art Durnev, David Godsell, Lew Johnson, Cherie Metcalf, Lynnette Purda, Walid Saffar, Fatma Sonmez, and seminar participants at the Queen’s University for constructive comments. The authors also appreciate generous financial support from Canada’s Social Sciences and Humanities Research Council.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Yang Ni.

Appendices

The description of the models and notations used in the appendix follow El Ghoul et al. (2011).

Appendix 1: Models of Cost of Equity Capital

The description of the models and notations used in the appendix follow El Ghoul et al. (2011).

In this appendix, we describe the cost of equity models used in this article. We start by defining variables and specifying assumptions common to all models. We then successively cover each model and its assumptions.

Common Variables and Assumptions

  • P t  = stock price in June of year t

  • DPS 0 = actual dividend per share in year t − 1

  • EPS 0 = actual earnings per share in year t − 1

  • LTG = long-term growth forecast in June of year t

  • FEPS t+τ  = forecasted earnings per share for year t + τ recorded in June of year t

  • B t  = book value per share at the beginning of year t

  • r f  = yield on a 10-year Treasury note in June of year t

As explained in the text, we require firms to have positive 1-year-ahead (FEPS t+1) and 2-year-ahead (FEPS t+2) earnings forecasts as well as a long-term growth forecast (LTG). Yet, the two models call for the use of earnings forecasts beyond year 2. If a forecast is not available in I/B/E/S, then we impute it from the previous year forecast and the long-term growth forecast as FEPS t+τ  = FEPS t+τ−1(1 + LTG).

Model 1: Ohlson and Juettner-Nauroth (2005)

The model is a generalization of the Gordon constant growth model. It allows share price to be expressed in terms of 1-year-ahead earnings forecast, near-term, and perpetual growth forecasts. The explicit forecast horizon is set to 1 year, after which forecasted earnings grow at a near-term rate that decays to a perpetual rate. We follow Gode and Mohanram (2003) implementation of the model. The near-term earnings growth is the average of (i) the percentage difference between 2-year-ahead and 1-year-ahead earnings forecasts, and (ii) the I/B/E/S long-term growth forecast. The perpetual growth rate is the expected inflation rate. Dividend per share is assumed to be constant. The model requires positive 1-year-ahead and 2-year-ahead earnings forecasts. The valuation equation is given by

$$ k_{\text{OJ}} = A + \sqrt {A^{2} + \frac{{FEPS_{t + 1} }}{{P_{t} }}\left( {g_{2} - \left( {\gamma - 1} \right)} \right)} $$
(1)

where \( A = 1/2\left[ {\left( {\gamma - 1} \right) + \left( {DPS_{t + 1} } \right)/P_{t} } \right] \), DPS t+1 = DPS 0, g 2 = (STG + LTG)/2, STG = (FEPS t+2 − FEPS t+1)/FEPS t+1, and (γ − 1) = r f  − 0.03.

Model 2: Easton (2004)

This model is a generalization of the Price-Earnings-Growth (PEG) model and is based on Ohlson and Juettner-Nauroth (2005). It allows share price to be expressed in terms of 1-year-ahead expected dividend per share, and 1-year-ahead and 2-year-ahead earnings forecasts. The explicit forecast horizon is set to 2 years, after which forecasted abnormal earnings grow in perpetuity at a constant rate. The model requires positive 1-year-ahead and 2-year-ahead earnings forecasts as well as positive change in earnings forecast. The valuation equation is given by

$$ P_{t} = \frac{{FEPS_{t + 2} + k_{\text{ES}} DPS_{t + 1} - FEPS_{t + 1} }}{{k_{\text{ES}}^{2} }} $$
(2)

where DPS t+1 = DPS 0.

Model 3: Claus and Thomas (2001)

This model assumes clean surplus accounting (Ohlson 1995), allowing share price to be expressed in terms of forecasted residual earnings and book values. The explicit forecast horizon is set to 5 years, beyond which forecasted residual earnings grow at the expected inflation rate. Dividend payout is assumed to be constant at 50%. The valuation equation is given by

$$ P_{t} = B_{t} + \mathop \sum \limits_{\tau = 1}^{5} \frac{{ae_{t + \tau } }}{{\left( {1 + k_{\text{CT}} } \right)^{\tau } }} + \frac{{ae_{t + 5} \left( {1 + g} \right)}}{{\left( {k_{\text{CT}} - g} \right)\left( {1 + k_{\text{CT}} } \right)^{5} }} $$
(3)

where ae t+τ  = FEPS t+τ  − k CT B t+τ−1, B t+τ  = B t+τ−1 + FEPS t+τ (1 − DPR t+τ ), DPR t+τ  = 0.5, and g = r f  − 0.03.

Model 4: Gebhardt, Lee, and Swaminathan (2001)

This model also assumes clean surplus accounting, allowing share price to be expressed in terms of forecasted returns on equity (ROE) and book values. The explicit forecast horizon is set to 3 years, beyond which forecasted ROE decays to the median industry ROE by the 12th year, and remains constant thereafter. Dividend payout is assumed to be constant. The valuation equation is given by

$$ P_{t} = B_{t} + \mathop \sum \limits_{\tau = 1}^{11} \frac{{FROE_{t + \tau } - k_{\text{GLS}} }}{{\left( {1 + k_{\text{GLS}} } \right)^{\tau } }}B_{t + \tau - 1} + \frac{{FROE_{t + 12} - k_{\text{GLS}} }}{{k_{\text{GLS}} \left( {1 + k_{\text{GLS}} } \right)^{11} }}B_{t + 11} $$
(4)

where FROE t+τ  = forecasted return on equity for year t + τ, B t+τ  = B t+τ−1 + FEPS t+τ (1 − DPR t+τ ), and DPR t+τ  = expected dividend payout ratio in year t + τ.

For the first 3 years, FROE t+τ is set equal to FEPS t+τ /B t+τ−1. Beyond the third year, FROE fades linearly to industry median ROE by the 12th year. Industries are defined according to Fama and French’s (1997) 48 industry classification, and the median industry ROE is calculated over the previous 10 years excluding loss firms.

The expected dividend payout ratio DPR t+τ is set equal to DPS 0/EPS 0. If EPS 0 is negative, then it is replaced by the value implied by a 6% return on assets (the long-run return on assets in the U.S.). We winsorize payout ratios at zero and one.

Alternative Models

We also consider alternative models of the cost of equity. These are used in Table 8.

Gordon Infinite Horizon model

This model assumes that dividends grow in perpetuity at a constant rate, g. Assuming that g = LTG, the valuation equation is given by

$$ k_{\text{IHG}} = \frac{{DPS_{1} }}{{P_{t} }} + LTG $$
(5)

Gordon Finite Horizon Model

This model assumes that dividends grow over an explicit forecasting horizon set to 4 years, beyond which the firm’s return on equity reverts to the expected cost of equity capital. The valuation equations are given by

$$ P_{t} = \mathop \sum \limits_{\tau = 1}^{4} \frac{{DPS_{t + \tau } }}{{\left( {1 + k_{\text{FHG}} } \right)^{{{\uptau}}} }} + \frac{{NEPS_{t + 1} \left( {1 + LTG} \right)^{4} }}{{k_{\text{FHG}} \left( {1 + k_{\text{FHG}} } \right)^{4} }} $$
(6)

where DPS t+τ  = DPS 0(1 + LTG)τ and \( NEPS_{t + 1} = \frac{{FEPS_{t + 3} }}{{\left( {1 + LTG} \right)^{2} }}. \)

Price-Earnings-Growth (PEG) Ratio

This is a special case of the Easton (2004) model assuming no dividend payments. There are two versions of the model. One is based on short-term earnings forecasts and the other on long-term earnings forecasts. The valuation equations are given by

$$ P_{t} = \frac{{FEPS_{t + 2} - FEPS_{t + 1} }}{{k_{\text{ES}}^{2} }} $$
(7)
$$ P_{t} = \frac{{FEPS_{t + 5} - FEPS_{t + 4} }}{{k_{\text{ES}}^{2} }} $$
(8)

Earnings-Price (EP) Ratio

This is a special case of the Easton (2004) model assuming that abnormal earnings growth is set to zero.

$$ EPR = \frac{{FEPS_{t + 1} }}{{P_{t} }} $$
(9)

Appendix 2

See Table 12.

Table 12 Regression variable definitions and data sources

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

El Ghoul, S., Guedhami, O., Ni, Y. et al. Does Religion Matter to Equity Pricing?. J Bus Ethics 111, 491–518 (2012). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10551-012-1213-x

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10551-012-1213-x

Keywords

Navigation