Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

Fuel Efficiency Improvements: Feedback Mechanisms and Distributional Effects in the Oil Market

  • Published:
Environmental and Resource Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

We study the interactions between fuel efficiency improvements in the transport sector and the oil market, where the efficiency improvements are policy-induced in certain regions of the world. We are especially interested in feedback mechanisms of fuel efficiency such as the rebound effect, carbon leakage and the “green paradox”, but also the distributional effects for oil producers. An intertemporal numerical model of the international oil market is introduced, where OPEC-Core producers have market power. We find that the rebound effect has a noticeable effect on the transport sector, with the magnitude depending on the oil demand elasticity. In the benchmark simulations, we calculate that almost half of the energy savings may be lost to a direct rebound effect and an additional 10% to oil price adjustments. In addition, there is substantial intersectoral leakage to other sectors through lower oil prices in the regions that introduce the policy. There is a small green paradox effect in the sense that oil consumption increases initially when the fuel efficiency measures are gradually implemented. Finally, international carbon leakage will be significant if policies are not implemented in all regions; we estimate leakage rates of 35% or higher when only major consuming regions implement fuel economy policies. Non-OPEC producers will to a larger degree than OPEC producers cut back on its oil supply as a response to fuel efficiency policies due to high production costs.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4
Fig. 5
Fig. 6
Fig. 7
Fig. 8

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Fuel efficiency is usually measured as miles driven per gallon of fuel, or alternatively how much fuel you need to drive a mile.

  2. However, growth in energy use has shifted towards more energy-intensive countries, such as China. Thus, global energy intensity fell by 1.3% per year in the 1990s, but only by 0.4% per year in the 2000s (see IEA 2013a, p. 237).

  3. The targets are \(\hbox {CO}_{\mathrm{2}}\)-intensity targets, not fuel efficiency targets, but the effects are quite similar for petrol and diesel cars (but not when considering biofuels and electrical vehicles).

  4. For instance, EU has a target of at least 27% improvement in energy efficiency by 2030. This will be reviewed in 2020 to see if it can be increased to 30% (http://ec.europa.eu/clima/policies/strategies/2030/index_en.htm, accessed 1 November 2016). Further, in the 13th 5-year plan for China (2016–2020), the aim is to reduce energy consumption per unit of gross domestic product (GDP) by 15% and to reduce the carbon intensity in the economy by 18% over the 5 year period, while the long term aim is a fall in carbon intensity by 60–65% from 2005 to 2030 (http://carbon-pulse.com/16618/, accessed 1 November 2016).

  5. Sims et al. (2014) refers to a ”substantial potential for improving internal combustion engines” for light duty vehicles, with up to 50% improvements in vehicle fuel economy (litres/100 km) or 100% when measured in miles per gallon.

  6. http://www.c2es.org/federal/executive/vehicle-standards/fuel-economy-comparison (accessed 1 November 2016).

  7. There may be incentives on the demand side of future carbon policies as they may want to avoid carbon-lock-in for instance in capacity building in power plants, see Bauer et al. (2014).

  8. Strictly speaking, with imperfect competition on the supply side, it is not really price responsiveness as such, but rather how market changes affect the (optimal) supply of the large producers.

  9. After the substantial price drop since 2014, a question could be raised whether OPEC’s behavior has changed. However, the current situation has certain similarities with the situation in 1985–1986, when Saudi Arabia stopped defending the high oil price, mainly due to the loss of market share to various Non-OPEC countries (see e.g. Alkhathlan et al. 2014). Gradually the oil price started to increase, although it took almost two decades before prices were back at the 1985 level, and quotas were used to regulate OPEC members’ production volume. A similar situation could take place again, assuming that expensive Non-OPEC production continues to drop out due to the lower oil prices. Thus, OPEC’s decision in 2014 to maintain its production quotas could well be in the best interest of the producer group.

  10. The first Petro model was introduced in Berg et al. (1997). The new model differs in several aspects.

  11. Dahl refers to them as long-run elasticities, but notes that dynamic models, estimating both short- and long-term elasticities, tend to find long-term elasticities 50–100% above the elasticities found in static studies.

  12. This is in the special case where all end-user prices in a sector/region are equal across energy goods. See the “Appendix” for how the implicit price elasticity for oil is derived.

  13. We use nominal GDP levels, not PPP values, as most energy products are internationally traded goods, and thus exchange rates matter a lot. Due to the calibration of income elasticities (see below), this choice has little importance anyway.

  14. The share of oil in the transport sectors declines to 80% in 2050 and to 41% in 2100.

  15. For instance, in an alternative reference scenario with no growth in GDP, the oil price increases to $135 per barrel in 2050. In this case, the Global_30 scenario reduces global oil consumption by 5.5% in 2050, compared to 5.6% in the main scenario (see below).

  16. While the oil price is increasing over time in all scenarios, the price at a given time period will be lower. Note that this is different than the conclusion in Kverndokk and Rosendahl (2013), as referred in the introduction above, where the price would increase if the market power of oil producers were sufficiently strong. The reasons for the different results are that Kverndokk and Rosendahl used a static model, where the producers did not take into account the intertemporal aspects, and that the market power is not very strong in our model as only OPEC-Core can utilize it.

  17. While Non-OPEC production is around 9% higher in 2040 than in 2020 in our reference scenario, the Non-OPEC production level in the NPS in IEA (2014) is 9% lower. The IEA predicts a decline in unconventional oil production in the U.S as well as reductions in conventional oil production in Russia, Kazakhstan and China, above all after 2025.

  18. Our result is different from the one in Böhringer et al. (2014), where the main conclusion is that OPEC cuts back on its supply to such a large degree when the EU imposes unilateral climate policy that the oil price in fact does not decline. Hence, there is no international leakage through the oil market in their simulations. However, that result is mainly due to the particular type of climate policy, where the EU sets a target for global emission reductions design. When they instead consider a fixed \(\hbox {CO}_{\mathrm{2}}\) tax, OPEC is less willing to reduce its production.

  19. The rebound effect in 2050 can be decomposed as follows: The direct rebound effect is (as before) 14 percentage points. The rebound effect of a lower global oil price is 5–6 percentage points. Thus, as the rebound effect is neutralized by the \(\hbox {CO}_{\mathrm{2}}\) tax (by construction), the direct effect of the \(\hbox {CO}_{\mathrm{2}}\) tax is to reduce oil consumption in the transport sector by around 20%.

  20. For instance, the transport sectors’ share of the oil market in 2050 is increased in the case with low demand or supply elasticity, while it is decreased in the case with low substitution elasticity or competitive supply (compared to the benchmark case). This explains the seemingly inconsistent percentage results in Table 3.

  21. Note that in Kverndokk and Rosendahl (2013) they use \(m =\) 1/AEEI as a measure of fuel efficiency.

  22. Here we use the third-to-last expression in (15).

References

  • Alkhathlan K, Gately D, Javid M (2014) Analysis of Saudi Arabia’s behavior within OPEC and the world oil market. Energy Policy 64:209–225

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Al-Qahtani A, Balistreri E, Dahl C (2008) Literature on oil market modeling and OPEC’s behavior. Colorado School of Mines, Golden

    Google Scholar 

  • Aune FA, Mohn K, Osmundsen P, Rosendahl KE (2010) Financial market pressures, tacit collusion and oil price formation. Energy Econ 32:389–398

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bauer N, Hilaire J, Bertram C (2014) The calm before the storm—what happens to \(\text{CO}_{2}\) emissions before their price starts to increase? Paper presented at the World Congress of Environmental and Resource Economists, 28 June–2 July, Istanbul, Turkey

  • Berg E, Kverndokk S, Rosendahl KE (1997) Market power, international \(\text{ CO }_{{\rm 2}}\) taxation and petroleum wealth. Energy J 18(4):33–71

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Berg E, Kverndokk S, Rosendahl KE (2002) Oil exploration under climate treaties. J Environ Econ Manag 44(3):493–516

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Borenstein S (2015) A microeconomic framework for evaluating energy efficiency rebound and some implications. Energy J 36(1):1–21

    Google Scholar 

  • Böhringer C, Rosendahl KE, Schneider J (2014) Unilateral climate policy: can OPEC resolve the leakage problem? Energy J 35(4):79–100

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dahl C (2012) Measuring global gasoline and diesel price and income elasticities. Energy Policy 41:2–13

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dahl C, Yucel M (1991) Testing alternative hypotheses of oil production behavior. Energy J 12(4):117–138

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • EIA—Energy Information Administration (2012) Performance profiles of major energy producers, various issues 1981–2009. U.S. Department of Energy

  • Felder S, Rutherford TF (1993) Unilateral \(\text{ CO }_{{\rm 2}}\) reductions and carbon leakage: the consequences of international trade in oil and basic materials. J Environ Econ Manag 25(2):162–176

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fischer C, Salant S (2014) Quantifying intertemporal emissions leakage. In: Pittel K, van der Ploeg R, Withagen C (eds) Climate policy and nonrenewable resources: the green paradox and beyond, chap 11. The MIT Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Frondel M, Ritter N, Vance C (2012) Heterogeneity in the rebound: further evidence for Germany. Energy Econ 34(2):388–394

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fæhn T, Hagem C, Lindholt L, Mæland S, Rosendahl KE (2017) Climate policies in a fossil fuel producing country. Demand versus supply side policies. Energy J 38(1):77–102

    Google Scholar 

  • Gillingham K, Kochen M, Rapson D, Wagner G (2013) A comment: energy policies—the rebound effect is overplayed. Nature 493:475–476

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gillingham K, Rapson D, Wagner G (2016) The rebound effect and energy efficiency policy. Rev Environ Econ Policy 10(1):68–88

  • GTZ (2009) International fuel prices. https://www.giz.de/expertise/html/4282.html

  • Habermacher F (2015) Carbon leakage: a medium- and long-term view. CESifo working paper 5216

  • Hansen PV, Lindholt L (2008) The market power of OPEC 1973–2001. Appl Econ 40(22):2939–2959

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Huntington H, Al-Fattah SM, Huang Z, Gucwa M, Nouri A (2013) Oil markets and price movements: a survey of models. Energy Modeling Forum, Stanford University, Stanford

    Google Scholar 

  • Huppmann D, Holz F (2009) A model for the global crude oil market using a multi-pool MCP approach. DIW Berlin, German Institute for Economic Research, Berlin

    Google Scholar 

  • IEA (2007a) Energy prices and taxes. OECD/IEA, Paris

  • IEA (2007b) World Energy Outlook 2006. International Energy Agency, Paris

  • IEA (2008) Review of international policies for vehicle fuel efficiency. IEA information paper, Aug 2008. OECD/IEA, Paris. http://www.iea.org/publications/freepublications/publication/vehicle_fuel.pdf. Accessed 1 Nov 2016

  • IEA (2013a) World Energy Outlook 2013. OECD/IEA, Paris

  • IEA (2013b) Data services. OECD/IEA, Paris

  • IEA (2014) World Energy Outlook 2014. OECD/IEA, Paris

  • IMF (2012) World Economic Outlook database. International Monetary Fund, Apr 2012

  • IPCC (2014) Climate Change 2014: mitigation of climate change. Contribution of Working Group III to the Fifth Assessment Report of the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge

  • Kaufmann RK, Bradford A, Belanger LH, Mclaughlin JP, Miki Y (2008) Determinants of OPEC production: implications for OPEC behavior. Energy Econ 30(2):333–351

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kverndokk S, Rose A (2008) Equity and justice in global warming policy. Int Rev Environ Resour Econ 2(2):135–176

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kverndokk S, Rosendahl KE (2013) Effects of transport regulation on the oil market: does market power matter? Scand J Econ 115(3):662–694

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lindholt L (2015) The tug-of-war between resource depletion and technological change in the global oil industry 1981–2009. Energy 93:1607–1616

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mabro R (1991) OPEC and the price of oil. Energy J 13:1–17

    Google Scholar 

  • Michielsen T (2014) Brown backstops versus the green paradox. J Environ Econ Manag 68:87–110

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ministry of Petroleum and Energy (2011) En næring for fremtida—Om petroleumsvirksomheten (An industry for the future—on the petroleum activity). Report no. 28 to the Storting (in Norwegian)

  • Okullo SJ, Reynès F (2011) Can reserve additions in mature crude oil provinces attenuate peak oil? Energy 36(9):5755–5764

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Okullo SJ, Reynès F, Hofkes MW (2015) Modelling peak oil and the geological constraints on oil production. Resour Energy Econ 40:36–56

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Okullo SJ, Reynès F, Hofkes MW (2016) Biofuel mandating and the green paradox, Draft, Aug 17

  • Roy RJ (2000) The rebound effect: some empirical evidence from India. Energy Policy 28:433–438

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Salant S (1976) Exhaustible resources and industry structure: a Nash–Cournot approach to the world oil market. J Polit Econ 84(5):1079–1093

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Salant S (1982) Imperfect competition in the world oil market. Lexington Books, Lanham

    Google Scholar 

  • Saunders HD (2015) Recent evidence for large rebound: elucidating the drivers and their implications for climate change models. Energy J 36(1):23–48

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Serletis A, Timilsina G, Vasetsky O (2011) International evidence on aggregate short-run and long-run interfuel substitution. Energy Econ 33:209–216

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sims R, Schaeffer R, Creutzig F, Cruz-Núñez X, D’Agosto M, Dimitriu D, Figueroa Meza MJ, Fulton L, Kobayashi S, Lah O, McKinnon A, Newman P, Ouyang M, Schauer JJ, Sperling D, Tiwari G (2014) Transport. In: Edenhofer O, Pichs-Madruga R, Sokona Y, Farahani E, Kadner S, Seyboth K, Adler A, Baum I, Brunner S, Eickemeier P, Kriemann B, Savolainen J, Schlömer S, von Stechow C, Zwickel T, Minx JC (eds) Climate change 2014: mitigation of climate change. Contribution of Working Group III to the Fifth Assessment Report of the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge

  • Singer SF (1983) The price of world oil. Annu Rev Energy 8:97–116

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sinn H-W (2008) Public policies against global warming: a supply side approach. Int Tax Public Financ 15:360–394

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Small KA, Van Dender K (2007) Fuel efficiency and motor vehicle travel: the declining rebound effect. Energy J 28(1):25–51

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Smith J (2005) Inscrutable OPEC? Behavioral tests of the cartel hypothesis. Energy J 26(1):51–82

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • United Nations (2011) World Population prospects: the 2010 revision

  • van der Ploeg F, Withagen C (2012) Is there really a green paradox? J Environ Econ Manag 64(3):342–363

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wang H, Zhou P, Zhou DQ (2012) An empirical study of direct rebound effect for passenger transport in urban China. Energy Econ 34(2):452–460

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • World Bank (2008) Climate Change and the World Bank Group: Phase I: an evaluation of World Bank win–win energy policy reforms. World Bank, Washington

  • World Bank (2012) GDP projections until 2030 on country level. Data received through personal communication

Download references

Acknowledgements

Thanks to Cathrine Hagem, Bjart Holtsmark, three anonymous referees, the guest editors and participants at the 11th Tinbergen Institute Conference on “Combating Climate Change” for comments. The project is financed by CREE, the PETROSAM program at the Research Council of Norway and the ENTRACTE Project financed by the European Union. While carrying out this research the authors have been associated with CREE - Oslo Centre for Research on Environmentally Friendly Energy. The CREE Centre acknowledges financial support from The Research Council of Norway.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Snorre Kverndokk.

Appendix: A Formal Description of the Petro2 Model

Appendix: A Formal Description of the Petro2 Model

1.1 Demand Side

We have seven regions i, where both demand and production take place: OPEC, Western Europe (EU/EFTA), U.S., Rest-OECD, Russia, China and Rest of the World (on the supply side we can divide OPEC into OPEC-Core and Non-Core OPEC). Demand for final energy goods in each region is divided into six end-user sectors s: Industry, Households, Other sectors (private and public services, defense, agriculture, fishing, other), Electricity, Road and rail transport, and Domestic and international aviation and domestic shipping. In addition, there is one global sector: International shipping. Further, the model has one transformation sector: Power generation. We have six energy commodities/fuels f: Oil (aggregate of different oil products), Gas, Electricity, Coal, Biomass and Biofuels for transport (Table 4).

All variables are functions of time. However, we generally skip the time notation in the following. The functional forms and parameters are generally constant over time.

Table 4 List of regions, sectors and energy goods in the Petro2 model

List of symbols

Endogenous variables

\(Q_{s,i}^{f} \) :

Demand for fuel f in sector s in region i

\(Q_{s,i} \) :

Demand for energy aggregate in sector s in region i (index)

\(P_{i}^{f} \) :

Producer price (node price) of fuel f in region i

\(PP_{s,i}^{f} \) :

End-user price of fuel f in sector s in region i

\(PI_{s,i} \) :

Price index for a fuel aggregate in sector s in region i

Exogenous variables and parameters

\(GDP_{s,i} \) :

Economic activity per capita index in sector s in region i

\(Pop_{i} \) :

Population index in region i

\(AEEI_{s,i} \) :

Autonomous improvements in energy efficiency index in sector s in region i

\(\beta _{s,i} \) :

Long-term income per capita elasticity in sector s in region i

\(\alpha _{s,i} \) :

Long-term price elasticity of the fuel aggregate in sector s in region i

\(\varepsilon _{s,i} \) :

Long-term elasticity of population growth in sector s in region i

\(b_{s,i} \) :

Short-term income per capita elasticity in sector s in region i

\(a_{s,i} \) :

Short-term price elasticity of the fuel aggregate in sector s in region i

\(e_{s,i} \) :

Short-term population elasticity in sector s in region i

\(\sigma _{s,i} \) :

Elasticity of substitution in sector s in region i

\(\theta _{s,i}^{f} \) :

Initial budget share of fuel f in sector s in region i

\(\omega _{s,i} \) :

Constant in demand function in sector s in region i

\(v_{s,i}^{f} \) :

Existing taxes/subsidies on fuel f in sector s in region i

\(z_{s,i}^{f} \) :

Costs of transportation, distribution and refining on fuel f in sector s in region i

\(\gamma _{s,i} \) :

Lag parameter in demand function in sector s in region i

The end-user price of fuel f in sector s in region i is equal to the regional producer price of the fuel (node price) plus costs of transportation, distribution and refining in addition to existing taxes/subsidies:

$$\begin{aligned} PP_{s,i}^{f} =P_{i}^{f} +z_{s,i}^{f} +v_{s,i}^{f} \end{aligned}$$
(2)

We assume that demand for energy goods can be described through CES demand functions. Hence, we construct weighted aggregated fuel price index for each sector s and region i:

$$\begin{aligned} PI_{s,i} =\frac{\left[ {\sum \nolimits _f{\left\{ {\theta _{s,i}^{f} \left( PP_{s,i}^{f} \right) ^{(1-\sigma _{s,i} )}} \right\} }} \right] ^{1/(1-\sigma _{s,i} )}}{\left[ {\sum \nolimits _f {\left\{ {\overline{\theta }_{s,i}^{f} \left( \overline{PP}_{s,i}^{f} \right) ^{(1-\sigma _{s,i} )}} \right\} } } \right] ^{1/(1-\sigma _{s,i} )}} \end{aligned}$$
(3)

where \(\overline{PP}_{s,i,0} \) denotes the (exogenous) actual price levels in the initial data year 2007. The budget shares for fuel f in the base year are given by:

$$\begin{aligned} \overline{\theta }_{s,i}^f = {{{\overline{PP} _{s,i,0}^f \cdot Q_{s,i}^f}\Bigg / {\sum \limits _{f f} \left( {\overline{PP} _{s,i}^{ff} \cdot Q_{s,i}^{ff}}\right) }}} \end{aligned}$$
(4)

where prices and quantities in (4) are measured at \(t =\) 0. We allow for exogenous changes in \(\theta _{s,i}^{f} \) to better model future changes in the composition of fuel consumption. So far we have only let oil as a share of total energy-use decline in the transport sector. Long-term demand for a fuel aggregate in sector sand region i is assumed to be on the following form:

$$\begin{aligned} Q_{s,i,t} =K_{s,i,t} \cdot \left( {AEEI_{s,i,t} PI_{s,i,t} } \right) ^{\alpha _{s,i} } \end{aligned}$$
(5)

where \(K_{s,i,t}\) is an exogenous factor representing other variables than the price:

$$\begin{aligned} K_{s,i,t} =\omega _{s,i,t} \cdot GDP_{s,i,t}^{\beta _{s,i} } \cdot Pop_{i,t}^{\varepsilon _{s,i} } \cdot AEEI_{s,i,t}. \end{aligned}$$

Note that energy efficiency improvements beyond the reference level are modelled by reducing the AEEI-parameters. However, as efficiency improvements imply lower costs of energy services, there will be a rebound effect as long as the price elasticity is strictly negative. Following eq. (3) in Kverndokk and Rosendahl (2013), the inverse demand function for fuel \(P_{f }(Q^{f})\) can be expressed as \(P_{f} \left( {Q^{f}} \right) =\frac{1}{AEEI}P_{s} \left( {\frac{Q^{f}}{AEEI}} \right) \), where \(P_{s}\) denotes the underlying inverse demand function for energy services.Footnote 21 From this expression we can derive the expression in (5).

In order to take account of short- and medium-term effects, the demand functions are specified in the following partial adjustment way (here we include the time notation):

$$\begin{aligned} Q_{s,i,t}= & {} K_{s,i,t} \cdot PI_{s,i,t}^{a_{s,i} } \cdot Q_{s,i,t-1}^{\gamma _{s,i} }\nonumber \\= & {} \omega _{s,i,t} \cdot PI_{s,i,t}^{a_{s,i} } \cdot GDP_{s,i,t}^{b_{s,i} } \cdot Pop_{i,t}^{e_{s,i} } \cdot \left( {AEEI_{s,i,t} } \right) ^{1+\alpha _{s,i} }\cdot Q_{s,i,t-1}^{\gamma _{s,i} } \end{aligned}$$
(6)

where \(\gamma _{s,i} \) is the lag-parameter (i.e. the effect of demand in the previous period \((0\le \gamma _{s,i} < 1)\). Then the long-term elasticities are given by: \(\alpha _{s,i} =\frac{a_{s,i} }{1-\gamma _{s,i}}, \beta _{s,i} =\frac{b_{s,i} }{1-\gamma _{s,i}}\) and \(\varepsilon _{s,i} =\frac{e_{s,i} }{1-\gamma _{s,i} }\). In the present model version \(\gamma _{s,i} = 0\). Hence, we have no lags on the demand side and the short- and the long-term effects are equal (i.e., \(\alpha _{s,i} = a_{s,i}, \beta _{s,i} = b_{s,i}, \varepsilon _{s,i} = e_{s,i})\). Then (6) is identical to (5). We normalize \(Q_{s,i,0}=\textit{ 1}\) and \(\textit{PI}_{s,i,0} =\textit{1}\) in the base year. Then, since GDP, Pop and AEEI all are indices equal to 1 in the base year, it must be that \(\omega =\textit{ 1}\) when \(\gamma _{s,i} = 0\).

Demand for fuel f in sector s in region i is a function of the demand for the fuel aggregate as well as the changes in the end-user price of the fuel aggregate relative to the end-user price of the fuel:

$$\begin{aligned} Q_{s,i}^{f} =\overline{Q}_{s,i,0}^{f} Q_{s,i} \frac{\theta _{s,i}^{f} }{\overline{\theta }_{s,i}^{f} }\left( \frac{{{PI_{s,i} }\bigg / {\overline{PI}_{s,i} }}}{{{PP_{s,i}^{f} } \bigg /{\overline{PP}_{s,i}^{f} }}}\right) ^{\sigma _{s,i} } \end{aligned}$$
(7)

where \(\overline{Q}_{s,i,0}^{f} \) is the (exogenous) actual demand in the data year. The elasticities of substitution (\(\sigma _{s,i} )\) can vary over sectors and regions.

1.2 Oil Supply Side

We have seven or eight oil producing regions i, depending on whether or not OPEC is split into OPEC-Core and Non-Core OPEC (this is the case in the current paper). Below we refer to OPEC as the cartel (C)—if OPEC is split into two, only OPEC-Core is assume to act as a cartel, while Non-Core OPEC is assumed to act as a competitive producer. The six Non-OPEC regions (NO) are always modelled as competitive producers.

List of symbols

Endogenous variables

\(P^{o} \) :

Oil producer price (equal across regions, hence index i is not needed)

\(X^{C} \) :

OPEC production (includes only OPEC-Core if OPEC is split into two)

\(X_{i}^{NO} \) :

Production in Non-OPEC region i (includes Non-Core OPEC if OPEC is split into two)

\(A^{C} \) :

Accumulated OPEC production

\(A_{i}^{NO} \) :

Accumulated Non-OPEC production in region i

\(C^{C} \) :

Total costs for OPEC

\(C_{i}^{NO} \) :

Total costs for Non-OPEC in region i

\(c^{C} \) :

Unit costs for OPEC

\(c_{i}^{NO} \) :

Unit costs for Non-OPEC region i

\(\lambda ^{C}\) :

Lagrange multiplier for OPEC

\(\lambda _{i}^{NO} \) :

Lagrange multiplier for Non-OPEC region i

\(\mu ^{C}\) :

Current shadow price for OPEC

\(\mu _{i}^{NO} \) :

Current shadow price for Non-OPEC region i

Exogenous variables and parameters

\(\varphi _{i}^{NO} \) :

Lag parameter for Non-OPEC region i

\(\eta ^{C}\) :

Convexity parameter for OPEC

\(\eta _{i}^{NO} \) :

Convexity parameter for Non-OPEC region i

\(\tau ^{C}\) :

Rate of technological progress for OPEC

\(\tau _{i}^{NO} \) :

Rate of technological progress for Non-OPEC region i

r :

Discount rate

\(K_{s,i} \) :

Exogenous term representing other variables than price in the demand function in region i (i.e., \(K_{s,i} =\omega _{s,i} \cdot GDP_{s,i}^{\beta _{s,i} } \cdot Pop_{i}^{\varepsilon _{i} } \cdot AIEE_{s,i}\))

Consumption of fuel (aggregate) in Eq. (6) can be written:

$$\begin{aligned} Q_{s,i} =PI_{s,i}^{\alpha _{s,i} }K_{s,i} \end{aligned}$$
(8)

where \(K_{s,i}\) denotes the exogenous parts of the RHS of (6).

Global oil consumption is given by (where we use (2), (7) and (8)):

$$\begin{aligned} Q^{o}= & {} \sum \limits _s {\sum \limits _i {Q_{s,i}^{o} } } =\sum \limits _s {\sum \limits _i {\left\{ {\overline{Q}_{s,i,0}^{o} Q_{s,i} \frac{\theta _{s,i}^{f} }{\overline{\theta }_{s,i}^{f} }\left( {\frac{PI_{s,i} /\overline{PI}_{s,i} }{PP_{s,i}^{o} /\overline{PP} _{s,i}^{o} }} \right) ^{\sigma _{s,i} }} \right\} } } \nonumber \\= & {} \sum \limits _s {\sum \limits _i {\left\{ {\overline{Q}_{s,i,0}^{o} \frac{\theta _{s,i}^{f} }{\overline{\theta }_{s,i}^{f} }\left( {\frac{\overline{PP}_{s,i}^{o} }{\overline{PI}_{s,i} }} \right) ^{\sigma _{s,i} }K_{s,i} \left( {PP^{o}} \right) ^{-\sigma _{s,i} }PI_{s,i}^{\alpha _{s,i} +\sigma _{s,i} }} \right\} } } \nonumber \\= & {} \sum \limits _s {\sum \limits _i {\left\{ {\varGamma _{1,s,i} \left( {PP^{o}} \right) ^{-\sigma _{s,i} }PI_{s,i}^{\alpha _{s,i} +\sigma _{s,i} }} \right\} } } \end{aligned}$$
(9)

where \(\Gamma _{1,s,i} =\overline{Q}_{s,i,0}^{o} \frac{\theta _{s,i}^{f} }{\overline{\theta }_{s,i}^{f} }\left( {\frac{\overline{PP}_{s,i,0}^{o} }{\overline{PI}_{s,i,0} }} \right) ^{\sigma _{s,i} }K_{s,i} \) include only exogenous terms.

1.3 The Optimization Problem for the Oil Producers

OPEC’s residual demand (for fixed Non-OPEC production \(X^{NO})\) is:

$$\begin{aligned} X^{C}=Q^{o}-X^{NO} \end{aligned}$$
(10)

OPEC maximizes the following discounted profit over time:

$$\begin{aligned} \varPi =\,\sum \limits _t {\left\{ {\left( {1+r} \right) ^{-t}\left( {P_{t}^{o} X_{t}^{C} -C_{t}^{C} \left( {X_{t}^{C} ,A_{t}^{C} } \right) } \right) } \right\} } \end{aligned}$$
(11)

s.t. \(A_{t}^{C} -A_{t-1}^{C} =X_{t}^{C} \)

The cost function of OPEC in period t has the following functional form:

$$\begin{aligned} C_{t}^{C} \left( X_{t}^{C} ,A_{t}^{C} \right) =c_{t}^{C} \left( A_{t}^{C} \right) X_{t}^{C} \end{aligned}$$
(12)

where \(c_{t}^{C} \) are the unit costs given by the following function:

$$\begin{aligned} c_{t}^{C} \left( A_{t}^{C} \right) =c_{0}^{C} \cdot e^{\eta \cdot ^{C}A_{t}^{C} -\tau ^{C} t} \end{aligned}$$
(13)

We assume that unit costs are increasing in accumulated extraction \(A^{C.}\). Hence, the Lagrangian function becomes:

$$\begin{aligned} L= & {} \,\sum \limits _t {\left\{ {\left( {1+r} \right) ^{-t}\left( {P_{t}^{o} \left( {Q_{t}^{o} -X_{t}^{NO} } \right) -c_{t}^{C} (A_{t}^{C} )\cdot \left( {Q_{t}^{o} -X_{t}^{NO} } \right) } \right) } \right\} }\nonumber \\&+\sum \limits _t {\left\{ {\mu _{t}^{C} \cdot \left( {1+r} \right) ^{-t}\cdot \left( {A_{t}^{C} -A_{t-1}^{C} -\left( {Q_{t}^{o} -X_{t}^{NO} } \right) } \right) } \right\} } \end{aligned}$$
(14)

where \(\mu _{t}^{C} >0\) is the current value of the shadow price of the resource at period t, and where \(Q^{o}\) is a function of \(P^{o}\) [see Eq. (9) above].

Before differentiating L wrt \(P^{o}\), it is useful to differentiate \(Q^{o}\) wrt \(P^{o}\):

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\partial Q^{o}}{\partial P^{o}}= & {} -\sum \limits _s {\sum \limits _i {\left\{ {\varGamma _{1,s,i} \sigma _{s,i} \left( {PP_{s,i}^{o} } \right) ^{-\sigma _{s,i} -1}PI_{s,i}^{\alpha _{s,i} +\sigma _{s,i} }\left( {\frac{\partial PP_{s,i}^{o} }{\partial P^{o}}} \right) } \right\} } } \nonumber \\&+\sum \limits _s {\sum \limits _i {\left\{ {\varGamma _{1,s,i} \left( {PP_{s,i}^{o} } \right) ^{-\sigma _{s,i} }\left( {\alpha _{s,i} +\sigma _{s,i} } \right) PI_{s,i}^{\alpha _{s,i} +\sigma _{s,i} -1}\left( {\frac{\partial PI_{s,i} }{\partial P^{o}}} \right) } \right\} } } \nonumber \\= & {} -\sum \limits _s {\sum \limits _i {\left\{ {\varGamma _{1,s,i} \sigma _{s,i} \left( {PP_{s,i}^{o} } \right) ^{-\sigma _{s,i} -1}PI_{s,i}^{\alpha _{s,i} +\sigma _{s,i} }} \right\} } } \nonumber \\&+\sum \limits _s {\sum \limits _i {\left\{ {\varGamma _{1,s,i} \theta _{s,i}^{0} \left( {\alpha _{s.i} +\sigma _{s,i} } \right) \left( {PP_{s,i}^{o} } \right) ^{-2\sigma _{s,i} }PI_{s,i}^{\alpha _{s,i} +\sigma _{s,i} }\left( {\sum \limits _f {\theta _{s,i}^{f} \left( {PP_{s,i}^{f} } \right) ^{1-\sigma _{s,i} }} } \right) ^{-1}} \right\} } } \nonumber \\= & {} -\sum \limits _s {\sum \limits _i {\left\{ {\overline{Q}_{s,i,0}^{o} \frac{\theta _{s,i}^{o} }{\overline{\theta }_{s,i}^{o} }\left( {\frac{\overline{PP}_{s,i}^{o} }{\overline{PI}_{s,i} }} \right) ^{\sigma _{s,i} }K_{s,i} \sigma _{s,i} \left( {PP_{s,i}^{o} } \right) ^{-\sigma _{s,i} -1}PI_{s,i}^{\alpha _{s,i} +\sigma _{s,i} }} \right\} } } \nonumber \\&+\sum \limits _s \sum \limits _i \left\{ \overline{Q}_{s,i,0}^{o} \frac{\left( {\theta _{s,i}^{o} } \right) ^{2}}{\overline{\theta }_{s,i}^{o} }\left( {\frac{\overline{PP}_{s,i}^{o} }{\overline{PI}_{s,i} }} \right) ^{\sigma _{s,i} }K_{s,i} \right. \nonumber \\&\left. \quad \times \left( {\alpha _{s,i} +\sigma _{s,i} } \right) \left( {PP_{s,i}^{o} } \right) ^{-2\sigma _{s,i} }PI_{s,i}^{\alpha _{s,i} +\sigma _{s,i} }\left( \sum \limits _f \theta _{s,i}^{f}\left( {PP_{s,i}^{f} } \right) ^{1-\sigma _{s,i} } \right) ^{-1} \right\} \nonumber \\= & {} -\sum \limits _s {\sum \limits _i {\left\{ {\overline{Q}_{s,i,0}^{o} \frac{\theta _{s,i}^{o} }{\overline{\theta }_{s,i}^{o} }\left( {\overline{PP}_{s,i}^{o} } \right) ^{\sigma _{s,i} }K_{s,i} \sigma _{s,i} \left( {PP_{s,i}^{o} } \right) ^{-\sigma _{s,i} -1}PI_{s,i}^{\alpha _{s,i} +\sigma _{s,i} }} \right\} } } \nonumber \\&+\sum \limits _s \sum \limits _i \left\{ \overline{Q}_{s,i,0}^{o} \frac{\left( {\theta _{s,i}^{o} } \right) ^{2}}{\overline{\theta }_{s,i}^{o} }\left( {\overline{PP}_{s,i}^{o} } \right) ^{\sigma _{s,i} }K_{s,i}\right. \nonumber \\&\left. \quad \times \left( {\alpha _{s,i} +\sigma _{s,i} } \right) \left( {PP_{s,i}^{o} } \right) ^{-2\sigma _{s,i} }PI_{s,i}^{\alpha _{s,i} +\sigma _{s,i} }\left( {\sum \limits _f {\theta _{s,i}^{f} \left( {PP_{s,i}^{f} } \right) ^{1-\sigma _{s,i} }} } \right) ^{-1} \right\} \end{aligned}$$
(15)

where we used \(\frac{\partial PP_{s,i}^{o} }{\partial P^{o}}=1\) (cf. Eq. 2) and

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\partial PI_{s,i} }{\partial P^{o}}= & {} \frac{\partial }{\partial P^{o}}\left\{ {{{\left[ {\sum \limits _f {\theta _{s,i}^f{{\left( {PP_{s,i}^f} \right) }^{1 - {\sigma _{s,i}}}}} } \right] }^{\frac{1}{{(1 - {\sigma _{s,i}})}}}}}\Bigg / {{{\left[ {\sum \limits _f {\overline{\theta }_{s,i}^f{{\left( {\overline{PP} _{s,i}^f} \right) }^{1 - {\sigma _{s,i}}}}} } \right] }^{\frac{1}{{(1 - {\sigma _{s,i}})}}}}}\right\} \\= & {} \frac{1}{\varGamma _{2} }\cdot \frac{\partial }{\partial P^{o}}\left[ {\sum \limits _f {\theta _{s,i}^{f} \left( {PP_{s,i}^{f} } \right) ^{1-\sigma _{s,i} }} } \right] ^{\frac{1}{(1-\sigma _{s,i} )}} \\= & {} \frac{1}{\varGamma _{2} }\frac{1}{(1-\sigma _{s,i} )}\left[ {\sum \limits _f {\theta _{s,i}^{f} \left( {PP_{s,i}^{f} } \right) ^{(1-\sigma _{s,i} )}} } \right] ^{\frac{1}{(1-\sigma _{s,i} )}-1}\cdot \theta _{s,i}^{o} \cdot \left( {1-\sigma _{s,i} } \right) \cdot \left( {PP_{s,i}^{o} } \right) ^{-\sigma _{s,i} } \\= & {} \frac{1}{\varGamma _{2} }\theta _{s,i}^{o} \cdot \left( {PP_{s,i}^{o} } \right) ^{-\sigma _{s,i} }\cdot \left[ {\sum \limits _f {\theta _{s,i}^{f} \left( {PP_{s,i}^{f} } \right) ^{(1-\sigma _{s,i} )}} } \right] ^{\frac{1}{(1-\sigma _{s,i} )}-1}\\= & {} \theta _{s,i}^{o} \cdot \left( {PP_{s,i}^{o} } \right) ^{-\sigma _{s,i} }\cdot \frac{\left[ {\sum \nolimits _f {\theta _{s,i}^{f} \left( {PP_{s,i}^{f} } \right) ^{(1-\sigma _{s,i} )}} } \right] ^{\frac{1}{(1-\sigma _{s,i} )}-1}}{\left[ {\sum \nolimits _f {\overline{\theta }_{s,i}^{f} \left( {\overline{PP}_{s,i}^{f} } \right) ^{1-\sigma _{s,i} }} } \right] ^{\frac{1}{(1-\sigma _{s,i} )}}} \\= & {} \theta _{s,i}^{o} \cdot \left( {PP_{s,i}^{o}} \right) ^{-\sigma _{s,i} }PI_{s,i} \left( {\sum \limits _f {\theta _{s,i}^{f} \left( {PP_{s,i}^{f} } \right) ^{(1-\sigma _{s,i} )}}} \right) ^{-1},\\ \hbox {where}&\varGamma _{2} =\left[ {\sum \limits _f {\overline{\theta }_{s,i}^{f} \left( {\overline{PP} _{s,i}^{f} } \right) ^{1-\sigma _{s,i} }} } \right] ^{\frac{1}{(1-\sigma _{s,i} )}}. \end{aligned}$$

To ease computation the following formulation of (15) is used in GAMS:

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\partial Q^{o}}{\partial P^{o}}&=-\sum \limits _s {\sum \limits _i {\left\{ {\sigma _{s,i} \overline{Q}_{s,i,0}^{o} \frac{\theta _{s,i}^{o} }{\overline{\theta }_{s,i}^{o} }\left( {\overline{PP}_{s,i}^{o} } \right) ^{\sigma _{s,i} }K_{s,i} PI_{s,i}^{\alpha _{s,i} +\sigma _{s,i} }\left( {PP_{s,i}^{o} } \right) ^{-\sigma _{s,i} -1}} \right\} } } \nonumber \\&\quad +\sum \limits _s \sum \limits _i \left\{ \left( {\alpha _{s,i} +\sigma _{s,i} } \right) \overline{Q}_{s,i,0}^{o} \frac{\left( {\theta _{s,i}^{o} } \right) ^{2}}{\overline{\theta }_{s,i}^{o} }\left( {\overline{PP}_{s,i}^{o} } \right) ^{\sigma _{s,i} }K_{s,i} PI_{s,i}^{\alpha _{s,i} +\sigma _{s,i} -1}\left( {PP_{s,i}^{o} } \right) ^{-\sigma _{s,i} }\right. \nonumber \\&\left. \quad \times \left( {PP_{s,i}^{o} } \right) ^{-\sigma _{s,i} }PI_{s,i} \frac{1}{\sum \nolimits _f {\theta _{s,i}^{f}\left( {PP_{s,i}^{f} } \right) ^{1-\sigma _{s,i} }} } \right\} \nonumber \\&=-\sum \limits _s {\sum \limits _i {\left\{ {\sigma _{s,i} \overline{Q} _{s,i,0}^{o} \frac{\theta _{s,i}^{o} }{\overline{\theta }_{s,i}^{o} }\left( {\overline{PP}_{s,i}^{o} } \right) ^{\sigma _{s,i} }K_{s,i} PI_{s,i} ^{\alpha _{s,i} +\sigma _{s,i} }\left( {PP_{s,i}^{o} } \right) ^{-\sigma _{s,i} -1}} \right\} } } \nonumber \\&\quad +\sum \limits _s \sum \limits _i \left\{ \left( {\alpha _{s.i} +\sigma _{s,i} } \right) \overline{Q}_{s,i,0}^{o} \frac{\left( {\theta _{s,i}^{o} } \right) ^{2}}{\overline{\theta }_{s,i}^{o} }\left( {\overline{PP}_{s,i}^{o} } \right) ^{\sigma _{s,i} }K_{s,i} PI_{s,i}^{\alpha _{s,i} +\sigma _{s,i} }\left( {PP_{s,i}^{o} } \right) ^{-2\sigma _{s,i} }\right. \nonumber \\&\left. \quad \times \frac{1}{\sum \nolimits _f {\theta _{s,i}^{f} \left( {PP_{s,i}^{f} } \right) ^{1-\sigma _{s,i} }} } \right\} \nonumber \\&=-\sum \limits _s {\sum \limits _i {\left\{ {\sigma _{s,i} \overline{Q} _{s,i,0}^{o} \frac{\theta _{s,i}^{o} }{\overline{\theta }_{s,i}^{o} }\left( {\overline{PP}_{s,i}^{o} } \right) ^{\sigma _{s,i} }K_{s,i} PI_{s,i} ^{\alpha _{s,i} +\sigma _{s,i} }\left( {PP_{s,i}^{o} } \right) ^{-\sigma _{s,i} -1}} \right\} } } \nonumber \\&\quad +\sum \limits _s \sum \limits _i \left\{ \left( {\alpha _{s,i} +\sigma _{s,i} } \right) \overline{Q}_{s,i,0}^{o} \frac{\left( {\theta _{s,i}^{o} } \right) ^{2}}{\overline{\theta }_{s,i}^{o} }\left( {\overline{PP}_{s,i}^{o} } \right) ^{\sigma _{s,i} }K_{s,i} PI_{s,i}^{\alpha _{s,i} +2\sigma _{s,i} -1}\left( {PP_{s,i}^{o} } \right) ^{-2\sigma _{s,i} }\right. \nonumber \\&\left. \quad \times \frac{1}{\sum \nolimits _f {\theta _{s,i}^{f} \left( {\overline{PP}_{s,i}^{f} } \right) ^{1-\sigma _{s,i} }} } \right\} \end{aligned}$$
(15*)

We now differentiate L wrt \(P^{o}\):

$$\begin{aligned} ({1+r})^{t}\frac{\partial L}{\partial P_{t}^{o} }=\,\left( {Q_{t}^{o} -X_{t}^{NO} } \right) +\left( {P_{t}^{o} -c_{t}^{C} \left( {A_{t}^{C} } \right) -\mu _{t}^{C} } \right) \frac{\partial Q_{t}^{o} }{\partial P_{t}^{o} }=0 \end{aligned}$$
(16)

where we can insert for \({\partial Q_{t}^{o} } \big /{\partial P_{t}^{o} }\) from Eq. (15) above.

If we rearrange Eq. (16) we get:

$$\begin{aligned} P_{t}^{o} =c_{t}^{C} \left( {A_{t}^{C} } \right) +\mu _{t}^{C} -\frac{\partial P_{t}^{o} }{\partial Q_{t}^{o} }\left( {Q_{t}^{o} -X_{t}^{NO} } \right) \end{aligned}$$
(17)

where the last term on the right hand side is the cartel rent.

Next, we differentiate wrt \(A^{C}\):

$$\begin{aligned} \left( {1+r} \right) ^{t}\frac{\partial L}{\partial A_{t}^{C} }=\,-\frac{\partial c_{t}^{C} \left( {A_{t}^{C} } \right) }{\partial A_{t}^{C} }\left( {Q_{t}^{C} -X_{t}^{NO} } \right) +\mu _{t}^{C} -\left( {1+r} \right) ^{-1}\mu _{t+1}^{C} =0 \end{aligned}$$
(18)

or:

$$\begin{aligned} \eta ^{C}c_{t}^{C} \left( {A_{t}^{C} } \right) \left( {Q_{t}^{C} -X_{t}^{NO} } \right) -\mu _{t}^{C} +\left( {1+r} \right) ^{-1}\mu _{t+1}^{C} =0 \end{aligned}$$
(19)

Whereas the discounted shadow price decreases over time, the running shadow price \(\mu \) can both decrease and increase over time. When the cartel stops producing, the shadow price reaches zero.

Let us turn to the competitive fringe’s optimization problem. The cost function of Non-OPEC regions in period t has the following functional form:

$$\begin{aligned} C_{i,t}^{NO} \left( X_{i,t}^{NO} ,A_{i,t}^{NO} \right)= & {} c_{i,t}^{NO} \left( A_{i,t}^{NO} \right) e^{\phi _{i}^{NO} \left( {\frac{X_{i,t}^{NO} }{X_{i,t-1}^{NO} }-1} \right) }X_{i,t}^{NO} \end{aligned}$$
(20)
$$\begin{aligned} c_{i,t}^{NO} \left( A_{i,t}^{NO} \right)= & {} c_{i,0}^{NO} \cdot e^{\eta _{i}^{NO} A_{i,t}^{NO} -\tau _{i}^{NO} t} \end{aligned}$$
(21)

We here assume that there are no adjustment costs for Non-OPEC production, reflected by the parameter \(\phi _{i}^{NO} = 0\).

However, we assume the following cost function:

$$\begin{aligned} C_{i,t}^{NO} \left( X_{i,t}^{NO} ,A_{i,t}^{NO} \right) =\kappa _{A,t} c_{i,t}^{NO} \left( A_{i,t}^{NO} \right) \left( {X_{i,t}^{NO} } \right) ^{\kappa _{B,t} } \end{aligned}$$
(20b)

where \(\kappa _{A,t}\) and \(\kappa _{B,t}\) are exogenous parameters. In the initial years, \(\kappa _{B,t}\) >1 to reflect increasing marginal costs also within a period. \(\kappa _{B,t}\) is then gradually reduced to one over time. \(\kappa _{A,t}\) is calibrated so that marginal costs at \(X_{i,0}^{NO} \)are the same as with \(\kappa _{A,t} = \kappa _{B,t} = 1\), i.e., \(\kappa _{A,t} =\left( {\kappa _{B,t} } \right) ^{-1}\left( {X_{i,t}^{NO} } \right) ^{1-\kappa _{B,t} }\)

The optimization problem can be written:

$$\begin{aligned} \text{ Max }\,\sum \limits _t {\left\{ {(1+r)^{-t}\left( {X_{i,t}^{NO} P_{t} -C_{i,t}^{NO} \left( X_{i,t}^{NO} ,A_{i,t}^{NO} \right) } \right) } \right\} } \end{aligned}$$
(22)

with \(A_{i,t}^{NO} -A_{i,t-1}^{NO} =X_{i,t}^{NO}\).

The Lagrangian function becomes:

$$\begin{aligned} L= & {} \sum \limits _t {\left\{ {(1+r)^{-t}\left( {X_{i,t}^{NO} P_{t} -C_{i,t}^{NO} \left( X_{i,t}^{NO} ,A_{i,t}^{NO}\right) } \right) } \right\} }\nonumber \\&+\sum \limits _t {\left\{ {\mu _{i,t}^{NO} \cdot (1+r)^{-t}\cdot \left( A_{i,t}^{NO} -A_{i,t-1}^{NO} -X_{i,t}^{NO} \right) } \right\} } \end{aligned}$$
(23)

where \(\mu _{i}^{NO} =-(1+r)\lambda _{i}^{NO} >0\) is the current value of the shadow price on the resource constraint, and \(\lambda _{i}^{NO}\) is the present value of the shadow price (the Lagrange multiplier).

The first order condition wrt.\(X_{i,t}^{NO}\) is:

$$\begin{aligned} P_{t}= & {} \frac{C_{i,t}^{NO} \left( X_{i,t}^{NO} ,A_{i,t}^{NO} \right) }{X_{i,t}^{NO} }+\frac{\varphi _{i}^{NO} }{X_{i,t-1}^{NO} }C_{i,t}^{NO} \left( X_{i,t}^{NO} ,A_{i,t}^{NO} \right) \nonumber \\&-(1+r)^{-1}\frac{\varphi _{i}^{NO} X_{i,t+1}^{NO} }{(X_{i,t}^{NO} )^{2}}C_{i,t}^{NO} \left( X_{i,t+1}^{NO} ,A_{i,t+1}^{NO} \right) +\mu _{i,t}^{NO} \end{aligned}$$
(24)

Note that if \(\phi _{\mathrm {i}}^{\mathrm {NO}} = 0\), (24) simplifies to:

$$\begin{aligned} P_{t} =c_{i,t}^{NO} \left( A_{i,t}^{NO} \right) +\mu _{i,t}^{NO} \end{aligned}$$
(25)

The first term on the right-hand-side in Eqs. (24) and (25) is the average unit cost. The second term in (24) accounts for the rising short-term unit costs. Together, the two first terms are the marginal production costs in the short term (for an exogenous \(X_{t-1}^{NO}\)). The third term is negative, taking into account the positive effect on future cost reductions of increasing current production. The last term in (24) and (25) is the scarcity effect; the alternative cost of producing one unit more today as it increases future costs due to scarcity.

Alternatively, using (20b) we get the following first order condition:

$$\begin{aligned} P_{t} =\kappa _{B,t} \frac{C_{i,t}^{NO} \left( X_{i,t}^{NO} ,A_{i,t}^{NO}\right) }{X_{i,t}^{NO} }+\mu _{i,t}^{NO} \end{aligned}$$
(24b)

When we differentiate L wrt \(A_{i,t}^{NO}\) we get the following condition for changes in the Lagrange multiplier (identical to the corresponding condition for OPEC above):

$$\begin{aligned} \eta _{i}^{NO} \cdot C_{i,t}^{NO} \left( X_{i,t}^{NO} ,A_{i,t}^{NO} \right) -\mu _{i,t}^{NO} +\left( {1+r} \right) ^{-1}\mu _{i,t+1}^{NO} =0 \end{aligned}$$
(26)

Relationships between price and substitution elasticities

In the model described above, \(\alpha \) is the direct price elasticity of the energy aggregate, while \(\sigma \) is the substitution elasticity between energy goods in the energy aggregate. The direct price elasticity of oil follows implicitly from \(\alpha \) and \(\sigma \), as well as the value shares \(\theta \) and prices of the energy goods. Since we may want to specify the direct price elasticity of oil instead of the elasticity of the energy aggregate, it is useful to derive the exact relationship between these two, and specifically derive a reduced form expression for the latter as a function of the former (and other necessary parameters/variables).

Let \(\xi _{s,i}^{o} =\frac{\partial Q_{s,i}^{o}}{\partial PP_{s,i} ^{o}}\frac{PP_{s,i}^{o}}{Q_{s,i}^{o}}\) denote the direct price elasticity of oil in sector sand region i. From (15) and (9) we have \(\Big (\)note that \(\frac{\partial Q_{s,i}^{o}}{\partial PP_{s,i}^{o}}=\frac{\partial Q_{s,i} ^{o}}{\partial P^{o}}\Big )\) Footnote 22:

$$\begin{aligned} \xi _{s,i}^{o} =\frac{\partial Q_{s,i}^{o}}{\partial PP_{s,i} ^{o}}\frac{PP_{s,i}^{o}}{Q_{s,i}^{o}}=-\sigma _{s,i} +\left( {\alpha _{s.i} +\sigma _{s,i} } \right) \theta _{s,i}^{o} \frac{\left( {PP_{s,i}^{o}} \right) ^{1-\sigma _{s,i} }}{\sum \nolimits _f {\theta _{s,i}^{f} \left( {PP_{s,i}^{f} } \right) ^{1-\sigma _{s,i} }}} \end{aligned}$$

This can alternatively be expressed as:

$$\begin{aligned} \alpha _{s,i} =\left( {\xi _{s,i}^{o} +\sigma _{s,i} } \right) \;\frac{\sum \nolimits _f {\theta _{s,i}^{f} \left( {\overline{PP} _{s,i}^{f} } \right) ^{1-\sigma _{s,i} }} }{\theta _{s,i}^{o} \left( {\overline{PP}_{s,i}^{o} } \right) ^{1-\sigma _{s,i} }}-\sigma _{s,i} \end{aligned}$$
(27)

In the special case where all end-user prices in a sector/region are equal across energy goods, we get:

$$\begin{aligned} \alpha _{s,i} =\frac{\xi _{s,i}^{o} +\sigma _{s,i} }{\theta _{s,i}^{o} }-\sigma _{s,i} \end{aligned}$$
(27*)

In the calibration of the model, we use (27) to derive estimates of \(\alpha \), given estimates of the RHS parameters and base-year levels of the variables.

1.4 Oil Demand Share by Sector and Region

See Table 5.

Table 5 Oil demand share by sector and region in 2007 (%)

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Aune, F.R., Bøeng, A.C., Kverndokk, S. et al. Fuel Efficiency Improvements: Feedback Mechanisms and Distributional Effects in the Oil Market. Environ Resource Econ 68, 15–45 (2017). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10640-017-0134-7

Download citation

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10640-017-0134-7

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation