Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

Organized crime, money laundering and legal economy: theory and simulations

  • Published:
European Journal of Law and Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

This paper proposes a dynamic model to simulate the relationships between the profits of organized crime, money laundering and legal investments. We develop a macro framework in which organized crime can increase its possibilities to invest in the legal sector by resorting to effective but costly money laundering schemes. The model explores the conditions under which the effectiveness of money laundering causes a positive trend in the legal assets owned by the criminal organizations. We use the model to simulate the total amount of legal wealth generated by organized crime through drug trafficking in different world regions, with particular attention to Europe.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4
Fig. 5
Fig. 6
Fig. 7
Fig. 8
Fig. 9
Fig. 10
Fig. 11

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Fiorentini and Peltzman (1995).

  2. Costa (2009).

  3. Europol (2006).

  4. Europol (2009).

  5. For a survey of the literature see Walker and Unger (2009), Unger (2009), Argentiero et al. (2008), Barone and Masciandaro (2008) and Schneider and Windischbauer (2008). See also Bagella et al. (2009). Micro dynamic models are proposed in Argentiero et al. (2008), Bagella et al. (2009).

  6. Schneider and Windischbauer (2008).

  7. Masciandaro (1999) and Barone and Masciandaro (2008).

  8. In general the data plausibility is a problem to face in analyzing all the illegal markets: for the estimates of the illegal drugs markets see Reuter and Greenfield (2001), Blickman (2003) and Thoumi (2003).

  9. Europol (2006).

  10. Europol (2009).

  11. Europol (2009).

  12. Masciandaro (1999) and Masciandaro et al. (2007).

  13. Microeconomic models on illegal activities and money laundering are presented in Masciandaro (2007), Siva Moreira (2007), Argentiero et al. (2008) and Ferwenda (2009).

  14. The financial sector is the most affected by money laundering (Europol 2006, 2007, 2008). From the point of view of the supply of money laundering services the financial industry acquires a peculiar role for two key attributes: a greater than normal degree of ‘opacity’ (information asymmetry), since the exchanges and flows of purchasing power are filtered, coordinated and administered by specialised operators (the intermediaries); the privileged position of such operators. For criminal parties, the presence of intermediaries that collude with them (crook intermediaries) and/or honest but inefficient in protecting their integrity (lax intermediaries) increases the possibility of using the financial services system for their concealment objectives. See Takatz (2007), Masciandaro et al. (2007), Picard and Pieretti (2009), Dalla Pellegrina and Masciandaro (2009) and Unger and Van Waarden (2009).

  15. From an economic point of view, the money laundering cost is the overall price of the operation, without any distinction among the three conventional stages—Schott (2006)—of placement, layering and integration.

  16. Barone and Masciandaro (2008) proposed a static model, where also for the re-investment in the illegal sector it is necessary to clean the money.

  17. Europol (2009).

  18. Europol (2006).

  19. We assume that in general the money laundering procedures represent a cost for organized crime, notwithstanding it is well known that the criminal groups can implement legal businesses (fast cash business as restaurants, bars, gaming halls, supermarkets) also for the concealment of their illegal proceeds—Europol (2006, 2007, 2009)—and these businesses can produce profits.

  20. Europol (2006, 2007, 2008).

  21. Europol (2006).

  22. Europol (2009).

  23. Europol (2006, 2007, 2009).

  24. Europol (2006).

  25. It is also an increasing function for \( r_{i} < {\frac{y}{{1 - y}}} \) and \( r_{l} < {\frac{{1 - f}}{f}} \) but these conditions are not interesting for our empirical analysis, as we will show in the Appendix 1.

  26. On the relationship between money laundering and its regulation see Masciandaro (1999) and Chong and Lopez-de-Silanes (2006). On the evolution of the anti-money laundering regulations see Arnone and Padoan (2008).

  27. Europol (2006, 2007, 2008).

  28. Europol (2009).

  29. Europol (2006).

  30. Schneider (2007).

  31. Europol (2006, 2008, 2009).

  32. Source: our calculation using data from United Nations (2005).

  33. United Nations (2005).

  34. The launderer can invest in capital market to wash dirty money, however he prefers assets like bonds and security with low risk in order to minimize the probability of losing money (see Unger 2007).

  35. Unger (2007).

  36. We obtain this value estimating the average of the policy interest rates for advanced and emerging countries. For this purpose we used BIS data and data from National Central Bank of several countries.

  37. See Unger (2007), p. 152.

  38. Reuter and Truman (2004).

  39. Famous launderers were Stephen Saccoccia, in (1993), who laundered from US$ 200 to US$ 750 million, charging to his clients a commission of 10%, German Cadavid who laundered in 1995, $ 50–60 million pound, charging to his clients a commission of 7%, and others such as Robert Hirsch, Richard Spence, Harvey Weinig: see Reuter and Truman (2004), pp. 35–40.

  40. In Masciandaro (2008) an Offshore Attitude Index (or laxity index) is proposed, using a two stage process. First stage: for each country it has been checked whether it was a member of both OECD and FATF (strong onshore attitude, or minimum level of offshore attitude) or it was listed in each of the three types of OFC list: the Financial Stability (FSF) list, the OECD list, the FATF list. The degree of offshore attitude will depend on the number of the country presences into three different blacklists (this number ranges from 0 to 3). Second stage: it has been assigned numerical values to each level of offshore attitude: 0 if a country shows a strong onshore attitude, 1 if a country doesn’t show a strong onshore attitude, but, at the same time, it wasn’t in any blacklist; 2, 3 and 4 if a country was present respectively in one, two, or three blacklists. For more details see Masciandaro (2008).

  41. The complete simulations are available on request.

References

  • Argentiero, A., Bagella, M., & Busato, F. (2008). Money laundering in a two sector model: Using theory for measurement. European Journal of Law and Economics, 26(3), 341–359.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Arnone, M., & Padoan, P. C. (2008). Anti-money laundering by international institutions: A preliminary assessment. European Journal of Law and Economics, 26(3), 361–386.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bagella, M., Busato, F., & Argentiero, A. (2009). Money laundering in a microfounded dynamic model: Simulations for the U.S. and the EU—15 Economies. Review of Law and Economics, 5, 879–902.

    Google Scholar 

  • Barone, R., & Masciandaro, D. (2008), Worldwide Anti-Money Laundering: Regulation: Estimating the costs and benefits. Global Business and Economics Review, 10(3), 243–264.

    Google Scholar 

  • Blickman, T. (2003). The economic impact of the illicit drug industry. Transnational Institute, Amsterdam: Mimeo.

  • Chong, A., & Lopez-de-Silanes, F. (2006). Money laundering and its regulation. Working paper no. 590, Research Department, Inter-American Development Bank, Washington DC.

  • Coase, R. (1960). The nature of the firm. Economica (6), 386.

  • Costa, A. M. (2009). How can parliaments fight organized crime? United Nations Office on Drugs and Crime, September 13, mimeo.

  • Dalla Pellegrina, L., & Masciandaro, D. (2009). The risk based approach in the New European anti-money laundering legislation: A law and economics view. Review of Law and Economics, 932–952.

  • Europol. (2006). OCTA 2009: EU organized crime threat assessment. The Netherlands: European Police Office.

  • Europol. (2007). OCTA 2009: EU organized crime threat assessment. The Netherlands: European Police Office.

  • Europol. (2008). OCTA 2009: EU organized crime threat assessment. The Netherlands: European Police Office.

  • Europol. (2009). OCTA 2009: EU organized crime threat assessment. The Netherlands: European Police Office.

  • Ferwenda, J. (2009). The economics of crime and money laundering: Does anti—Money laundering policy reduce crime? Utrecht School of Economics. Review of Law and Economics, 903–929.

  • Fiorentini, G., & Peltzman, S. (1995). The economics of organized crime. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Masciandaro, D. (1999). Money laundering: the economics of regulation. European Journal of Law and Economics, 26(3), 245.

    Google Scholar 

  • Masciandaro, D. (2007). Economics of money laundering: A primer, Paolo Baffi Centre. Working Paper, n.171.

  • Masciandaro, D. (2008). Offshore financial centres: The political economy of regulation. European Journal of Law and Economics, 26, 307–340.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Masciandaro, D., Takats, E., & Unger, B. (2007). Black finance. The economics of money laundering. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.

    Google Scholar 

  • Picard, P. M., & Pieretti, P. (2009). Bank secrecy, illicit money and offshore financial centres. Paolo Baffi Centre, Research Series, n.45.

  • Quirk, P. J. (1996). Macroeconomic implications of money laundering. Washington, DC: International Monetary Fund.

  • Quirk, P. J. (1997). Money laundering: Muddying the macroeconomy. Washington, DC: International Monetary Fund.

  • Reuter, P., & Greenfield, V. (2001). Measuring global drug markets. World Economics, 2(4), 159–173.

    Google Scholar 

  • Reuter, P., & Truman, E. M. (2004). Chasing dirty money: Progress on anti-money laundering. Washington, DC: Institute for International Economics.

  • Schneider, F. (2007). Shadow economies and corruption all over the world: New estimates for 145 countries. Economics, The Open Access, Open Assesment E-Journal (No. 2007-9).

  • Schneider, F., & Windischbauer, U. (2008). Money laundering: some facts. European Journal of Law and Economics, 26(3), 387–404.

    Google Scholar 

  • Schott, P. A. (2006). Reference guide to anti-money laundering and combating the financing of terrorism. Washington, DC: International Monetary Fund and the World Bank.

  • Siva Moreira, T. B. (2007). A two period model of money laundering and organized crime. Economics Bulletin, 11(3), 1–5.

    Google Scholar 

  • Smekens, M., & Verbruggen, M. (2004). De illegale Economie in Nederland. Centraal Bureau voor de Statistiek.

  • Stigler, G. (1964), Public regulation of the securities markets. Journal of Business (37), 117.

  • Takats, E. (2007). A theory of “Crying Wolf”: The economics of money laundering enforcement. IMF Working Paper, n.81.

  • Tanzi, V. (1996). Money laundering and the international financial system. Working paper, International Monetary Fund, 96(55).

  • Tanzi, V. (1997). Macroeconomic implications of money laundering: In E. U. Savona (Ed.), Responding to Money Laundering, International Perspective. Amsterdam: Harwood Academic Publishers (pp. 91–104).

  • Thoumi, F. (2003). The numbers' game, let's all guess the size of the illegal drugs industry! Crime and Globalization paper, Transnational Institute, Amsterdam.

  • Unger, B. (2007), International economics. In D. Masciandaro, E. Takats, & B. Unger (Eds.), Black finance. The economics of money laundering. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar (forth.).

  • Unger, B. (2009). Money laundering—A newly emerging topic on the international agenda. Review of Law and Economics, 807–819.

  • Unger, B., Ferwerda, J., de Kruijf, W., Rawlings, G., Siegel, M., & Wokke, K. (2006). The amounts and the effects of money laundering. Report for the Dutch Ministry of Finance.

  • Unger, B., & Rawlings, G. (2008). Competing for Criminal Money. Global Business and Economis Review, 10(3).

  • Unger, B., & Van Waarden, F. (2009). How to dodge drowing in data? Rule- and risk-based anti money laundering policies compared. Review of Law and Economics, 821–853.

  • United Nations. (2005). World drug report. Washington, DC: Office on Drugs and Crime, United Nations Publication.

  • United Nation. (2010). Manual on Victimization Surveys. United Nations Office on Drugs and Crime—United Nations Economic Commission for Europe.

  • Walker, J. (1999). How big is the global money laundering? Journal of Money Laundering Control, 3(1), 25–37.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Walker, J. (2007). The extent of money laundering in and through Australia in 2004, Criminology Research Council.

  • Walker, J., & Unger, B. (2009). Measuring global money laundering: “The Walker Gravity Model”. Review of Law and Economics, 821–853.

  • WODC. (2003). European sourcebook of crime and criminal justice statistics. United Nations Economic Commission for Europe.

Download references

Acknowledgments

The authors would like to thank Lucia Dalla Pellegrina, Donatella Porrini and Domenico Delle Side for useful comments and suggestions.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Donato Masciandaro.

Appendices

Appendix 1

In Sect. 2 we said that L(t) is a monotonic increasing function for both \( f < {\frac{1}{{1 + r_{l} }}} \) and \( r_{i} > {\frac{y}{1 - y}} \). This could be shown by taking the first derivative of L(t) and imposing that it should be greater than zero.

$$ \frac{dL}{dt} = {\frac{{f\left( {1 + r_{l} } \right)}}{{1 - f\left( {1 + r_{l} } \right)}}}yK_{0} \left( {1 - C} \right)\left( {1 - y} \right)^{t} \left( {1 + r_{i} } \right)^{t} \log \left[ {\left( {1 - y} \right)\left( {1 + r_{i} } \right)} \right] > 0. $$
(17)

Condition 17 could be satisfied also for both \( f > {\frac{1}{{1 + r_{l} }}} \) and \( r_{i} < {\frac{y}{1 - y}} \), but this eventuality is not reasonable because it will means that, given the actual values for the legal interest rate, f should be near to 100%, and this is incoherent with the economical data and with the common sense, because it will means that criminal will work without expending any money in consumption goods. According to these considerations we have that the range of variation of the share of money laundered reinvested in the legal market—i.e. f—has an upper extremum which is lower than 100%.

Let see now how the legal capital varies with the variation of the other parameters involved in our model.

For a fixed t we have:

$$ {{\frac{\partial L}{\partial f}} =\, }{\frac{{\left( {1 + r_{l} } \right)}}{{1 - f\left( {1 + r_{l} } \right)}}}yK_{0} \left( {1 - C} \right)\left[ {\left( {1 - y} \right)^{t} \left( {1 + r_{i} } \right)^{t} - 1} \right] $$
(18)

We know that this quantity will be always greater than zero thanks to the conditions quoted above; this means that L(t) will increase as f increases, precisely for \( f \to {\frac{1}{{1 + r_{l} }}} \);

$$ {{\frac{\partial L}{{\partial r_{l} }}} = }{\frac{f}{{\left[ {1 - f\left( {1 + r_{l} } \right)} \right]^{2} }}}yK_{0} \left( {1 - C} \right)\left[ {\left( {1 - y} \right)^{t} \left( {1 + r_{i} } \right)^{t} - 1} \right] $$
(19)

This function is always positive, so L(t) will increase as r l increases;

$$ {{\frac{\partial L}{{\partial r_{i} }}} =\, }{\frac{{f\left( {1 + r_{l} } \right)}}{{1 - f\left( {1 + r_{l} } \right)}}}yK_{0} \left( {1 - C} \right)\left[ {t\left( {1 - y} \right)^{t} \left( {1 + r_{i} } \right)^{t - 1} } \right] $$
(20)

The legal capital gets higher as r i increases but its growing become sensible only when> 1 because \( \left( { 1+ r_{i} } \right)^{t - 1} \) become a positive power of r i .

$$ \begin{aligned} {\frac{\partial L}{\partial y}} = & A\left[ {\left( {1 - y} \right)^{t} \left( {1 + r_{i} } \right)^{t} - 1} \right] - tyA\left[ {\left( {1 - y} \right)^{t - 1} \left( {1 + r_{i} } \right)^{t} } \right] = A\left\{ {\left[ {\left( {1 - y} \right)^{t} \left( {1 + r_{i} } \right)^{t} - ty\left( {1 - y} \right)^{t - 1} \left( {1 + r_{i} } \right)^{t} } \right] - 1} \right\} \\ = & A\left\{ {\left( {1 - y} \right)^{t - 1} \left( {1 + r_{i} } \right)^{t} \left( {1 - y - ty} \right) - 1} \right\} \\ \end{aligned} $$
(21)

where \( A = {\frac{{f\left( {1 + r_{l} } \right)}}{{1 - f\left( {1 + r_{l} } \right)}}}\,K_{0} \left( {1 - C} \right) \)

The legal capital decreases as the share of illegal money that needs to be laundered increases. The rationale for this is that gains coming principally from illegal traffics, therefore if the share of illegal capital that needs to be laundered increases, profits decrease.

$$ {{\frac{\partial L}{\partial \delta }} = WC_{1} \beta }. $$
(22)

where \( W = {\frac{{f\left( {1 + r_{l} } \right)}}{{1 - f\left( {1 + r_{l} } \right)}}}\,yK_{0} \left[ {\left( {1 - y} \right)^{t} \left( {1 + r_{i} } \right)^{t} - 1} \right]. \)

The legal capital increases as the anti money laundering regulation decreases.

Appendix 2

See Tables 3, 4 and 5 and Fig. 12.

Table 3 Regional distribution of world drugs retail sales (US$ mill)
Table 4 Share (y) of crimes proceeds that needs to be laundered
Table 5 Examples of money laundering technical costs (C 0 in US$)
Fig. 12
figure 12

Global illicit drug market at the retail prices by regions (US$bn). Source Own elaboration on basis of data from United Nations (2005), pp. 131–142

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Barone, R., Masciandaro, D. Organized crime, money laundering and legal economy: theory and simulations. Eur J Law Econ 32, 115–142 (2011). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10657-010-9203-x

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10657-010-9203-x

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation