Skip to main content
Log in

What price makes a good a status good? Results from a mating game

  • Published:
European Journal of Law and Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

This contribution provides a game theoretical derivation of market demand for status goods as a function of the level and distribution of income: if (1) the price is sufficiently low, everyone buys the good; if (2) the price is sufficiently high, only the rich buy the good (a status good in a narrow sense). If (3) the price is located in very high or in middle range, demand collapses. Thereby, we explain the critical price from which a status good acts as a distinctive signal. In addition, this approach shows the potential welfare-improving impact of conspicuous consumption.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Today, Veblen’s continuing popularity among students stems less from his model of social evolution, but rather from Harvey Leibenstein’s article Bandwagon, Snob, and Veblen Effects in the Theory of Consumers’ Demand. There, “for want of a better term” (Leibenstein 1950, 203), he named the case of a partly upward sloping demand function the Veblen Effect, which can be found in almost each microeconomic textbook.

  2. Corneo and Jeanne (1997) state that the prohibition of conspicuous consumption is always welfare-improving, whereas the welfare effects of taxation are ambiguous.

  3. In addition, in their welfare analysis the Frank (1985) and Ireland (1994) compare a world with status signaling and income as private information with a world in which the income rank of each individual is common knowledge. This comparison leads to the result that a world in which the income rank of each individual is common knowledge is welfare-superior, and so status signaling has to be seen as social waste. But: it is hardly surprising that conspicuous consumption as a signal makes no sense in a world of complete information which is definitely a part of Nirvana economics.

  4. The present paper is also related to the contributions of Corneo and Jeanne (1998) as well as Van Long and Shimomura (2004) who analyze the intertemporal consumption decision in the framework of life cycle models. Cooper et al. (2001), Corneo and Jeanne (2001) and Rauscher (1997) focus on the impact of conspicuous consumption on economic growth. Haucap (2001) as well as Jaramillo et al. (2001) analyze conspicuous consumption in clubs. Ferrer (2005) presents a signaling game in which education acts as a status signal. Krähmer (2006) focuses on the connection between advertising and conspicuous consumption.

  5. At a first view this assumption might be problematic. A second view disclosures that this assumption is straightforward. In the present mating game the only situation in which some individuals signal and some individuals do not is a separating equilibrium in a world with status signaling. This situation is characterised by individuals of type H who signal and individuals of type L who do not. So, if an individual does not signal in the separating equilibrium, the only conclusion can be that she is of type L. As a result, she has to expect that she will be seen by the others as being poor and with this be matched with an individual of type L for sure.

  6. For deeper insights in fashion cycles see Pesendorfer (1995).

  7. The set up that individuals purchase at most one unit of the status good is similar to the approach of Corneo and Jeanne (1997, 57). What differs to their seminal contribution as well to the approaches of Frank (1985, 103), Irland (1994, 93), and more recent Hopkins and Kornienko (2004, 1089) is that in our model neither status nor the consumption of the status good itself enters the utility function. From this perspective in our model conspicuous consumption is instrumental and without intrinsic motivation.

  8. The single crossing property is the condition for the possible emergence of separating equilibria in signaling games. It is also well known as sorting condition, constant sign condition or Spence-Mirrlees condition (Fudenberg and Tirole 1991, 259).

  9. In his seminal contribution Haucap (2001) presents a similar welfare analysis. What differs in our contribution is the strict focus on the price-dependency of different welfare outcomes.

References

  • Bagwell, L. S., & Bernheim, B. D. (1996). Veblen effects in a theory of conspicuous consumption. American Economic Review, 86, 349–373.

    Google Scholar 

  • Basmann, R. L., Molina, D. J., & Slottje, D. J. (1983). Budget constraint prices as preference changing parameters of generalized Fechner-Thurstone utility functions. American Economic Review, 73, 411–413.

    Google Scholar 

  • Basmann, R. L., Molina, D. J., & Slottje, D. J. (1987). Price-dependent preferences and the Fechner-Thurstone direct utility function: An exposition. Journal of Institutional and Theoretical Economics, 143, 568–594.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cole, H. L., Mailath, G. J., & Postlewaite, A. (1995). Incorporating concern for relative wealth into economic models. Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis Quarterly Review, 19, 12–21.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cooper, B., García-Peñalosa, C., & Funk, P. (2001). Status effects and negative utility growth. Economic Journal, 111, 642–665.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Corneo, G., & Jeanne, O. (1997). Conspicuous consumption, Snobbism and conformism. Journal of Public Economics, 66, 55–71.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Corneo, G., & Jeanne, O. (1998). Social organization, status, and saving behavior. Journal of Public Economics, 70, 37–51.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Corneo, G., & Jeanne, O. (2001). Status, the distribution of wealth, and growth. Scandinavian Journal of Economics, 103, 283–293.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Creedy, J., & Slottje, D. J. (1991). Conspicuous consumption in Australia. Research Paper Number 307, University of Melbourne.

  • Ferrer, A. M. (2005). Signaling, inequality and the social structure. Economica, 73, 515–529.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Frank, R. H. (1985). The demand for unobservable and other nonpositional goods. American Economic Review, 75, 101–116.

    Google Scholar 

  • Fudenberg, D., & Tirole, J. (1991). Game theory. Cambridge: MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Galbraith, J. K. (1958). The affluent society. Cambridge: The Riverside Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Haucap, J. (2001). Konsum und soziale Beziehungen. Jahrbuch für Wirtschaftswissenschaften, 52, 243–263.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hirsch, F. (1976). Social limits to growth. Cambridge: Havard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hopkins, E., & Kornienko, T. (2004). Running to keep in the same place: Consumer choice as a game of status. American Economic Review, 94, 1085–1107.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ireland, N. J. (1994). On limiting the market for status signals. Journal of Public Economics, 53, 111–126.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jaramillo, F., Kempf, H., & Moizeau, F. (2001). Conspicous consumption, social status and clubs. Annales d’Économie et de Statistique, issue, 63–64, 321–344.

    Google Scholar 

  • Krähmer, D. (2006). Advertising and conspicuous consumption. Journal of Institutional and Theoretical Economics, 162, 661–682.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Leibenstein, H. (1950). Bandwagon, Snob, and Veblen effects in the theory of consumers’ demand. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 64, 183–207.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mandeville, B. (1924/1714). The fable of the bees: Or, private vices, public benefits. Oxford: Clarendon Press.

  • Pesendorfer, W. (1995). Design innovation and fashion cycles. American Economic Review, 85, 771–792.

    Google Scholar 

  • Phillips, R. J., & Slottje, D. J. (1983). The importance of relative prices in analyzing Veblen effects. Journal of Economic Issues, 17, 197–206.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rae, J. (1965/1834). Statement of some new principles on the subject of political economy, exposing the fallacies of the system of free trade, and of some other doctrines maintained in “The Wealth of Nation”. In R. Warren James (Ed.), John Rae: Political economist. An account of his life and a compilation of his main writings, Vol. 2. Toronto: University of Toronto Press.

  • Rauscher, M. (1997). Conspicuous consumption, economic growth, and taxation. Journal of Economics, 66, 35–42.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Scitovsky, T. (1992/1976). The joyless economy—The psychology of human satisfaction. New York: Oxford University Press.

  • Smith, A. (1910/1776). The wealth of nations. London: J.M. Dent & Sons.

  • Sombart, W. (1913). Luxus und Kapitalismus. München and Leipzig: Duncker & Humblot.

    Google Scholar 

  • Van Long, N., & Shimomura, K. (2004). Relative wealth, status-seeking, and catching-up. Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, 53, 529–542.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Veblen, T. B. (1899/1953). The theory of the Leisure Class—An economic study of institutions, reprint. New York: The New American Library of World Literature.

Download references

Acknowledgments

The author would like to express his gratitude to the participants of the Annual Congress of the Verein für Socialpolitik (German Economic Association) in Graz, Austria, and of the 64th Congress of the International Institute of Public Finance in Maastricht, Netherlands, as well as to an anonymous referee for fruitful comments and helpful discussion.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Tobias Thomas.

Appendix

Appendix

Note, that all parameter w H ,   w L ,   q H ,   α > 0.

  1. (a)

    The upper limit of the pooling case is given by

    $$ p_{S}=w_{L}-\root{\alpha}\of{{w_{L}^{\alpha}+q_{H}\left(w_{L}^{\alpha}- \left(\frac{ w_{L}+w_{H}}{2}\right)^{\alpha}\right)}}. $$

    Note, that in the pooling equilibrium the budget condition \(\alpha<\ln \left(\frac{1-q_{H}}{q_{H}}\right)/\ln\left(\frac{w_{H}+w_{L}} {2w_{L}}\right)\) holds, so that \(w_{L}^{\alpha}+q_{H}\left(w_{L}^{\alpha}-\left(\frac{w_{L}+w_{H}} {2}\right)^{\alpha}\right)>0\).

    The first order derivatives of p S with respect to w H , w L , q H and α are given as follows:

    $$ \begin{aligned} \frac{\partial p_{S}}{\partial w_{H}}&=\frac{1} {2}q_{H}\left(\frac{w_{L}+w_{H}}{2}\right)^{\alpha-1}\\ &\quad\times\left(w_{L}^{\alpha}+q_{H}\left(w_{L}^{\alpha}-\left(\frac{w_{L}+w_{H}} {2}\right)^{\alpha}\right)\right)^{\left(\frac{1}{\alpha}-1\right)}>0 \end{aligned} $$
    (25)
    $$ \begin{aligned} \frac{\partial p_{S}}{\partial w_{L}}& =1-\left(w_{L}^{\alpha-1}+q_{H} \left(w_{L}^{\alpha-1}-\frac{1}{2}\left(\frac{w_{L}+w_{H}} {2}\right)^{\alpha-1}\right)\right)\\ &\quad\times\left(w_{L}^{\alpha}+q_{H}\left(w_{L}^{\alpha}-\left(\frac{w_{L}+w_{H}} {2}\right)^{\alpha}\right)\right)^{\left(\frac{1}{\alpha}-1\right)}\lessgtr 0 \end{aligned} $$
    (26)

    If w L is low, \(\frac{\partial p_{S}}{\partial w_{L}}>0\) holds. If w L is high, \(\frac{\partial p_{S}}{\partial w_{L}}<0\) holds. One can construct parametric constellations for each case.

    $$ \begin{aligned} \frac{\partial p_{S}}{\partial q_{H}}&=\frac{1} {a}\left(\left(\frac{w_{L}+w_{H}}{2}\right)^{\alpha}-w_{L}^{\alpha}\right)\\ &\quad \times\left(w_{L}^{\alpha}+q_{H}\left(w_{L}^{\alpha} -\left(\frac{w_{L}+w_{H}} {2}\right)^{\alpha}\right)\right)^{\left(\frac{1}{\alpha}-1\right)}>0\\ \end{aligned} $$
    (27)
    $$ \begin{aligned} \frac{\partial p_{S}}{\partial\alpha}& =\left(\frac{(w_{L}^{\alpha}+q_{H} (w_{L}^{\alpha}-\left(\frac{w_{L}+w_{H}} {2}\right)^{\alpha}))\ln(w_{L}^{\alpha} +q_{H}(w_{L}^{\alpha}-\left(\frac{w_{L}+w_{H}}{2}\right)^{\alpha})}{\alpha^{2} \left(w_{L}^{\alpha}+q_{H}\left(w_{L}^{\alpha}-\left(\frac{w_{L}+w_{H}} {2}\right)^{\alpha}\right)\right)}\right.\\ &\quad\left.+\frac{\alpha\left(\left(q_{H}\left(\frac{w_{L}+w_{H}} {2}\right)^{\alpha}\ln\left(\frac{w_{L}+w_{H}} {2}\right)\right)-(1+q)w_{L}^{\alpha}\ln(w_{L})\right)} {\alpha^{2}(w_{L}^{\alpha}+q_{H} \left(w_{L}^{\alpha}-\left(\frac{w_{L}+w_{H}}{2})^{\alpha}\right)\right)}\right)\\ &\quad \times\left(w_{L}^{\alpha}+q_{H}\left(w_{L}^{\alpha}-\left(\frac{w_{L}+w_{H}} {2}\right)^{\alpha}\right)\right)^{\frac{1}{\alpha}}>0 \end{aligned} $$
    (28)
  2. (b)

    The lower limit of the separating case is given by

    $$ p_{S}=w_{L}-\root{\alpha}\of{{2w_{L}^{\alpha}-\left(\frac{w_{L}+w_{H}} {2}\right)^{\alpha}}}. $$

    Note, that in the separating equilibrium the budget condition \(\alpha<\ln(2)/\ln\left(\frac{w_{H}+w_{L}}{2w_{L}}\right)\) holds, so that \(2w_{L}^{\alpha}-\left(\frac{w_{L}+w_{H}}{2}\right)^{\alpha}>0\).

    The first order derivatives of p S with respect to w H , w L , q H and α are given as follows:

    $$ \begin{aligned} \frac{\partial p_{S}}{\partial w_{H}}&=\frac{1} {2}\left(\frac{w_{L}+w_{H}}{2}\right)^{(\alpha-1)}\\ &\quad \times\left(2w_{L}^{\alpha}-\left(\frac{w_{L}+w_{H}} {2}\right)^{\alpha}\right)^{\left(\frac{1}{\alpha}-1\right)}>0 \end{aligned} $$
    (29)
    $$ \begin{aligned} \frac{\partial p_{S}}{\partial w_{L}}&=1-\left(2w_{L}^{(\alpha-1)}- \frac{1}{2}\left(\frac{w_{L}+w_{H}}{2}\right)^{(\alpha-1)}\right)\\ &\quad \times\left(2w_{L}^{\alpha}-\left(\frac{w_{L}+w_{H}} {2}\right)^{\alpha}\right)^{\left(\frac{1}{\alpha}-1\right)}\lessgtr 0 \end{aligned} $$
    (30)

    If w L is low, \(\frac{\partial p_{S}}{\partial w_{L}}>0\) holds. If w L is high, \(\frac{\partial p_{S}}{\partial w_{L}}<0\) holds. One can construct parametric constellations for each case.

    $$ \frac{\partial p_{S}}{\partial q_{H}}=0 $$
    (31)
    $$ \begin{aligned} \frac{\partial p_{S}}{\partial\alpha}&=\left(\frac{(2w_{L}^{\alpha} -\left(\frac{w_{L}+w_{H}}{2}\right)^{\alpha})\ln\left(2w_{L}^{\alpha}-\left(\frac{w_{L}+w_{H}}{2}\right)^{\alpha}\right)}{\alpha^{2}\left(2w_{L}^{\alpha}-\left(\frac{w_{L}+w_{H}}{2}\right)^{\alpha}\right)}\right.\\&\quad\left. +\frac{\alpha\left(\left(\frac{w_{L}+w_{H}}{2}\right)^{\alpha}\ln\left(\frac{w_{L}+w_{H}}{2}\right)-2w_{L}^{\alpha}\ln(w_{L})\right)}{a^{2}(2w_{L}^{\alpha}-\left(\frac{w_{L}+w_{H}}{2}\right)^{\alpha})}\right)\\&\quad \times\left(2w_{L}^{\alpha}-\left(\frac{w_{L}+w_{H}}{2}\right)^{\alpha}\right)^{\left(\frac{1}{\alpha}\right)}>0\end{aligned} $$
    (32)
  3. (c)

    If \(c_{A}\geq w_{H}^{\alpha}-\left(\frac{w_{H}+w_{L}} {2}\right)^{\alpha}\) holds, the upper limit of the separating case is given by

    $$ p_{S}=\left(\frac{w_{H}-w_{L}}{2}\right) $$

    The first order derivatives of p S with respect to w H , w L , q H and α are given as follows:

    $$ \frac{\partial p_{S}}{\partial w_{H}}=\underset{}{\frac{1}{2}}>0,\,\frac{\partial p_{S}} {\partial w_{L}}=\underset{}{-\frac{1}{2}}<0,\,\frac{\partial p_{S}} {\partial q_{H}}=0\hbox{ and }\frac{\partial p_{S}}{\partial\alpha}=0 $$
    (33-36)

    If \(c_{A}<w_{H}^{\alpha}-\left(\frac{w_{H}+w_{L}}{2}\right)^{\alpha}\) holds, the upper limit of the separating case is given by

    $$ p_{S}=w_{H}-\root{\alpha}\of{{w_{H}-c_{A}}}. $$

    Note that w H  > c A holds.

The first order derivatives of p S with respect to w H , w L , q H and α are given as follows:

$$ \frac{\partial p_{S}}{\partial w_{H}}=1-\frac{\root{\alpha}\of{{w_{H}-c_{A}}} }{{\alpha\cdot(w_{H}-c_{A})}}<0 $$
(37)
$$ \frac{\partial p_{S}}{\partial w_{L}}=0,\quad \frac{\partial p_{S}}{\partial q_{H}}=0 $$
(38–39)
$$ \frac{\partial p_{S}}{\partial\alpha}=\frac{\root{\alpha}\of{{w_{H}-c_{A}} \ln(h-c)}}{\alpha}>0 $$
(40)
$$ \frac{\partial p_{S}}{\partial c_{A}}=\frac{\root{\alpha}\of{{w_{H}-c_{A}}}} {\alpha\cdot(w_{H}-c_{A})}>0 $$
(41)

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Thomas, T. What price makes a good a status good? Results from a mating game. Eur J Law Econ 36, 35–55 (2013). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10657-011-9273-4

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10657-011-9273-4

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation