Skip to main content
Log in

The border effects in Spain: an industry-level analysis

  • Original Paper
  • Published:
Empirica Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

A gravity-model approach is used to estimate the magnitude of the internal border (home bias) and external border (frontier) effects in Spain using industry-level trade flows. We find that the average border effects are about 30 and 10, respectively. Next we explore the variation in the industry-specific border effects. First, the border effects are larger in highly product differentiated industries. Second, the internal border effect is twice bigger for trade in intermediate goods than for trade in final goods. Third, conditioning on the geographic concentration of firms reduces significantly the internal border effect.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. The external border effect or frontier effect has been studied by McCallum (1995), Helliwell (1996, 1998), Anderson and Smith (1999), Anderson and van Wincoop (2003), Okubo (2004), Gil et al. (2005).

  2. Wei (1996), Head and Mayer (2000), Nitsch (2000), Evans (2003) and Chen (2004). These papers all calculated domestic trade as gross output minus exports, a “rough” estimate of intra-national trade flows.

  3. Helliwell (1996), Wolf (2000), Hillberry and Hummels (2003), Millimet and Osang (2007) and Combes et al. (2005) find an internal border effect between 2 and 6 in Canada, USA and France. Djankov and Freund (2000), Poncet (2003) and Daumal and Zignago (2008) find an internal border effect between 11 and 20 in ex-former USSR, China and Brazil.

  4. Evans (2003), Hillberry (2002) and Chen (2004) also use industry value added as a measure of exporter´s economic size rather than origin-region GDP to control for industry location patterns.

  5. The OECD countries included in the study are: Australia (AUS), Austria (AUT), Belgium (BEL, Belgium and Luxemburg), Canada (CAN), Czech Republic (CZE), Denmark (DNK), Finland (FIN), France (FRA), Germany (DEU), Greece (GRC), Hungary (HUN), Iceland (ISL), Ireland (IRL), Italy (ITA), Japan (JPN), Korea (KOR), Mexico (MEX), Netherlands (NDL), New Zealand (NZL), Norway (NOR), Poland (POL), Portugal (PRT), Slovenia (SVK), Sweden (SWE), Switzerland (SWT), United Kingdom (UK), United States (USA).

  6. Llano (2004b) describes in detail the harmonization method, the estimation of non-available data, the debugging procedure for transport flows in physical units and the estimation of value/weight relations from international trade statistics.

  7. The great circle distance between i’s and j’s cities is calculated as follows. First we transform the latitude φ j and the longitude λ into radians (xπ/360). Second, the formula used to calculate the distance between the pair of cities is \( \Updelta_{ij} \equiv \lambda_{j} - \lambda_{i} , \) \( d_{ij} = \arccos \left[ {\sin \varphi_{i} \sin \varphi_{j} + \cos \varphi_{i} \cos \varphi_{j} \cos \Updelta_{ij} } \right]z, \) with z = 6,367 for km. Third, we calculate the population-weighted average distance between the cities by region and by country using the same formula \( D_{{r,r^{\prime}}} = \sum_{i \in r} w_{i} (\sum_{{i \in r^{\prime}}} w_{j} d_{ij} ),\,w_{i} = pop_{i} /pop_{r} \).

  8. Head and Mayer (2002) and Chen (2004) use the same approach in their analysis of the home country bias in Europe using industry-levels trade flows.

  9. Following Chen (2004), ehe weight-to-value measure is industry-specific and averaged across all region-country pairs, \( \sum_{i} \sum_{j} Q_{ij,k} /\sum_{i} \sum_{j} X_{ij,k} \) where Q ij,k is the weight of bilateral international exports X ij,k .

  10. Of course, it is delicate to compare results of the diverse studies because they use different methods and data. Therefore, we have to remain cautious concerning these comparisons.

  11. When we used aggregated trade flows and replicated the specification of Gil et al. (2005) using manufacturing sectors only, the magnitude of the external border effect was 15, a greater value than the one obtained using industry-specific trade flows.

  12. The importance in absolute terms of the energy industry (electricity, gas and water) within the country, together with the domestic nature of the Spanish distribution system, tends to magnify the external border effect (it is the largest one) and diminish the internal border effect (it is among the smallest ones), compared to any estimation that omits this important sector.

  13. A specific industry in a region could account for long international inflows and low levels of inter-regional outflows. In some cases, this trade structure could fit with the typical one-way-trade predicted by the Ricardian or the Heckscher-Ohlin-Vanek model. However, it could be just a consequence of intra-firm imports of products that would be distributed nationally through the internal network of the company.

  14. Regarding this point, it has been argued that small and weakly internationalised companies in Spain are fond of promoting international trade just when the national demand is weak, and vice versa.

  15. Chen (2004) defines the first group of factors as “behavioural responses to trade costs” and the second group as “trade costs”.

  16. Evans (2003) and Chen (2004) use the same approach.

  17. For a discussion, see Deardorff (1998)), Anderson and Van Wincoop (2003) and Feenstra (2002).

  18. The three measures are constructed using Spain as a geographic unit. IIT was constructed using international import and export (value and quantity) flows. R&D was obtained from Estadística de I + D (INE) and ADV was obtained from Encuesta Industrial de Empresas (INE). For the variable ADV the agriculture sector is excluded due to lack of information.

  19. We set the two endpoints of the elasticity range (2–6) to the minimum and maximum IIT index values (0.03 and 0.66), and used linear interpolation to assign elasticities to the intervening industries, based on their ITT index values (as in Evans 2003).

  20. Notice that the use of information on geographic concentration for 1999 and trade flows for 2000 alleviates the problem of endogeneity between the geographic location of firms and trade flows.

References

  • Alonso O, Chamorro JM, Gonzalez X (2003) Spillovers geográficos y sectoriales de la industria. Revista de Economía Aplicada 32:77–95

    Google Scholar 

  • Amiti M (2001) Regional specialisation and technological leapfrogging. J Reg Sci 41(1):149–172

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Amiti M (2005) Location of vertically linked industries: agglomeration versus comparative advantage. Eur Econ Rev 49:809–832

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Anderson MA, Smith SLS (1999) Canadian provinces in world trade: engagement and detachment. Can J Econ 32(1):23–37

    Google Scholar 

  • Anderson JE, van Wincoop E (2003) Gravity with gravitas: a solution to the border puzzle. Am Econ Rev 93(1):170–192

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chen N (2004) Intra-national versus international trade in the European Union: why do national borders matter? J Int Econ 63(1):93–118

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Combes PP, Lafourcade M, Mayer T (2005) The trade-creating effect of business and social networks: evidence from France. J Int Econ 66:1–29

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Daumal M, Zignago S (2008) Border effects of Brazilian states. Working Papers 2008-11, CEPII Research Center

  • Davis DR, Weinstein DE (1999) Economic geography and regional production structure: an empirical investigation. Eur Econ Rev 43:379–407

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Deardorff AV (1998) Determinants of bilateral trade: does gravity work in a neoclassic world? In: Frankel JA (ed) The regionalization of the world economy. University of Chicago Press, Chicago

    Google Scholar 

  • Djankov S, Freund C (2000) Disintegration and trade flows: evidence from the Former Soviet Union. Policy Research Working Paper Series 2378. The World Bank

  • Ellison G, Glaeser E (1997) Geographic concentration in US manufacturing industry: a dartboard approach. J Polit Econ 105(5):889–927

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Evans CL (2003) The economic significance of national border effects. Am Econ Rev 93(4):1291–1312

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Feenstra R (2002) Border effect and the gravity equation: consistent methods for estimation. Scott J Polit Econ 49(5):1021–1035

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Forslid R, Haland K, Midlefart Knarvik K (2002) A U-shape Europe? A simulation study of industrial location. J Int Econ 57(2):273–297

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fujita M, Krugman P, Venables AJ (1999) The spatial economy. The MIT Press, Cambridge, MA

    Google Scholar 

  • Gil S, Llorca R, Martínez JA, Oliver J (2005) The border effect in Spain. World Econ 28:1617–1631

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Head K, Mayer T (2000) Non-Europe: the magnitude and causes of market fragmentation in the EU. Weltwirtschaftliches Archiv 136(2):284–314

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Head K, Mayer T (2002) Illusory border effects: distance mismeasurement inflates estimates of home bias in trade. CEPII working paper no 2002-01

  • Helliwell JF (1996) Do national borders matter for Quebec’s trade? Can J Econ 29(3):507–522

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Helliwell JF (1998) How much do national borders matter?. Brookings Institution Press, Washington, DC

    Google Scholar 

  • Helliwell JF, Verdier G (2001) Measuring internal trade distances: a new method applied to estimate provincial border effects in Canada. Can J Econ 35(3):517–530

    Google Scholar 

  • Hillberry RH (2002) Aggregation bias compositional change, and the border effect. Can J Econ 35(3):517–530

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hillberry RH, Hummels D (2003) Intranational home bias: some explanations. Rev Econ Stat 85(4):1089–1092

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hillberry RH, Hummels D (2008) Trade responses to geographic frictions: a decomposition using micro-data. Eur Econ Rev 52(3):527–550

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Llano C (2004a) Economía sectorial y espacial: el comercio interregional en el marco input-output. Instituto de Estudios Fiscales. Colección Investigaciones, No.1, 2004

  • Llano C (2004b) The interregional trade in the context of a multirregional input–output model for Spain. Estudios de Economía Aplicada 22(3):1–34

    Google Scholar 

  • Llano C, Esteban A, Pulido A, Pérez J (2008) La base de datos C-intereg sobre el comercio interregional de bienes en España (1995–2006): metodología. Documento de trabajo. Instituto L. Klein. Centro Stone. Septiembre 2008. www.c-intereg.es

  • McCallum J (1995) National borders matter: Canadian–US regional trade patterns. Am Econ Rev 85(3):615–623

    Google Scholar 

  • McDonald JF, Moffit RA (1980) The uses of Tobit analysis. Rev Econ Stat 62(2):318–321

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Millimet D, Osang Th (2007) Do state borders matter for U.S. intranational trade? The role of history and internal migration. Can J Econ 40(1):93–126

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nitsch V (2000) National borders and international trade: evidence from the European Union. Can J Econ 33(4):1091–1105

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nitsch V (2002) Border effects and border regions: lessons from the German unification. mimeo, Banakgesellschaft, Berlin

  • Okubo T (2004) The border effect in the Japanese market: a gravity model analysis. Jpn Int Econ 18:1–11

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pérez J, Llano C, García G (2009) Valoración de las tablas input-output interregionales de la economía española. Revista del ICE 848:37–65

    Google Scholar 

  • Poncet S (2003) Measuring Chinese domestic and international integration. China Econ Rev 14(1):1–21

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Puga D (1999) The rise and fall of regional inequalities. Eur Econ Rev 43(2):303–334

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wei S (1996) Intra-national versus international trade: how stubborn are nations in global integration? NBER working paper 5531

  • Wolf HC (2000) Intra-national home bias in trade. Rev Econ Stat 82(4):555–563

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgments

F. Requena acknowledges financial support from the Spanish Ministry of Science and Innovation (project number ECO 2008-04059/ECON) and Generalitat Valenciana, project Prometeo/2009/098. C. Llano acknowledges financial support from the Education Department of the Regional Government of Madrid (project TransporTrade S2007/HUM/497).

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Francisco Requena.

Appendix

Appendix

See Table 6.

Table 6 Descriptive statistics

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Requena, F., Llano, C. The border effects in Spain: an industry-level analysis. Empirica 37, 455–476 (2010). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10663-010-9123-6

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10663-010-9123-6

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation