Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

The Economic Contribution of High-Growth Firms: Do Policy Implications Depend on the Choice of Growth Indicator?

  • Published:
Journal of Industry, Competition and Trade Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Prior studies have defined high-growth firms (HGFs) in terms of growth in firm employment or firm sales, and primarily analyzed their contribution to overall employment growth. In this paper we define HGFs using the commonly applied growth indicators (employment and sales), but also add definitions based on growth in value added and productivity. Our results indicate that HGFs in terms of employment are not the same firms as HGFs in terms of productivity, and that their economic contributions differ significantly. Economic policy promoting fast growth in employment may therefore come at the cost of reduced productivity growth. Although HGFs of different definitions may not be the same firms, young firms are more likely to be HGFs irrespective of definition. This suggests that economic policy should focus on the conditions for new firm formation and early growth of firms, rather than target a particular type of HGFs.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Recently, endogenous growth theory has emerged arguing that new knowledge drives economic growth (Romer 1986). This literature was preceded by Hayek who early on forcefully emphasized the role of knowledge (e.g. 1937, 1945, 1984).

  2. Audretsch and Fritsch (2002) and Fritsch and Mueller (2006) have extended the use of the regimes concept to geographical units, notably regions, the idea being that the mode of production in a certain region may be distinct from the dominant modes of production in other regions.

  3. The measures of ambitious entrepreneurship, provided by the Global Entrepreneurship Monitor, echo this. Stam et al. (2008) find that ambitious entrepreneurship contributes more strongly to country-scale economic growth than entrepreneurship in general. According to Wong et al. (2005), high-growth potential Total Entrepreneurial Activity (TEA) is the sole form of entrepreneurship that has any explanatory effect on differing rates of economic growth across nations. Based on this and similar studies, Sternberg and Wennekers (2005, p.200) conclude: “These findings may have important implications for entrepreneurship policy in highly developed economies. At least from an economic growth perspective, policy should focus primarily on potentially fast-growing new firms and not on new enterprises in general.”

  4. Organic growth is growth through new appointments in a firm, while acquired growth is growth through acquisitions and/or mergers. Organic growth and acquired growth may also be denoted internal growth and external growth, respectively. McKelvie and Wiklund (2010) also suggest that different hybrids of organic and acquired growth should be considered.

  5. Stam et al. (2011) investigate whether the rate of HGFs has an effect on subsequent macroeconomic performance in a sample of low- and high-income countries during the period 2002–2005. Teruel and de Wit (2011) analyze the determinants of HGFs in different countries. As they do not concern themselves directly with the contribution of HGFs, we do not include their studies in our overview.

  6. López-Garcia and Puente (2012) use growth in value added to identify HGFs. However, this is only as a test of robustness of their regression model with HGFs defined by growth in employment. As their study does not consider the contribution of HGFs defined by value added, we do not include their use of value added as a growth indicator in our survey of the previous literature.

  7. Although they do not directly focus on HGFs, this is supported by Coad and Broekel (2012). Their results indicate that the relationship between employment and productivity growth is dependent on where the firm is located at the firm growth rate distribution. An increase in productivity growth seems to be associated with a decrease in employment growth for most firms, while it stimulates further employment growth for fast growing firms.

  8. The report investigates the growth dynamics of firms in 11 countries for the period 2002 to 2005. It covers the non-agricultural business sector, ISIC Rev3 Sectors 10–74. In general, firms with ten or more employees are analyzed.

  9. Shepherd and Wiklund (2009) investigate correlations between firm growth measured over one- and three-year time spans, finding them to be rather high in the case of employment and sales growth. They see average correlations of 0.582 for absolute employment growth measured over these two time spans, and 0.580 for absolute sales growth, while correlations for relative employment growth were 0.556 and for relative sales growth 0.678.

  10. We also identified HGFs as the firms with the 3 % highest growth rates during the studied periods in order to test whether our results are sensitive to the chosen cut-off level. All results remain qualitatively similar, and are available from the authors upon request.

  11. A descriptive analysis also shows that HGFs are significantly larger and older when the Eurostat-OECD definition of HGFs is used (see Table A1 in the Appendix).

  12. Absolute employment HGFs are defined measuring the growth in employment in absolute numbers; relative employment HGFs are defined measuring the growth in employment in relative numbers; composite employment HGFs are defined measuring the growth in employment using a combination of relative and absolute numbers; absolute sales HGFs are defined measuring the growth in sales in absolute numbers; relative sales HGFs are defined measuring the growth in sales in relative numbers; absolute value added HGFs are defined measuring the growth in value added in absolute numbers; relative value added HGFs are defined measuring the growth in value added in relative numbers; absolute productivity HGFs are defined measuring the growth in labor productivity in absolute numbers; relative productivity HGFs are defined measuring the growth in labor productivity in relative numbers.

  13. How the Eurostat-OECD definition and the choice of growth cut-offs influence the average size and age of different types of HGFs are presented in Table 13 in the appendix.

  14. Firm size is lagged two periods to avoid endogeneity problems.

  15. All the firms in the database are denoted by five-digit SNI codes. Based on these, the firms have been sorted using three-digit SNI codes into 213 different industries to control for industry-specific heterogeneity in the presence of HGFs. The estimated coefficients for each of these industry dummies are not presented in this paper in order to save space, but are available from the authors upon request.

  16. Note that the variables D72 and DGROUP are not presented in Table 7 in order to save space, but are available from the authors upon request. The enterprise group dummy is always positive and significant (in line with previous research), except in the regressions where HGFs based on productivity function as a basis for the dependent variable, where it is insignificant. The dummy for being registered as a startup in 1972 is only occasionally significant.

  17. All estimations were also done with a 3 % cut-off point to test the robustness of our results. The results are qualitatively very similar to the results we obtain when we use the 1 % cut-off point, and they are available from the authors upon request.

References

  • Acs ZJ, Audretsch DB (2005) Entrepreneurship, innovation and technological change. Found Trends Entrep 1(4):1–49

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Acs ZJ, Mueller P (2008) Employment effects of business dynamics: mice, gazelles and elephants. Small Bus Econ 30(1):85–100

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Acs ZJ, Parsons W, Tracy S (2008) High impact firms: gazelles revisited. Office of Advocacy Working Paper, the United States Small Business Administration

  • Aiginger K (2006) Competitiveness: from a dangerous obsession to a welfare creating ability with positive externalities. J Ind Comp Trade 6(2):161–177

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Aiginger K (2007) Industrial policy: a dying breed or a re-emerging phoenix. J Ind Comp Trade 7(3–4):297–323

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Alchian AA (1950) Uncertainty, evolution and economic theory. J Polit Econ 58:211–222

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Anyadike-Danes M, Bonner K, Hart M, Mason C (2009) Measuring business growth—High-growth firms and their contribution to employment in the UK. Belfast: ERINI, Economic Research Institute of Northern Ireland, Monograph 44

  • Audretsch DB (1995) Innovation and industry evolution. MIT Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Audretsch DB, Fritsch M (2002) Growth regimes over time and space. Reg Stud 36(2):113–124

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Audretsch DB, Thurik AR (2000) Capitalism and democracy in the 21st Century: from the managed to the entrepreneurial economy. J Evol Econ 10(1):17–34

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Autio E, Arenius P, Wallenius H (2000) Economic impact of gazelle firms in Finland. Helsinki University of Technology, Institute of Strategy and International Business Working Paper Series 2000:3

  • Bartelsman EJ, Doms M (2000) Understanding productivity: lessons from longitudinal microdata. J Econ Lit 38(3):569–594

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bartelsman EJ, Haltiwanger J, Scarpetta S (2004) Microeconomic evidence of creative destruction in industrial and developing countries. The World Bank, Policy Research Working Paper Series 3464

  • Bartelsman EJ, Haltiwanger J, Scarpetta S (2013) Cross-country difference in productivity: the role of allocation and selection. Am Econ Rev 103(1):305–334

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Baumol WJ (1990) Entrepreneurship: productive, unproductive and destructive. J Polit Econ 98(5):893–921

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Baumol WJ (2004) Entrepreneurial enterprises, large established firms and other components of the free-market growth machine. Small Bus Econ 23(1):9–21

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Birch DL (1979) The job generation process. MIT Program on Neighborhood and Regional Change, Massachusetts Institute of Technology, Cambridge, MA

  • Birch DL (2006) What have we learned? Found Trends Entrep 2(3):197–202

    Google Scholar 

  • Birch DL, Medoff JL (1994) Gazelles. In: Solmon LC, Levenson AR (eds) Labor markets, employment policy, and job creation. Westview Press, Boulder, pp 159–167

    Google Scholar 

  • Birch DL, Haggerty A, Parsons W (1995) Who’s creating jobs? Cognetics Inc, Boston

    Google Scholar 

  • Bjuggren CM, Daunfeldt SO, Johansson D (2013) High-growth firms and family ownership. J Small Bus Entrep 26(4):365–385

    Google Scholar 

  • Bornhäll A, Daunfeldt SO, Rudholm N (2013) Sleeping gazelles: High profits but no growth. HUI Research Working Papers 91

  • Bottazzi G, Secchi A (2003) Why are distributions of firm growth rates tent-shaped? Econ Lett 80(3):415–420

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bottazzi G, Dosi G, Lippi M, Pammolli F, Riccaboni M (2001) Innovation and corporate growth in the evolution of the drug industry. Int J of Ind Organ 19(7):1161–1187

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bravo-Biosca A (2010) Growth dynamics: Exploring business growth and contraction in Europe and the US. NESTA Research report: November, London, UK

  • Brüderl J, Preisendörfer P (2000) Fast-growing businesses: empirical evidence from a German study. Int J Soc 30(3):45–70

    Google Scholar 

  • Caballero R (2007) Specificity and the macroeconomics of restructuring. MIT Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Capasso M, Cefis E, Frenken K (2009) Do some firms persistently outperform? Utrecht University Discussion Paper Series 09-28

  • Caves R (1998) Industrial organization and new findings on the turnover and mobility of firms. J Econ Lit 36(4):1947–1982

    Google Scholar 

  • Coad A (2010) The exponential age distribution and the Pareto firm size distribution. J Ind Compet Trade 10(3–4):389–395

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Coad A, Broekel T (2012) Firm growth and productivity growth: evidence from a panel VAR. Appl Econ 44(10):1251–1269

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Coad A, Hölzl W (2009) On the autocorrelation of growth rates. J Ind Compet Trade 9(2):139–166

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Coad A, Hölzl W (2010) Firm growth: empirical analysis. WIFO Working Papers No. 361, Vienna

  • Coad A, Daunfeldt SO, Johansson D, Wennberg K (2013) Who do high-growth firms hire? Ind Corp Change (forthcoming)

  • Daunfeldt SO, Halvarsson D (2012) Are high-growth firms one-hit wonders? Evidence from Sweden. HUI Research Working Papers 73

  • Daunfeldt SO, Halvarsson D, Johansson D (2012) A cautionary note on using the Eurostat-OECD definition of high-growth firms. HUI Research Working Papers 65

  • Davidsson P (1991) Continued entrepreneurship: ability, need, and opportunity as determinants of small firm growth. J Bus Vent 6(6):405–429

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Davidsson P, Delmar F (2003) Hunting for new employment: The role of high growth firms. In: Kirby DA, Watson A (eds) Small firms and economic development in developed and transition economies - a reader. Ashgate Publishing, Hampshire, pp 7–19

    Google Scholar 

  • Davidsson P, Delmar F (2006) High-growth firms and their contribution to employment: The case of Sweden. In: Davidsson P, Delmar F, Wiklund J (eds) Entrepreneurship and the growth of firms. Edward Elgar, Cheltenham, pp 156–178

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Davidsson P, Achtenhagen L, Naldi L (2010) Small firm growth. Found Trends Entrep 6(2):69–166

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Delmar F (1997) Measuring growth: Methodological considerations and empirical results. In: Donckels R, Miettinen A (eds) Entrepreneurship and SME research: On its way to the next millennium. Ashgate, Aldershot, pp 199–216

    Google Scholar 

  • Delmar F, Davidsson P (1998) A taxonomy of high-growth firms. In: Reynolds PD, Bygrave WD, Carter NM, Manigart S, Mason CM, Meyers D, Shaver KG (eds) Frontiers of entrepreneurship research: Proceedings of the 18th Annual Entrepreneurship Research Conference. Babson College Wellesley, MA, pp 399–413

  • Delmar F, Davidsson P, Gartner WB (2003) Arriving at the high-growth firm. J Bus Vent 18(2):189–216

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Deschryvere M (2008) High growth firms and job creation in Finland. The Research Institute of the Finnish Economy (ETLA), Discussion Papers 1144

  • Dosi G (2007) Statistical regularities in the evolution of industries: A guide through some evidence and challenges for the theory. In: Malerba F, Brusoni S (eds) Perspectives on innovation. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, pp 153–186

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • European Commission (2010) Europe 2020: A strategy for smart, sustainable and inclusive growth: Communication from the commission. Research report, European Commission

  • Foster L, Haltiwanger J, Krizan CJ (1998) Aggregate productivity growth: Lessons from microeconomic evidence. NBER Working Paper 6803, National Bureau of Economic Research

  • Fritsch M, Mueller P (2004) Effects of new business formation on regional development over time. Reg Stud 38(8):961–975

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fritsch M, Mueller P (2006) The evolution of regional entrepreneurship and growth regimes. In: Fritsch M, Schmude J (eds) Entrepreneurship in the region. Springer, New York, pp 225–244

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Fritsch M, Weyh A (2006) How large are the direct employment effects of new businesses? An empirical investigation for West Germany. Small Bus Econ 27(2–3):245–260

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gibrat R (1931) Les inégalités économiques. Librairie du Receuil Sirey, Paris

    Google Scholar 

  • Halabisky D, Dreessen E, Parsley C (2006) Growth in firms in Canada, 1985–1999. J Small Bus Entr 19(3):255–268

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Haltiwanger JC, Jarmin RS, Miranda J (2013) Who creates jobs? Small vs. large vs. young. Rev Econ Stat 95(2):347–361

    Google Scholar 

  • Hannan MT, Freeman J (1977) The population ecology of organizations. Am J Sociol 82(5):929–964

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hayek F (1937) Economics and knowledge. Economica 4(13):33–54

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hayek F (1945) The use of knowledge in society. Am Econ Rev 35(4):519–530

    Google Scholar 

  • Hayek F (1984) Competition as a discovery procedure. In: Nishiyama C, Leube K (eds) The essence of Hayek. Hoover Institution Press, Stanford, pp 254–265

    Google Scholar 

  • Henrekson M, Johansson D (2010) Gazelles as job creators: a survey and interpretation of the evidence. Small Bus Econ 35(2):227–244

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hölzl W (2009) Is the R&D behaviour of fast growing SMEs different? Evidence from CIS III data for 16 countries. Small Bus Econ 33(1):59–75

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hölzl W (2010) The economics of entrepreneurship policy: introduction to the Special Issue. J Ind Compet Trade 10(3):187–197

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hölzl W (2011) Persistence, survival and growth—A closer look at 20 years of high-growth firms in Austria. Wifo Working Papers 403:2011

    Google Scholar 

  • Hölzl W, Friesenbichler K (2010) High-growth firms, innovation and the distance to the frontier. Econ Bull 30(2):1016–1024

    Google Scholar 

  • Jovanovic B (1982) Selection and the evolution of industry. Econometrica 50(3):649–670

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kenney M (2012) Venture capital has a role, but do not forget nice-growth firms. In: Immonen S, Puheenjohtaja J (eds) Kasvuyrityskatsaus 2012. Edita Publishing Ltd, Finnish Ministry of Employment and the Economy, Helsinki, pp 60–72

    Google Scholar 

  • Kirchhoff BA (1994) Entrepreneurship and dynamic capitalism: the economics of business firm formation and growth. Praeger, Westport

    Google Scholar 

  • Klepper S, Simons KL (2005) Industry shakeouts and technological change. Int J Ind Organ 23(1–2):23–43

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Landström H (2005) Pioneers in entrepreneurship and small business research. Springer Boston, MA

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Littunen H, Tohmo T (2003) The high growth in new metal-based manufacturing and business service firms in Finland. Small Bus Econ 21(2):187–200

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • López-Garcia P, Puente S (2012) What makes a high growth firm? A probit analysis using Spanish firm-level data. Small Bus Econ 39:1029–1041

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Maddison A (2001) The world economy: A millennial perspective. OECD Development Centre, Paris

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Malerba F, Orsenigo L (1995) Schumpeterian patterns of innovation. Cam J Econ 19(1):47–65

    Google Scholar 

  • Mason C, Brown R (2013) Creating good public policy to support high-growth firms. Small Bus Econ 40(2):211–225

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • McCombie JSL (1987) Verdoorn’s law. In: Eatwell J, Milgate M, Newman P (eds) The New Palgrave: A dictionary of economics (Volume 4). Macmillan, London, pp 804–806

    Google Scholar 

  • McKelvie A, Wiklund J (2010) Advancing firm growth research: a focus on growth mode instead of growth rate. Entrep Theory Pract 34(2):261–288

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Metcalfe JS (1994) Competition, Fisher’s principle and increasing returns in the selection process. J Evol Econ 4:327–346

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Moreno AM, Casillas JC (2007) High-growth SMEs versus non-high-growth SMEs: a discriminant analysis. Entrep Reg Dev 19(1):69–88

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • OECD (2001) Measuring productivity. OECD Manual: Measurement of aggregate and industry level productivity growth. Organisation for Economic Cooperation and Development (OECD), Paris

  • OECD (2010a) High-growth enterprises: What governments can do to make a difference, OECD studies on SMEs and entrepreneurship. Organisation for Economic Cooperation and Development (OECD), Paris

  • OECD (2010b) Statistics Directorate, Labor productivity growth. http://www.oecd.org/LongAbstract/0,3425,en_2649_33715_39048703_1_1_1_1,00.html. Accessed 26 June 2013

  • Peneder M (2009) The meaning of entrepreneurship: a modular concept. J Ind Compet Trade 9(2):77–99

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Penrose E (1959) The theory of the growth of the firm. Wiley, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Picot G, Dupuy R (1998) Job creation by company size class: the magnitude, concentration and persistence of job gains and losses in Canada. Small Bus Econ 10(2):117–139

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Romer P (1986) Increasing returns and long-run growth. J Polit Econ 94(5):1002–1037

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Schreyer P (2000) High-growth firms and employment. OECD Science, Technology and Industry Working Papers 2000/3, Paris

  • Schumpeter JA (1934) The theory of economic development. Harvard University Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Schumpeter JA (1943) Capitalism, socialism and democracy. Harper, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Shane F (2009) Why encouraging more people to become entrepreneurs is bad public policy. Small Bus Econ 33:141–149

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Shepherd D, Wiklund J (2009) Are we comparing apples with apples or apples with oranges? Appropriateness of knowledge accumulation across growth studies. Entrep Theory Pract 33(1):105–123

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Stam E, Suddle K, Hessels SJA, van Stel A (2008) High growth entrepreneurs, public policies and economic growth. Paper prepared for the Basque J of Econ (EKONOMIAZ)—special issue on entrepreneurship

  • Stam E, Hartog C, van Stel A, Thurik R (2011) Ambitious entrepreneurship, high-growth firms and macroeconomic growth. In: Minniti M (ed) The dynamics of entrepreneurship: evidence from Global Entrepreneurship Monitor data. Oxford University Press, New York, pp 231–249

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Stangler D (2010) High-growth firms and the future of the American economy. Kauffman Foundation Research Series: Firm Formation and Economic Growth, March 2010

  • Sternberg R, Wennekers S (2005) Determinants and effects of new business creation using Global Entrepreneurship Monitor data. Small Bus Econ 24(3):193–203

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Storey DJ (1994) Understanding the small business sector. Routledge, London

    Google Scholar 

  • Storey DJ (1996) The ten percenters. Fast growing SMEs in Great Britain. First Report. Deloitte & Touche International, London, UK

  • Storey DJ (1997) The ten percenters. Fast growing SMEs in Great Britain. Second Report. Deloitte & Touche International, London, UK

  • Storey DJ (1998) The ten percenters. Fast growing SMEs in Great Britain. Third Report. Deloitte & Touche International, London, UK

  • Storey DJ (1999) The ten percenters. Fast growing SMEs in Great Britain. Fourth Report. Deloitte & Touche International, London, UK

  • Sutton J (1997) Gibrat’s legacy. J Econ Lit 35(1):40–59

    Google Scholar 

  • Teruel M, de Wit G (2011) Determinants of high-growth firms. Why have some countries more high-growth firms than others? EIM Research Report H201107. Zoetemeer, the Netherlands

  • van Stel A, Carree M, Thurik R (2005) The effect of entrepreneurial activity on national economic growth. Small Bus Econ 24(3):311–321

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wiklund J, Shepherd D (2003) Aspiring for, and achieving growth: the moderating role of resources and opportunities. J Man Stud 40(8):1919–1941

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Winter SG (1984) Schumpeterian competition in alternative technological regimes. J Econ Beh Org 5(3–4):287–320

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wong PK, Ho YP, Autio E (2005) Entrepreneurship, innovation and economic growth: evidence from GEM data. Small Bus Econ 24(3):335–350

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Woodward DP, Guimaraes P, Watson V (2011) High-impact firms in South Carolina. Division of Research, Moore School of Business, University of South Carolina, July 2011

Download references

Acknowledgments

We are grateful for useful comments from Niclas Berggren, David Granlund, seminar participants at Dalarna University, the 2010 HUI Workshop on Research in Retailing, the Research Institute of Industrial Economics (IFN), the Ratio Institute, and two anonymous referees. We are also grateful for financial support from Ragnar Söderberg’s Foundation.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Dan Johansson.

Appendix

Appendix

Table 13 Average age and size of HGFs for different growth cut-offs and the Eurostat-OECD definition, growth calculated over a 3-year period

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Daunfeldt, SO., Elert, N. & Johansson, D. The Economic Contribution of High-Growth Firms: Do Policy Implications Depend on the Choice of Growth Indicator?. J Ind Compet Trade 14, 337–365 (2014). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10842-013-0168-7

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Revised:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10842-013-0168-7

Keywords

JEL-code

Navigation