Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

Growth, entrepreneurship, and risk-tolerance: a risk-income paradox

  • Published:
Journal of Economic Growth Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Recent papers have modeled the prevalence of risk-tolerance as shaped by growth, making testable predictions about the distribution of risk-tolerance across the globe. We test these predictions using a dataset containing a survey question capturing people’s risk-tolerance for representative samples from 78 countries. We find a negative between-country correlation between risk-tolerance and GDP per capita. Together with the positive within-country correlation between risk-tolerance and income, this results in a risk-income paradox. We further find a negative interaction effect of risk-tolerance and GDP on fertility. These findings provide support for endogenous-preference models of economic growth.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4
Fig. 5
Fig. 6

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Galor and Michalopoulos (2012) do not take a stand on the transmission mechanism, acknowledging specifically that the theory is compatible with either genetic or cultural transmission (see their footnote 4). Transmission of preferences must, however, be prevalently vertical from parents to children, given the importance of fertility in shifting the composition of the population in terms of risk-tolerant types. Doepke and Zilibotti (2014), on the other hand, focus specifically on the transmission mechanism, identified in conscious socialization decisions by parents, but do not explicitly model the fertility channel.

  2. Most previous comparative datasets rely on student samples, thus potentially being affected by selection effects and not permitting to draw inferences on population-wide patterns (see Rieger et al. 2014; L’Haridon and Vieider 2019). An exception to this rule are the representative data described by Falk et al. (2018). We will compare our results to those based on the latter dataset below.

  3. This possibility is explicitly acknowledged by the authors, with the consequence that “allowing for entrepreneurial activity to generate higher expected income, in an era in which the latter is converted into larger number of surviving offspring, would accentuate the evolutionary advantage of the growth-promoting type.” (Galor and Michalopoulos 2012, footnote 16).

  4. The fact that we may not see convergence happening in reality may be due to convergence being conditional on a number of other factors, such as education and institutions; see e.g. Barro (1991) and Sala-i Martin (1996).

  5. Klasing (2014) proposed a model making similar predictions, that is however more difficult to test empirically. We will thus focus here on the model by Doepke and Zilibotti.

  6. Notice that this prediction is derived in equilibrium, where entrepreneurship fuels growth, and growth in turn creates incentives for parents to socialize children to be entrepreneurial. That also means that the prediction may not be expected to hold in some countries if the link between entrepreneurship and growth is broken while entrepreneurship itself is driven by other factors.

  7. We are grateful to Matthias Doepke for pointing this out in private correspondence.

  8. The choices were represented physically using colored balls and banknotes, and were shown to subjects one by one in individual interviews. At the end of the experiment, one of the decisions was randomly extracted to be played for real money—the standard procedure in this kind of task.

  9. The RRP is defined as the certainty equivalent minus the expected value, normalised by the absolute expected value.

  10. We use Pearson correlations throughout, since we are interested in the strength of the effects beyond mere ranks, and since the use of aggregate quantities lowers the incidence of outliers. Results using Spearman rank-correlations instead are qualitatively similar unless stated otherwise.

  11. We included a brief literature review of the correlation of risk-tolerance and entrepreneurship above. In terms of the correlation between risk-tolerance and income, many studies have found a positive relationship between risk-tolerance and income (Dohmen et al. 2011; Gloede et al. 2015; Hopland et al. 2016; Vieider et al. 2018; Falk et al. 2018), several others have found no correlation (Binswanger 1980; Cardenas and Carpenter 2013; Noussair et al. 2014), while others still have observed mixed results (Booij et al. 2010; Tanaka et al. 2010; von Gaudecker et al. 2011). See Hopland et al. (2016) for a more in-depth review.

  12. The question reads as follows: “On this card is a scale of incomes on which 1 indicates the ‘lowest income decile’ and 10 the ‘highest income decile’ in your country. We would like to know in what group your household is. Please, specify the appropriate number, counting all wages, salaries, pensions and other incomes that come in.”

  13. While the models we test predict causality to run from risk-tolerance to income passing through the entrepreneurship decision, in reality the causality in the risk-income relationship could run in either direction, and may well constitute a self-reinforcing feedback cycle. Indeed, the clear causal direction emerges from the model due to the abstraction from intergenerational transmission of wealth and skills, in addition to preferences. While most of the literature in labor economics emphasizes the causality from risk-tolerance to income passing through job choice (e g. Bonin et al. 2007), the literature in development economics generally emphasizes the opposite direction of causality (see Haushofer and Fehr 2014, for a review). Making risk-tolerance the dependent variable allows us to examine the correlates of risk-tolerance, which is the truly novel measure at the center of our analysis. The correlation between income and risk-tolerance is unaffected if we take income as the dependent variable instead—a regression with income as the dependent variable is shown in the Online Appendix.

  14. Our data indeed show a substantial correlation between income decile and education. In particular, each higher level of education results in a significantly higher response on the income decile scale—see online appendix for the regression result.

  15. In particular, optimistic people may overestimate their position in the income distribution, while at the same time indicating overly high levels of risk-tolerance. If so, one might observe a correlation between income and risk-tolerance that is spurious. To the extent that the life satisfaction question captures such optimism, it will serve to purify the correlation between income and risk-tolerance we observe in the regression.

  16. Notice how we take the contemporary EWP and the growth of the previous 20 years to test for the relationships predicted in the model. While risk-tolerance levels are determined by levels of these variables at the time parents educated their children, and thus generally earlier than we observe them, this strategy is legitimate in terms of the theory since the predictions are derived in equilibrium.

  17. This reflects the absence of growth data for some countries and territories in the World Bank tables (Palestine, Taiwan, and Serbia and Montenegro), as well as the absence of wage premium data for Argentina.

  18. This is not surprising. Taking an index of deaths per year out of 1000 people published by the World Bank, we find that the latter has a correlation of 0.89 with GDP per capita.

  19. The number of countries is reduced to 76 inasmuch as the question about number of children has no entries for Hong Kong and the USA.

  20. Technically, the pure effect of GDP p.c. captures the effect of GDP on the number of children for the mean level of risk-tolerance, since the latter is entered into the interaction as a z-score. That is, for an average level of risk-tolerance, GDP per capita per se has no predictive value for between-country differenes in fertility once cross-country variations in risk-tolerance are taken into account.

  21. We assembled the income per capita data at the regional level from the gross-cell-product (GCP) data assembled and discussed by Nordhaus (2006). The graph excludes a few extreme outliers on the GCP scale, generally found in petrolium-producing regions. The online appendix provides details on the assembly of the GCP data, and a stability analysis.

References

  • Andersen, S., Harrison, G. W., Lau, M. I., & Elisabet Rutström, E. (2010). Preference heterogeneity in experiments: Comparing the field and laboratory. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 73(2), 209–224.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Andersson, O., Tyran, J.-R., Wengström, E., & Holm, H. J. (2016). Risk aversion relates to cognitive ability: Preferences or noise? Journal of the European Economic Association, 14(5), 1129–1154.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ashraf, Q., & Galor, O. (2013). The out of Africa hypothesis, human genetic diversity, and comparative economic development. The American Economic Review, 103(1), 1–46.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ashraf, Q. H., & Galor, O. (2018). The macrogenoeconomics of comparative development. Journal of Economic Literature, 56(3), 1119–55.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bacon, P. M., Conte, A., & Moffatt, P. G. (2014). Assortative mating on risk attitude. Theory and Decision, 77(3), 389–401.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Barro, R. J. (1991). Economic growth in a cross-section of countries. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 106, 407–443.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Becker, G. S. (1960) An economic analysis of fertility. In Demographic and economic change in developed countries (Vol. 209, pp. 209–240). National Bureau of Economic Research, Inc.

  • Becker, A., Dohmen, T., Enke, B. & Falk A. (2015). The ancient origins of the cross-country heterogeneity in risk preferences. Working Paper

  • Becker, G. S., Murphy, K. M., & Tamura, R. (1990). Human capital, fertility, and economic growth. Journal of Political Economy, 98(5), S12–S37.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Benjamin, D. J., Brown, S. A., & Shapiro, J. M. (2013). Who is ’behavioral’? Cognitive ability and anomalous preferences. Journal of the European Economic Association, 11(6), 1231–1255.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Binswanger, H. P. (1980). Attitudes toward risk: Experimental measurement in rural India. American Journal of Agricultural Economics, 62(3), 395–407.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bisin, A., & Verdier, T. (2001). The economics of cultural transmission and the dynamics of preferences. Journal of Economic Theory, 97(2), 298–319.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bonin, H., Dohmen, T., Falk, A., Huffmann, D., & Sunde, U. (2007). Cross-sectional earnings risk and occupational sorting: The role of risk attitudes. Labour Economics, 14(6), 926–937.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Booij, A. S., van Praag, B. M. S., & van de Kuilen, G. (2010). A parametric analysis of prospect theory’s functionals for the general population. Theory and Decision, 68(1–2), 115–148.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Booth, A. L., & Nolen, P. (2012). Gender differences in risk behaviour: Does nurture matter? The Economic Journal, 122(558), F56–F78.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bowles, S. (1998). Endogenous preferences: The cultural consequences of markets and other economic institutions. Journal of Economic Literature, 36(1), 75–111.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cardenas, J. C., & Carpenter, J. (2013). Risk attitudes and economic well-being in Latin America. Journal of Development Economics, 103, 52–61.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cesarini, D., Dawes, C. T., Johannesson, M., Lichtenstein, P., & Wallace, B. (2009). Genetic variation in preferences for giving and risk taking. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 124(2), 809–842.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Charles, K. K., & Hurst, E. (2003). The correlation of wealth across generations. Journal of Political Economy, 111(6), 1155–1182.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Clark, G. (2007). A farewell to alms: A brief economic history of the world. Princeton: Princeton University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Clark, G., & Hamilton, G. (2006). Survival of the richest: The Malthusian mechanism in pre-industrial England. Journal of Economic History, 66(3), 707–736.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cohen, B. (1998). The emerging fertility transition in sub-Saharan Africa. World Development, 26(8), 1431–1461.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cramer, J. S., Hartog, J., Jonker, N., & van Praag, C. M. (2002). Low risk aversion encourages the choices for entrepreneurship: An empirical test of a Truism. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 48, 29–36.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Croson, R., & Gneezy, U. (2009). Gender differences in preferences. Journal of Economic Literature, 47(2), 1–27.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • di Falco, S., & Vieider, F. M. (2018). Assimilation in the risk preferences of spouses. Economic Inquiry, 56(3), 1809–1816.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Doepke, M., & Zilibotti, F. (2014). Culture, entrepreneurship, and growth. In P. Aghion & S. N. Durlauf (Eds.), Handbook of economic growth (Vol. 2). Amsterdam: Elsevier.

    Google Scholar 

  • Doepke, M., & Zilibotti, F. (2008). Occupational choice and the spirit of capitalism. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 123(2), 747–793.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Doepke, M., & Zilibotti, F. (2017). Parenting with style: Altruism and paternalism in intergenerational preference transmission. Econometrica, 85(5), 1331–1371.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dohmen, T., Falk, A., Huffman, D., & Sunde, U. (2010). Are risk aversion and impatience related to cognitive ability? American Economic Review, 100, 1238–1260.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dohmen, T., Falk, A., Huffman, D., & Sunde, U. (2012). The intergenerational transmission of risk and trust attitudes. Review of Economic Studies, 70(2), 645–677.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dohmen, T., Falk, A., Huffman, D., Sunde, U., Schupp, J., & Wagner, G. G. (2011). Individual risk attitudes: Measurement, determinants, and behavioral consequences. Journal of the European Economic Association, 9(3), 522–550.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Falk, A., Becker, A., Dohmen, T., Enke, B., Huffman, D., & Sunde, U. (2018). Global evidence on economic preferences. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 133, 1645–1692.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fehr-Duda, H., & Epper, T. (2012). Probability and risk: Foundations and economic implications of probability-dependent risk preferences. Annual Review of Economics, 4(1), 567–593.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Galizzi, M. M., Machado, S. R., & Miniaci, R. (2016). Temporal stability, cross-validity, and external validity of risk preferences measures: Experimental evidence from a UK representative sample.’ SSRN Scholarly Paper ID 2822613, Social Science Research Network, Rochester, NY, August

  • Gallup, J. L., Sachs, J. D., & Mellinger, A. D. (1999). Geography and economic development. International Regional Science Review, 22(2), 179–232.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Galor, O., & Savitskiy, V. (2018) Climatic roots of loss aversion. Technical report

  • Galor, O., & Klemp, M. (2019). Human genealogy reveals a selective advantage to moderate fecundity. Nature Ecology & Evolution, 3, 853–857.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Galor, O., & Michalopoulos, S. (2012). Evolution and the growth process: Natural selection of entrepreneurial traits. Journal of Economic Theory, 147(2), 759–780.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Galor, O., & Moav, O. (2002). Natural selection and the origin of economic growth. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 117(4), 1133–1191.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Galor, O., & Özak, Ö. (2016). The agricultural origins of time preference. American Economic Review, 106(10), 3064–3103.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Galor, O., & Weil, D. N. (2000). Population, technology, and growth: From Malthusian stagnation to the demographic transition and beyond. American Economic Review, 90(4), 806–828.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Garenne, M., & Joseph, V. (2002). The timing of the fertility transition in sub-Saharan Africa. World Development, 30(10), 1835–1843.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gloede, O., Menkhoff, L., & Waibel, H. (2015). Shocks, individual risk attitude, and vulnerability to poverty among rural households in Thailand and Vietnam. World Development, 71, 54–78.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Goodman, A., Koupil, I., & Lawson, D. W. (2012). Low fertility increases descendant socioeconomic position but reduces long-term fitness in a modern post-industrial society. Proceedings of the Royal Society B, 279, 4324–4351.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Görlitz, K., & Tamm, M. (2015). Parenthood and risk preferences.’ SSRN Scholarly Paper ID 2618442, Social Science Research Network, Rochester, NY

  • Hardeweg, B., Menkhoff, L., & Waibel, H. (2013). Experimentally validated survey evidence on individual risk attitudes in rural Thailand. Economic Development and Cultural Change, 61(4), 859–888.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Haushofer, J., & Fehr, E. (2014). On the psychology of poverty. Science, 344(6186), 862–867.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hill, E. M., Ross, L. T., & Low, B. S. (1997). The role of future unpredictability in human risk-taking. Human Nature, 8(4), 287.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hopland, A. O., Matsen, E., & Strøm, B. (2016). Income and choice under risk. Journal of Behavioral and Experimental Finance, 12, 55–64.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Keefer, P., & Knack, S. (1997). Why don’t poor countries catch up? A cross-national test of an institutional explanation. Economic Inquiry, 35(3), 590–602.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kimball, M. S., Sahm, C. R., & Shapiro, M. D. (2009). Risk preferences in the PSID: Individual imputations and family covariation. American Economic Review, Papers and Proceedings, 99(2), 363–368.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Klasing, M. J. (2014). Cultural change, risk-taking behavior and implications for economic development. Journal of Development Economics, 110, 158–169.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Levine, R. (1998). The legal environment, banks, and long-run economic growth. Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, 30(3), 596–613.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • L’Haridon, O., & Vieider, F. M. (2019). All over the map: A worldwide comparison of risk preferences. Quantitative Economics, 10, 185–215.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lönnqvist, J.-E., Verkasalo, M., Walkowitz, G., & Wichardt, P. C. (2015). Measuring individual risk attitudes in the lab: Task or ask? An empirical comparison. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 119, 254–266.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Malmendier, U., & Nagel, S. (2011). Depression babies: Do Macroeconomic experiences affect risk taking?*. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 126(1), 373–416.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Martin, S., & Xavier, X. (1996). The classical approach to convergence analysis. Economic Journal, 106(437), 1019–36.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Moulton, B. R. (1986). Random group effects and the precision of regression estimates. Journal of Econometrics, 32(3), 385–397.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nordhaus, W. D. (2006). Geography and macroeconomics: New data and new findings. Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences of the United States of America, 103(10), 3510–3517.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Noussair, C. N., Trautmann, S., & van de Kuilen, G. (2014). Higher order risk attitudes, demographics, and financial decisions. Review of Economic Studies, 21(1), 325–355.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Porta, L., Rafael, F. L., Silanes, A. S., & Vishny, R. (1998). Law and finance. Journal of Political Economy, 106(6), 1113–1155.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rieger, M. O., Wang, M., & Hens, T. (2014). Risk preferences around the world. Management Science, 61(3), 637–648.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Robinson, W. (1950). Ecological correlations and the behavior of individuals. American Sociological Review, 15, 351–357.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Schmidt, L. (2008). Risk preferences and the timing of marriage and childbearing. Demography, 45(2), 439–460.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Shaw, K. L. (1996). An empirical analysis of risk aversion and income growth. Journal of Labor Economics, 14(4), 626–653.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Snijders, T. A. B., & Bosker, R. J. (2012). Multilevel analysis: An introduction to basic and advanced multilevel modeling (2nd ed.). London: Sage PUblications.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tanaka, T., Camerer, C. F., & Nguyen, Q. (2010). Risk and time preferences: Linking experimental and household survey data from Vietnam. American Economic Review, 100(1), 557–571.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Vieider, F. M., Beyene, A., Bluffstone, R. A., Dissanayake, S., Gebreegziabher, Z., Martinsson, P., et al. (2018). Measuring risk preferences in rural Ethiopia. Economic Development and Cultural Change, 66(3), 417–446.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Vieider, F. M., Lefebvre, M., Bouchouicha, R., Chmura, T., Hakimov, R., Krawczyk, M., et al. (2015). Common components of risk and uncertainty attitudes across contexts and domains: Evidence from 30 countries. Journal of the European Economic Association, 13(3), 421–452.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Vieider, F. M., Martinsson, P., Khanh, N. P., & Truong, N. (2019). Risk preferences and development revisited. Theory & Decision, 86, 1–21.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • von Gaudecker, H.-M., van Soest, A., & Wengström, E. (2011). Heterogeneity in risky choice behaviour in a broad population. American Economic Review, 101(2), 664–694.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wilson, M., & Daly, M. (1997). Life expectancy, economic inequality, homicide, and reproductive timing in Chicago neighbourhoods. British Medical Journal, 314(7089), 1271–1274.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Zeger, S. L., Liang, K.-Y., & Albert, P. S. (1988). Models for longitudinal data: A generalized estimating equation approach. Biometrics, 44(4), 1049–1060.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Zhong, S., Chew, S. H., Set, E., Zhang, J., Xue, H., Sham, P. C., et al. (2009). The heritability of attitude toward economic risk. Twin Research and Human Genetics, 12(1), 103–107.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Ferdinand M. Vieider.

Additional information

Publisher's Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

The experimental validation contained in this paper was financed by the German Science Foundation (DFG) as part of project VI 692/1-1 on “Risk preferences and economic behavior: Experimental evidence from the field”. We are grateful to Matthias Doepke, Oded Galor, Thomas Dohmen, Thomas Epper, and to five anonymous referees for constructive and helpful comments. All errors remain our own.

Electronic supplementary material

Below is the link to the electronic supplementary material.

Supplementary material 1 (pdf 1102 KB)

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Bouchouicha, R., Vieider, F.M. Growth, entrepreneurship, and risk-tolerance: a risk-income paradox. J Econ Growth 24, 257–282 (2019). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10887-019-09168-0

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10887-019-09168-0

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation