Skip to main content
Log in

A simple test for distinguishing between internal reference price theories

  • Published:
Quantitative Marketing and Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

A large literature demonstrates the empirical importance of internal reference price effects. There are several theories regarding how and why these effects arise. We offer a simple test that distinguishes between the two leading theories based on economically rational behavior: price as a signal of quality and price as a predictor of future prices. Our test builds on differences in how past consumer purchases interact with internal reference prices. We first validate the reliability of our test by applying it to synthetic data. We then apply our test to purchases of ketchup and diapers and find: (1) quality signaling is the dominant mechanism behind reference price effects in both categories; (2) consistent with the quality-signaling theory, reference price effects diminish as various measures of consumer experience increase; but (3) in both categories there are many individuals for whom price-prediction effects dominate quality-signaling effects.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. There are models of new product introduction and consumer learning in which either a low introductory price (Tirole 1992, page 111) or an inefficiently high introductory price (Bagwell and Riordan 1991) can signal high quality. In the former model, a product’s mean price increases over time, whereas in the latter, a product’s mean price decreases.

  2. Perhaps less plausibly, quality signaling can also arise in a one-period model in which all consumers are uninformed about quality. Signaling can be sustained when firms charging higher prices signal higher quality, but have lower unit sales due to the nature of consumer tastes. This mechanism requires that firms have exogenously given quality levels and marginal costs that increase in quality.

  3. Guadagni and Little labeled this past-purchase term as “brand loyalty.” The broader literature, however, uses brand loyalty to refer both to positive state dependence (positive past purchase feedback) and unobserved heterogeneity. As discussed by Keane (1997), our Eq. 2 is the standard operationalization of positive state dependence. We account for unobserved heterogeneity separately in our model. Hence, we do not adopt the brand loyalty label for our past-purchase (use experience) variable.

  4. Additional discussion of the inventory variable is presented in the Appendix.

  5. An alternative approach to updating would be to update reference prices conditional on category purchase. In addition to failing to mesh with empirical findings (see Briesch et al. 1997 for a survey of the literature), this alternative approach suffers from a lack of internal consistency. To see why, observe that, if at least some consumers buy at low prices rather than at high, this behavior suggests that households check prices when they are high as well as low. Updating reference prices only when households make purchases would underestimate the reference price.

  6. The role of memory also merits attention in passing. Although such effects can, in theory, be important, past work has shown that they do not matter much empirically (see Briesch et al. 1997). Hence, we do not include them in our model.

  7. Katz and Shapiro (1986) provided an early test of the information-based kinked demand theory using scanner panel data for coffee.

  8. Erdem et al. (2003) have shown that the best model of ketchup prices is that they fluctuate around a mean while exhibiting serial correlation. Those authors assume there is no learning about the price process over time; households are assumed either to know the process exactly or not to know it all, and the former assumption fits the data better than does the latter.

  9. In addition, this may indicate that the consumer has a high overall willingness to pay for the product (otherwise the household would have foregone purchasing entirely). This would be true under either mechanism.

  10. Although we leave the issue for another paper, it is also worth observing that there may be other implications of the two mechanisms that could be used to determine their joint presence. For example, as shown by Hendel and Nevo (2006b), the price-expectations mechanism gives rise to certain predictions about the relationship between prices and interpurchase durations that the presence of a quality-signaling mechanism would not offset. In the present paper, we implicitly account for purchase timing by modeling purchase incidence, which is allowed to be a function of inventories, but we do not offer a full model of inventory behavior.

  11. We also checked for situations whether zero brand sales were observed for an extended and consecutive periods of time. Although zero brand sales for few consecutive periods occur (which are usually the cases when zero sales are correlated with consumer preferences) at some stores, prolonged/extended and consecutive zero sales were very rare.

  12. The mean prices of the excluded brands were generally less than those of Huggies and Pampers, but greater than those of Luvs and store brands. Thus, it does not appear that the excluded brands were targeted at especially price-conscious consumers.

  13. A large number of households in our dataset purchased diapers on only one occasion, suggesting that they were making purchases for children temporarily visiting. Alternatively, although our data set covers a high percentage of stores in each city, it is possible that what appear in our sample as single-purchase households are actually households that made repeated purchases at stores outside of our sample. In any event, we exclude these households from our analysis because we have no means of measuring their experience.

  14. After other exclusions, we lost only 16 households in Chicago and 21 households in Atlanta due to this restriction.

  15. The median interpurchase time for ketchup was 10.45 weeks. The mean and standard deviation of interpurchase times were 12.46 weeks and 7.36 weeks, respectively.

  16. For each estimation, we used an initialization period to set the initial values of the reference price and experience measures. Based on the distribution of interpurchase times, we used an initialization period of 21 weeks for diapers and 24 weeks for ketchup. We also tried several other period lengths, and our results were insensitive to the specific choices.

References

  • Bagwell, K., & Riordan, M. H. (1991). High and declining prices signal product quality. The American Economic Review, 81(1), 224–239.

    Google Scholar 

  • Briesch, R. A., Krishnamurthi, L., Mazumdar, T., & Raj, S. P. (1997). A comparative analysis of reference price models. Journal of Consumer Research, 24(2), 202–214.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Caves, R. E., & Greene, D. P. (1996). Brands’ quality levels, prices and advertising outlays: empirical evidence on signals and information costs. International Journal of Industrial Organization, 14(1), 29–52.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Erdem, T., Imai, S., & Keane, M. (2003). A model of consumer brand and quantity choice dynamics under price uncertainty. Quantitative Marketing and Economics, 1(1), 5–64.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Erdem, T., Keane, M., & Sun, B. (2008). A dynamic model of brand choice when price and advertising signal product quality. Marketing Science, 27(6), 1111–1125.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Guadagni, P. M., & Little, J. D. C. (1983). A logit model of brand choice calibrated on scanner data. Marketing Science, 2(3), 203–238.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hendel, I., & Nevo, A. (2006a). Measuring the implications of sales and consumer inventory behavior. Econometrica, 74(6), 1637–1673.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hendel, I., & Nevo, A. (2006b). Sales and consumer inventory. The Rand Journal of Economics, 37(3), 543–561.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kahneman, D., & Tversky, A. (1979). Prospect theory: an analysis of decision under risk. Econometrica, 47(2), 263–292.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kalyanaram, G., & Little, J. D. C. (1994). An empirical analysis of latitude of price acceptance in consumer package goods. Journal of Consumer Research, 21(3), 408–418.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kalyanaram, G., & Winer, R. S. (1995). Empirical generalizations from reference price research. Marketing Science, 14(3, Part 2), G161–G169.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Katz, M. L., & Shapiro C. (1986). Consumer shopping behavior in the retail coffee market. In Empirical approaches to consumer protection, Federal Trade Commission.

  • Keane, M. (1993). Simulation estimation for panel data models with limited dependent variables. In G. S. Maddala, C. R. Rao & H. D. Vinod (Eds.), The handbook of statistics. Amsterdam: North Holland.

  • Keane, M. P. (1997). Modeling heterogeneity and state dependence in consumer choice behavior. Journal of Business and Economic Statistics, 15(3), 310–327.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lattin, J. M., & Bucklin, R. E. (1989). Reference effects of price and promotion on brand choice behavior. Journal of Marketing Research, 26(3), 299–310.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lichtenstein, D. R., & Burton, S. (1989). The relationship between perceived and objective price-quality. Journal of Marketing Research, 26, 429–443.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mayhew, G. E., & Winer, R. S. (1992). An empirical analysis of internal and external reference prices using scanner data. Journal of Consumer Research, 19, 62–70.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mazumdar, T., & Papatla, P. (1995). Loyalty differences in the use of internal and external reference prices. Marketing Letters, 6(2), 111–122.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • McFadden, D. (1974). Conditional logit analysis of qualitative choice behavior. In P. Zarenmbka (Ed.), Frontiers in econometrics. New York: Academic Press.

  • McFadden, D. (1989). A method of simulated moments for estimation of discrete response models without numerical integration. Econometrica, 54, 1027–1058.

  • Pakes, A. (1987). Patents as options: some estimates of the value of holding european patent stocks. Econometrica, 57, 755–784.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rao, A. R., & Monroe, K. B. (1989). The effect of price, brand name and store name on buyers’ perceptions of product quality: an integrative review. Journal of Marketing Research, 26, 351–357.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Slonim, R., & Garbarino, E. (2009). Similarities and differences between stockpiling and reference effects. Managerial and Decision Economics, 30, 351–371.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Stiglitz, J. E. (1987). The causes and consequences of the dependence of quality on price. Journal of Economic Literature, 25, 1–48.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sun, B. (2005). Promotion effect on endogenous consumption. Marketing Science, 24(3), 430–443.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sun, B., Neslin, S., & Srinivasan, K. (2003). Measuring the impact of promotions on brand switching under rational consumer behavior. Journal of Marketing Research, 40(4), 389–405.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Thaler, R. (1985). Mental accounting and consumer choice. Marketing Science, 4(3), 199–214.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tirole, J. (1992). The theory of industrial organization (2nd ed.). Cambridge: MIT.

    Google Scholar 

  • Winer, R. S. (1986). A reference price model of brand choice for frequently purchased products. Journal of Consumer Research, 13(2), 250–256.

    Google Scholar 

  • Winer, R. S. (1988). Behavioral perspective on pricing: buyers’ subjective perceptions of price revisited. In T. Devinney (Ed.), Issues in pricing: theory and research (pp. 35–57). Lexington: Lexington Books.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Tülin Erdem.

Additional information

We are grateful to Sue Chang for expert research assistance, Michael Keane for extremely helpful advice, and two referees and seminar audiences at Columbia University, Duke University, the 4-School Colloquium (Columbia, NYU, Wharton, and Yale), New York University, and University of California, Riverside for useful comments and suggestions.

Appendix: additional data preparation

Appendix: additional data preparation

Diaper price index

We aggregated each brand’s diaper sizes into five categories: (a) 0 and 1; (b) 2; (c) 3; (d) 4; and (e) 5 and 6. We lumped sizes 0 and 1, as well as 5 and 6, together because the size differences between 0 and 1 and 5 and 6 are very small and there were fewer purchases of these sizes individually compared to other sizes. We then created a distinct price index for each: brand × size category × week × store. Where data were available, we took a quantity-weighted average of the prices paid at that store that week for that brand and size category. We calculated the sample-period weights by city. Where no data were available for a given store/week for that diaper size/brand, we constructed a price index based on the relevant data for all stores in the same city that week. If no data were available at any store in a given week, then we used the process described earlier in the text to interpolate data from other weeks:

Household-level inventory variable

Consider a household with purchase dates t 1, t 2,...,t N , and let \( {x_{{t_1}}},{x_{{t_2}}},...,{x_t}_N \) denote the corresponding purchase quantities on those dates. Notice that the purchase quantities are 0 in weeks that are in our sample period but not on these dates; that is, X t=0 for \( t \notin \left\{ {{t_1},{t_2},...,{t_N}} \right\}. \)

We first construct a consumption rate variable:

$$ r \equiv \frac{{\,\sum\limits_{j = 1}^{N - 1} {{x_{{t_j}}}} }}{{{t_N} - {t_1}}} $$

Notice that the summation of the quantities does not include the final purchase.

We next divide households into two categories. The first category comprises households that appear to make the first purchases of their lifetimes during the sample period. These households are identified as those that took a “long time” before making a purchase in the sample period. Specifically, a household’s purchase at time t 1 is considered to be its first ever if \( {t_1} > {\max_{j = 1,2...N - 1}}\left\{ {{t_{j + 1}} - {t_j}} \right\} \). For these households, we assume that they were not active purchasers until date t 1. That is, we exclude them from the sample for t < t 1. From date t 1 onward, we define their inventory at date t as follows:

$$ \begin{array}{*{20}{c}} {I{V_t}_{_1} = 0} \hfill \\{I{V_t} = \max \left\{ {I{V_{t - 1}} + {x_{t - 1}} - r,\;0} \right\}\;{\hbox{for}}\;t > {t_1}.} \hfill \\\end{array} $$

The second category of households comprises those that made initial purchases prior to the start of our sample period. These are households for whom \( {t_1} \leqslant {\max_{j = 1,2...N - 1}}\left\{ {{t_{j + 1}} - {t_j}} \right\} \). For these households, we assume that

$$ \begin{array}{*{20}{c}} {I{V_t} = r\left( {{t_1} - t} \right)\;{\hbox{for}}\;t < {t_1}} \hfill \\{I{V_{{t_1}}} = 0} \hfill \\{I{V_t} = \max \left\{ {{I_{t - 1}} + {x_{t - 1}} - r,0} \right\}\;{\hbox{for}}\;t > {t_1}.} \hfill \\\end{array} $$

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Erdem, T., Katz, M.L. & Sun, B. A simple test for distinguishing between internal reference price theories. Quant Mark Econ 8, 303–332 (2010). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11129-010-9087-7

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11129-010-9087-7

Keywords

JEL classifications

Navigation