Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

College Major and the Gender Earnings Gap: A Multi-country Examination of Postgraduate Labour Market Outcomes

  • Published:
Research in Higher Education Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

This paper explores the effects of degree choice on the distribution of occupational benefits in terms of income, and their contribution to the gender earnings gap, among young European higher education graduates. The results reveal that the field of study, which is the result of a personal choice, appears to influence the distribution of work-related benefits among graduates even after controlling for unobservable heterogeneity and observable individual/job specific characteristics. Analysis of the gender earnings gap shows that the earning disparities among female/male graduates in Education, Humanities and Mathematics are smaller.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

References

  • Angrist, J., Imbens, G., & Rubin, G. (1996). Identification of causal effects using instrumental variables. Journal of the American Statistical Association, 91, 444–455.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Barsky, R., Bound, J., Charles, K. K., & Lupton, J. (2002). Accounting for the black-white wealth gap. Journal of the American Statistical Association, 97, 663–673.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Becker, G. S. (1991). A treatise on the family (enlarged ed.). Cambridge MA: Hardvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Berger, M. C. (1988). Predicted future earnings and choice of college major. Industrial and Labor Relations Review, 41(3), 418–429.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Blinder, A. S. (1973). Wage discrimination reduced form and structural estimates. Journal of Human Resources, 81, 436–455.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Card, D. (1999). The causal effect of education on earnings. In O. Ashenfelter & D. Card (Eds.), Handbook of labor economics (3rd ed.). Amsterdmam: Elsevier Science.

    Google Scholar 

  • Carneiro, P., Hansen, K., & Heckman, J. J. (2003). Estimating distribution of treatment effects with an application to returns to schooling and measurement of the effects of uncertainty on collage choice. International Economic Review, 44(2), 361–422.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Charles, M., Buchmann, M., Halebsky, S., Powers, J., & Smith, M. (2001). The context of women’s market careers. Work and Occupations, 28(3), 371–396.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cotton, J. (1988). On the decomposition of wage differentials. Review of Economics and Statistics, 70, 236–243.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dar, Y., & Getz, S. (2007). Learning ability, socioeconomic status, and student placement for undergraduate studies in Israel. Higher Education, 54, 41–60.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dolton, P. J., & Makepeace, G. M. (1985). The statistical measurement of discrimination. Economics Letters, 18, 391–395.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Edison, H. J., & Klovland, J. T. (1987). A quantitative reassessment of the purchasing power parity hypothesis: Evidence from Norway and the United Kingdom. Journal of Applied Econometrics, 2(4), 309–333.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • García-Aracil, A. (2007). Gender earnings gap among young European higher education graduates. Higher Education, 53, 431–455.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • García-Aracil, A., Gabaldón, D., Mora, J. G., & Vila, L. E. (2007). The relationship between life goals and field of study among young European graduates. Higher Education, 53(6), 843–865.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • García-Aracil, A., & Van der Velden, R. (2007). Competencies for young European higher education graduates: Labor market mismatches and their payoffs. Higher education. doi:10.1007/s10734-006-9050-4.

  • Gerhart, B. (1990). Gender differences in current and starting salaries: The role of performance, college major, and job title. Industrial and Labor Relations Review, 43, 418–433.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gill, A. M., & Leigh, D. E. (2000). Community college enrolment, college major, and the gender wage gap. Industrial and Labor Relations Review, 54(1), 163–181.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Green, W. H. (1997). Econometric analysis (3rd ed.). New Jersey: Prentice-Hall.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hansen, M. N. (1993). Sex segregation in higher-education-influence of parents education and social background on students choice of field. Tidsskrift for Samfunnsforskning, 34(1), 3–29.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hansen, M. N. (1997). Social and economic inequality in the educational career: Do the effects of social background characteristics decline? European Sociological Review, 13(3), 305–321.

    Google Scholar 

  • Heckman, J. J. (1978). Dummy endogenous variables in a simultaneous equations system. Econometrica, 46(4), 931–959.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Heckman, J. J. (1979). Sample selection bias as a specification error. Econometrica, 47, 153–161.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Heckman, J. J. (2001). Micro data, heterogeneity, and the evaluation of public policy: Nobel lecture. Journal of Political Economy, 109(4), 673–748.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Heckman, J. J., & Navarro, S. (2004). Using matching, instrumental variables, and control functions to estimate economic choice models. Review of Economics and Statistics, 86(1), 30–57.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jablonska-Skinder, H., & Teichler, U. (1992). Handbook of higher education diplomas in Europe. Muenchen: K.G. Saur.

    Google Scholar 

  • Jacobs, J. A. (1995). Gender and academic specialities: Trends among recipients of college degrees in the 1980s. Sociology of Education, 68(2), 81–98.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Joy, L. (2003). Salaries of recent male and female college graduates: Educational and labor market effects. Industrial and Labor Relations Review, 56(4), 606–621.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Keane, M., & Wolpin, K. (1997). The career decision of young men. Journal of Political Economy, 105(3), 473–522.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kim, A., & Kim, K. W. (2003). Returns to tertiary education in Germany and the UK: Effects of fields of study and gender. Mannheimer Zentrum für Europäische Sozialforschung: Working paper, 62, 1–35.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lightbody, P., & Durndell, A. (1996). The masculine image of careers in science and technology: Fact or fantasy? British Journal of Educational Psychology, 66, 231–246.

    Google Scholar 

  • Loury, L. D. (1997). The gender earnings gap among college-educated workers. Industrial and Labor Relations Review, 50(4), 580–593.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Machin, S., & Puhani, P. A. (2003). Subject of degree and the gender wage differential: Eevidence from the UK and Germany. Economics Letters, 79(3), 393–400.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mincer, J., & Polachek, S. (1974). Family investments in human capital: Earnings of women. Journal of Political Economy, 82, S76–S108.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Montmarquette, C., Cannings, K., & Mahseredjian, S. (2002). How do young people choose college majors? Economics of Education Review, 21, 543–556.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Neumark, D. (1988). Employers’ discrimination behaviour and the estimation of wage discrimination. Journal of Human Resources, 23, 279–295.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Newey, W. K. (1990). Efficient instrumental variables estimation of nonlinear models. Econometrica, 58(4), 809–837.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Oaxaca, R. (1973). Male-female wage differentials in urban labor market. International Economic Review, 9, 693–705.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Oaxaca, R., & Ransom, M. (1994). On discrimination and the decomposition of wage differentials. Journal of Econometrics, 61(1), 5–21.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Oaxaca, R., & Ransom, M. (1999). Identification in detailed wage decompositions. Review of Economics and Statistics, 81, 154–157.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • OECD. (1992). Alternatives to universities. Paris: OECD.

    Google Scholar 

  • OECD. (1997). Education at a glance: OECD indicators. Paris: OECD.

    Google Scholar 

  • Polachek, S. W. (1978). Sex differences in college major. Industrial and Labor Relations Review, 31(4), 498–508.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Robinson, P. (1976). Instrumental variables estimation of differential equations. Econometrica, 44, 756–776.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rumberger, R. W., & Thomas, S. L. (1993). The economic returns to college major, quality and performance: A multilevel analysis of recent graduates. Economics of Education Review, 12(1), 1–19.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Schomburg, H., & Teichler, U. (Eds). (2006). Higher education and graduate Employment in Europe: Results of graduate survey from twelve countries. Higher education dynamics (Vol. 15). Springer: Netherlands.

  • Schultz, T. P. (1991). Labor market discrimination: Measurement and interpretation. In N. Birdsall & R. Sabot (Eds.), Unfair advantage: Labor market discrimination in developing countries. Washington, DC: The World Bank.

    Google Scholar 

  • Smyth, E. (2005). Gender differentiation and early labour market integration across Europe. European Societies, 7(3), 451–479.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Teichler, U. (2000). Graduate employment and work in selected European countries. European Journal of Education, 35(2), 141–156.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Teichler, U. (Ed.). (2007). Careers of university graduates: Views and experiences in comparative perspectives. The Netherlands: Springer.

    Google Scholar 

  • Thomas, S. L. (2000). Deferred costs and economic returns to college major, quality, and performance. Research in Higher Education, 41(3), 281–313.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Thomas, S. L. (2003). Longer-term economic effects of college selectivity and control. Research in Higher Education, 44(3), 263–299.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Thomas, S. L., & Zhang, L. (2005). Post-baccalaureate wage growth within 4 years of graduation: The effects of college quality and college major. Research in Higher Education, 46(4), 437–459.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tokar, D. M., Fischer, A. R., & Subich, L. M. (1998). Personality and vocational behavior: A selective review of the literature, 1993–1997. Journal of Vocational Behaviour, 53(2), 115–153.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Turner, S. E., & Bowen, W. G. (1999). Choice of major: The changing (unchanging) gender gap. Industrial and Labor Relations Review, 52(2), 289–313.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Werfhorst, van de H. G., Kraaykamp, G., & de Graaf, N. D. (2000). Intergenerational transmission of educational field resources. The impact of parental resources and socialization practices on children’s fields of study in the Netherlands. Netherlands Journal of Social Sciences, 36(2), 188–210.

    Google Scholar 

  • Whitehead, J. M. (1996). Sex stereotypes, gender identity and subject choice at A-level. Education Research, 38(2), 147–160.

    Google Scholar 

  • Wijnards van Resandt, A. (Ed.). (1991). A guide to higher education systems and qualifications in the European communities. Luxemburg: Office for Official Publications of the European Communities.

    Google Scholar 

  • Willis, R. J., & Rosen, S. (1979). Education and self-selection. Journal of Political Economy, 87(5), S7–S36.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Windolf, P. (1992). Choosing the major subject of study. Kolner Zeitschrift Fur Soziologie und Sozialpsychologie, 44(1), 76–98.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Adela García-Aracil.

Appendix

Appendix

Variables Used in the Multinomial Model for the Choice of Field of Study

Table 10 Descriptive statistics for the choice of field of study analysis

Methodology for Analysing the Effects of Degree Field on Earnings

Analysis of the effects of study field choice on earnings first needs to address the process behind the choice of field in terms of heterogeneity among graduates (Carneiro et al. 2003). That is, to isolate the income effects of the choice itself, we should compare earnings for graduates from different fields, with similar personal characteristics, doing similar jobs. Otherwise, the estimated coefficients should be interpreted as mere correlations between field of graduation and income, rather than the causal effects of field choice on income (Angrist et al. 1996) because students choose their field of study according to their background, tastes, inclinations, preferences and prospects. Accordingly, graduates from a given field are likely to share some personal characteristics, which may themselves influence their earnings beyond the effect generated by the educational choice itself (Heckman 1978, 2001; Heckman and Navarro 2004).

Therefore, the rationale for having two specifications of the earnings model is that it allows comparison between the coefficients of the study field, considered as an exogenous determinant of income (statistical correlation) and an endogenous determinant (causal effect). Under the first specification, we analyse the earnings for graduates from different fields doing comparable jobs (exogenous choice); under the second, we analyse the earnings of graduates from different fields, with similar personal characteristics and doing comparable jobs (endogenous choice).

The so-called direct specification of the model can be represented as

$$ I = \Upphi \left( {F,\,X} \right) + u $$
(1)

where I is income/earnings, F is actual field of graduation, X are the other observable determinants of income, and u is a disturbance term. Here, the field of study is included as an exogenous determinant of I. The estimated coefficient for F captures only the statistical correlation between field of graduation and income because the process behind the choice of field is not addressed.

However, we argue that the choice of field should be considered as an endogenous process that can be represented as

$$ F = \vartheta \left( Z \right) + v $$
(2)

where F again is the field of study, Z are individual-specific characteristics (observed heterogeneity) guiding the choice, and v is a disturbance term representing unobserved heterogeneity among graduates.

Substituting Eq. 2 into 1 yields \(\user2{I}=\varvec{\Upphi}[\varvec{\vartheta}\left(\user2{Z}\right)+\user2{v,\,X}]+\user2{u}. \) So, when the choice of field is endogenous, the coefficient of F estimated from Eq. 1 reflects the real influence of the term \( \varvec \vartheta \left( {\user2{Z}} \right) + {\user2{v}}. \) Obviously, this also includes the influence of unobserved heterogeneity among graduates from different fields, v, which in turn is correlated with u. This is the case for a regressor correlated with the disturbance term of the model, so the coefficient estimate would represent correlation, but not causal effect.

This problem can be fixed by estimating Eq. 2 first, thus obtaining a prediction for field of study in terms of the individual-specific observable characteristics, and discarding unobserved heterogeneity. This is equivalent to assigning to each graduate the field of study that would suit him/her best according to his/her own personal observable characteristics \( {\user2{F^*}} = \varvec \vartheta {\user2{^* }}\left( {\user2{Z}} \right) = {\user2{F - v^*}}, \) where (*) indicates an estimate.

By including the predicted field \( {\user2{F^*}} = \varvec \vartheta {\user2{^* }}\left( {\user2{Z}} \right) \) as a regressor in Eq. 1 instead of the observed F, the so-called instrumental variable (IV) specification emerges

$$ I = \Upphi (\vartheta ^* \left( Z \right),\,X) + u $$
(3)

Under this specification \( \varvec \vartheta {\user2{^* }}\left( {\user2{Z}} \right) ={\user2{F^*}} \) is not correlated with the disturbance term u. Consequently, the coefficient estimate from Eq. 3 captures the causal effect of field choice once the effects of heterogeneity among graduates from different fields have been removed through the two-step estimation procedure.

Variables Used in the Earning Equation

Table 11 Descriptive statistics for the earnings analysis

Methodology for Analysing Gender Earnings Gap

A number of econometric techniques have been developed to parse out the earnings differentials among groups of people (Blinder 1973; Oaxaca 1973; Cotton 1988; Neumark 1988; Oaxaca and Ransom 1994). The Oaxaca (1973) model, modified by Oaxaca and Ransom (1994), is the most widely used and is employed here. The standard procedure is to fit the following two equations, or earnings functions, for the employed members of each population group:

$$ LnY_{m} = b_{m} X_{m} + \upsilon _{m} $$
(4)
$$ LnY_{f} = b_{f} X_{f} + \upsilon _{f} $$
(5)

where subscripts m and f represent male and female workers, respectively; Y symbolises labour market earnings; X represents the measured productivity-determining characteristics of workers such as education, age and other control variables; b , the regression coefficient, reflects the labour market returns to a unit change in characteristics such as age and education; and u , the error term, reflects measurement error, including the effect of factors unmeasured or unobserved by the researcher. Taking the arithmetic average of Eqs. 4 and 5, the stochastic error term drops away, so that

$$ Ln\overline Y _{m} = \mathop b\limits^{ \wedge } {_m}\overline X{ _{m}} $$
(6)
$$ Ln\overline Y _{f} = \mathop b\limits^{ \wedge } {_{f}}\overline X {_{f}} $$
(7)

where hats (^) denote estimated values and bars (—) represent mean values, which simply says that mean earnings are predicted by mean characteristics.

If female workers received the same returns as male workers for their endowments of earnings-determining characteristics, then their average earnings would be

$$ Ln\overline Y _{f}^{*} = \mathop b\limits^{ \wedge } {_{m}}\overline X {_{f}} $$
(8)

which would therefore be the average earnings of female workers that would prevail if there were no wage discrimination.

Subtracting Eq. 8 from Eq. 6 gives the difference between the average male earnings and the hypothetical average female earnings that would prevail if female workers’ human capital in the labour market was rewarded in precisely the same way as male workers’ human capital. The difference between actual and hypothetical earnings reflects the differences between the two population groups’ human capital, so that

$$ Ln\overline {Y_{m} } - Ln\overline Y _{f}^{*} = \mathop{b}\limits^{ \wedge }{ _{m}} \overline X {_{m}} - \mathop b\limits^{\wedge } {_{m}} \overline {X_{f} } = \mathop b\limits^{ \wedge }{_{m}} (\overline {X_{m} } - \overline {X_{f} } ) $$
(9)

Subtracting Eq. 7 from Eq. 8 yields the difference between the actual and the hypothetical non-discriminatory earnings of female workers. This difference reflects the differential returns that the market awards to different population groups with the same human capital characteristics:

$$ Ln\overline Y _{f}^{*} - Ln\overline {Y_{f} } = \mathop{b}\limits^{ \wedge }{ _{m}} \overline X {_{f}} - \mathop b\limits^{\wedge } {_{f}} \overline {X_{f} } = \overline {X_{f} } (\mathop{b_{m} }\limits^{ \wedge } - \mathop {b_{f} }\limits^{ \wedge } )$$
(10)

Adding Eqs. 9 and 10 yields

$$ Ln\overline {Y_{m} } - Ln\overline {Y_{f} } = \mathop{b}\limits^{ \wedge } {_{m}} (\overline X {_{m}} - \overline {X_{f}} ) + \overline {X_{f} } (\mathop {b_{m} }\limits^{ \wedge } -\mathop {b_{f} }\limits^{ \wedge } ) $$
(11)

The overall earnings gap can thus be decomposed into two components: one attributed to differences in endowments of income-generating characteristics (Xm − Xf) evaluated using the male worker pay structure (bm); and the other attributed to differences in the returns (bm − bf) male and female workers receive for the same endowment of income-generating characteristics (X). This latter component is indicative of the extent of wage discrimination (Schultz 1991). This method, although illuminating––since it enables estimation of the extent of labour market discrimination––does not, however, identify the reasons for the discrimination.

Note that in the above decomposition model, the male coefficient vector is chosen as the reference structure against which the contribution of the differences in characteristics is evaluated. The female earnings structure could have been chosen as the reference structure and would have yielded an analogous decomposition

$$ Ln\overline {Y_{m} } - Ln\overline {Y_{f} } = \mathop{b}\limits^{ \wedge } {_{f}} (\overline X {_{m}} - \overline {X_{f}} ) + \overline {X_{m} } (\mathop {b_{m} }\limits^{ \wedge } -\mathop {b_{f} }\limits^{ \wedge } ) $$
(12)

The literature emphasises that there is no unambiguously best way to decide between the two alternative reference structures, which is really an index number problem.

Following Oaxaca and Ransom (1994), letting b* denote the estimated non-discriminatory earnings structure, the average earnings gap in logs can be rewritten as

$$ Ln\overline {Y_{m} } - Ln\overline {Y_{f} } = \mathop{b}\limits{{}}^*(\overline X {_{m}} - \overline {X_{f} } ) +\overline {X{_{m}} } (\mathop {b{_{m}} }\limits^{ \wedge } -\mathop {b^*}\limits^{{}} ) + \overline {X{_{f}} } (\mathop{b^*_{{}} }\limits^{{}} - \mathop {b{_{f}} }\limits^{ \wedge } )$$
(13)

where \( b^* = \Upomega \mathop b\limits^{ \wedge }{_{m}} + ({\rm I} -\Upomega )\mathop b\limits^{ \wedge }{{ _{f}}} \) is a weighted vector of the estimated vector of coefficients. The definition of the basic non-discriminatory earnings structure corresponds then to the choice of weighting matrix Ω. Several alternatives have been suggested in the literature. According to Oaxaca (1973), either the male earnings structure (Ω = I) or the female earnings structure (Ω = 0) could be used.

Cotton (1988) proposes the use of (Ω =  λ m I) where (λ m ) as the fraction of males in the sample. Neumark (1988) proposes an estimation of the non-discriminatory earnings structure on the basis of the pooled sample of males and females which implies that

$$ \Upomega = \left( {X^\prime X} \right)^{{ - 1}} \left( {X^\prime _{m} X_{m} } \right). $$

Although there are problems inherent in the methodology that may result in misleading results, here we use the more traditional parametric decomposition (see Dolton and Makepeace 1985; Oaxaca and Ransom 1994, 1999; Barsky et al. 2002 for more detail).

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

García-Aracil, A. College Major and the Gender Earnings Gap: A Multi-country Examination of Postgraduate Labour Market Outcomes. Res High Educ 49, 733–757 (2008). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11162-008-9102-y

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11162-008-9102-y

Keywords

Navigation