Skip to main content
Log in

Partially Ordered Sets and the Measurement of Multidimensional Ordinal Deprivation

  • Published:
Social Indicators Research Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

The paper presents a general framework and an operative procedure for the evaluation of multidimensional deprivation with ordinal attributes. Evaluation is addressed in terms of multidimensional comparisons among achievement profiles, rather than through attribute score aggregations. This makes it unnecessary to scale ordinal attributes into numerical variables, overcoming the limitations of aggregative procedures and counting approaches. The evaluation procedure is fuzzy in nature, accounts for both vagueness and intensity of deprivation and produces a comprehensive set of synthetic indicators for policy-makers.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4
Fig. 5
Fig. 6
Fig. 7
Fig. 8
Fig. 9

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. For the sake of simplicity, in the following elements of X partially ordered by \(\le\) will be referred directly as elements of P.

  2. We are assuming that deprivation attributes are measured in such a way that better achievements correspond to higher scores.

  3. We use the expression identification following Alkire and Foster (2011, 2011). While in their Counting Approach identification leads to a binary classification, here it has a fuzzy nature.

  4. In a linear order, there is no need to introduce the concept of complete deprivation, since there is no classification ambiguity.

  5. Linear extensions are graphs, so that graph distance applies. If \(\varvec{p}\) and \(\varvec{q}\) are elements of a linear extension \(\ell\), their distance is by definition the number of edges in the chain connecting them. More generally, the distance between a profile \(\varvec{p}\) and a subset of \(\ell\) is defined as the minimum of the distances between \(\varvec{p}\) and elements of the subset.

  6. The rank of a profile \(\varvec{p}\) in linear extension \(\ell\) is 1 plus the number of profiles below \(\varvec{p}\) in \(\ell\).

  7. The profiles it attains its minimum on, instead, depend upon the structure of the achievement poset and the choice of the threshold.

  8. It is easy to check that lexicographic linear orders over \(v_1,\ldots ,v_k\) are indeed linear extensions of \({\varPi }\).

  9. For example, consider that an antichain with n elements has n! linear extensions.

  10. Reported computations have been performed on an Intel® Core™2 Duo CPU E8400@3.00 GHz \(\times\) 2, RAM 1.9 GB, equipped with Linux 32 bit operative system.

References

  • Alkire, S., & Foster, J. (2011). Counting and multidimensional poverty measurement. Journal of Public Economics, 95(7–8), 476–487.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Alkire, S., & Foster, J. (2011). Understandings and misunderstandings of multidimensional poverty measurement. The Journal of Economic Inequality, 9(2), 289–314.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Annoni, P. (2007). Different ranking methods: Potentialities and pitfalls for the case of European opinion poll. Environmental and Ecological Statistics, 14, 453–471.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Annoni, P., & Bruggemann, R. (2009). Exploring partial order of European countries. Social Indicators Research, 92, 471–487.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Annoni, P., Fattore, M., & Bruggemann, R. (2011). A multi-criteria fuzzy approach for analyzing poverty structure. Statistica and Applicazioni, Special Issue, 7–30.

  • Arcagni, A., & Fattore, M. (2014). PARSEC: An R package for poset-based evaluation of multidimensional poverty. In R. Bruggemann, L. Carlsen, & J. Wittmann (Eds.), Multi-indicator systems and modelling in partial order. Berlin: Springer.

    Google Scholar 

  • Asselin, L.-M., & Anh, V. T. (2008). Multidimensional analysis and multiple correspondence analysis. In N. Kakwani & J. Silber (Eds.), Quantitative approaches to multidimensional poverty measurement. New York: Palgrave Macmillan.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bubley, R., & Dyer, M. (1999). Faster random generation of linear extensions. Discrete Mathematics, 201, 81–88.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bruggemann, R., Pudenz, S., Voigt, K., Kaune, A., & Kreimes, K. (1999). An algebraic/graphical tool to compare ecosystems with respect to their pollution. IV: Comparative regional analysis by Boolean arithmetics. Chemosphere, 38, 2263–2279.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bruggemann, R., & Patil, G. P. (2010). Multicriteria prioritization and partial order in environmental sciences. Environmental and Ecological Statistics, 17, 383–410.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bruggemann, R., & Patil, G. P. (2011). Ranking and prioritization for multi-indicator systems—Introduction to partial order applications. New York: Springer.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Bruggemann, R., & Voigt, K. (2012). Antichains in partial order, example: Pollution in a German region by lead, cadmium, zinc and sulfur in the herb layer. Match-Communications in Mathematical and Computer Chemistry, 67, 731–744.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bruggemann, R., & Carlsen, L. (2014). Incomparable-What now? Match-Communications in Mathematical and Computer Chemistry, 71, 699–714.

    Google Scholar 

  • Carlsen, L., & Bruggemann, R. (2014). The “Failed State Index”: Offers more than just a simple ranking. Social Indicators Research, 115, 525–530.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cerioli, A., & Zani, S. (1990). A fuzzy approach to the measurement of poverty. In C. Dagum & M. Zenga (Eds.), Income and wealth distribution, inequality and poverty. Berlin: Springer.

    Google Scholar 

  • Davey, B. A., & Priestley, B. H. (2002). Introduction to lattices and order. Cambridge: CUP.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • De Loof, K., De Baets, B., & De Meyer, H. (2006). Exploiting the lattice of ideals representation of a poset. Fundamenta Informaticae, 71(2–3), 309–321.

    Google Scholar 

  • De Loof, K., De Baets, B., & De Meyer, H. (2008). Properties of mutual rank probabilities in partially ordered sets. In J. W. Owsinski & R. Bruggemann (Eds.), Multicriteria ordering and ranking: Partial orders, ambiguities and applied issues. Warsaw: Polish Academy of Sciences.

    Google Scholar 

  • De Loof K. (2010). Efficient computation of rank probabilities in posets. Ph.D dissertation.

  • Fattore, M., Bruggemann, R., & Owsiński, J. (2011). Using poset theory to compare fuzzy multidimensional material deprivation across regions. In S. Ingrassia, R. Rocci, & M. Vichi (Eds.), New perspectives in statistical modeling and data analysis. Berlin: Springer.

    Google Scholar 

  • Fattore, M., Maggino, F., & Colombo, E. (2012). From composite indicators to partial order: evaluating socio-economic phenomena through ordinal data. In F. Maggino & G. Nuvolati (Eds.), Quality of life in Italy: Research and reflections., Social indicators research series 48 New York: Springer.

    Google Scholar 

  • Fattore, M., & Maggino, F. (2014). Partial orders in socio-economics: A practical challenge for poset theorists or a cultural challenge for social scientists? In R. Bruggemann, L. Carlsen, & J. Wittmann (Eds.), Multi-indicator systems and modelling in partial order. Berlin: Springer.

    Google Scholar 

  • Fattore, M. (2014). Partially ordered set. In A. C. Michalos (Ed.), Encyclopedia of quality of life and well-being research. Dordrecht: Springer.

    Google Scholar 

  • Fattore, M., & Maggino, F. (2015). A new method for measuring and analyzing suering Comparing suffering patterns in Italian society. In R. E. Anderson (Ed.), World Suering and the Quality of Life. New York: Springer.

    Google Scholar 

  • Freier, K. P., Bruggemann, R., Scheffran, J., Finckh, M., & Schneider, U. A. (2011). Assessing the predictability of future livelihood strategies of pastoralists in semi-arid Morocco under climate change. Technol. Forecasting Social Change, 79, 371–382.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kakwani, N., & Silber, J. (Eds.). (2008). Quantitative approaches to multidimensional poverty measurement. New York: Palgrave Macmillan.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lemmi, A., & Betti, G. (Eds.). (2006). Fuzzy set approach to multidimensional poverty measurement. New York: Springer.

    Google Scholar 

  • Madden, D. (2010). Ordinal and cardinal measures of health inequality: An empirical comparison. Health Economics, 19, 243–250.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Neggers, J., & Kim, S. H. (1998). Basic posets. Singapore: World Scientific.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Patil, G. P., & Taillie, C. (2004). Multiple indicators, partially ordered sets, and linear extensions: Multi-criterion ranking and prioritization. Environmental and Ecological Statistics, 11, 199–228.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Qizilbash, M. (2006). Philosophical accounts of vagueness, fuzzy poverty measures and multidimensionality. In A. Lemmi & G. Betti (Eds.), Fuzzy set approach to multidimensional poverty measurement. New York: Springer.

    Google Scholar 

  • R Core Team (2012). R: A language and environment for statistical computing, R Foundation for Statistical Computing, Vienna, Austria, http://www.R-project.org/.

  • Schroeder, B. S. W. (2002). Ordered set. An introduction. Boston: Birkäuser.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sen, A. (1992). Inequality reexamined. Cambridge: Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Marco Fattore.

Appendix

Appendix

In this appendix we prove that lexicographic linear extensions generate the basic achievement poset.

Proposition 2

The intersection of lexicographic linear extensions of \({\varPi }\)  equals \({\varPi }\), i.e.:

$${\varPi }=\bigcap Lex({\varPi }).$$
(14)

Proof

From \(Lex({\varPi })\subseteq {\varOmega }({\varPi })\), it follows \({\varPi }=\cap {\varOmega }({\varPi }) \subseteq \cap Lex({\varPi })\), so it is sufficient to prove the opposite inclusion. Since lexicographic linear extensions are indeed extensions of \({\varPi }\), this is equivalent to prove that if \(\varvec{p}\) and \(\varvec{q}\) are incomparable in \({\varPi }\), they are also incomparable in \(\cap Lex({\varPi })\). To show this, notice that if \(\varvec{p},\varvec{q}\in {\varPi }\) are incomparable, then they have at least two conflicting scores. Without loss of generality, suppose that \(p_i<q_i\) and \(q_j<p_j\). Then necessarily \(\varvec{p}\) is ranked below \(\varvec{q}\) in linear extensions lexicographically ordered with \(v_j\, \trianglelefteq_{{\varLambda }} v_i\); viceversa, \(\varvec{p}\) is ranked above \(\varvec{q}\) when in the corresponding attribute rankings \(v_i\trianglelefteq_{{\varLambda }} v_j\). Therefore \(\varvec{p}\) and \(\varvec{q}\) are incomparable in the intersection of lexicographic linear extensions. \(\square\)

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Fattore, M. Partially Ordered Sets and the Measurement of Multidimensional Ordinal Deprivation. Soc Indic Res 128, 835–858 (2016). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11205-015-1059-6

Download citation

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11205-015-1059-6

Keywords

Navigation