Skip to main content
Log in

Engineering Human Cooperation

Does Involuntary Neural Activation Increase Public Goods Contributions?

  • Published:
Human Nature Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

In a laboratory experiment, we use a public goods game to examine the hypothesis that human subjects use an involuntary eye-detector mechanism for evaluating the level of privacy. Half of our subjects are “watched” by images of a robot presented on their computer screen. The robot—named Kismet and invented at MIT—is constructed from objects that are obviously not human with the exception of its eyes. In our experiment, Kismet produces a significant difference in behavior that is not consistent with existing economic models of preferences, either self- or other-regarding. Subjects who are “watched” by Kismet contribute 29% more to the public good than do subjects in the same setting without Kismet.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Institutional subscriptions

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4

Similar content being viewed by others

References

  • Andreoni, J., & Petrie, R. (2004). Public goods experiment without confidentiality: A glimpse into fund-raising. Journal of Public Economics, 88, 1605–1623.

    Google Scholar 

  • Barkow, J. H., Cosmides, L., & Tooby, J. (1992). The Adapted Mind: Evolutionary Psychology and the Generation of Culture. New York: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Baron-Cohen, S. (1995). Mindblindness: An Essay on autism and theory of mind. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Baron-Cohen, S., Campbell, R., Karmiloff-Smith, A., Grant, J., & Walker, J. (1995). Are children with autism blind to the mentalistic significance of the eyes? British Journal of Developmental Psychology, 13, 379–398.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bateson, M., Nettle, D., & Roberts, G. (2006). Cues of being watched enhance cooperation in a real world setting. Biology Letters, 2, 412–414. Retrieved from www.journals.royalsoc.ac.uk.

    Google Scholar 

  • Berg, J., Dickhaut, J., & McCabe, K. (1995). Trust, reciprocity, and social history. Games and Economic Behavior, 10, 122–142.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bolton, G. (1991). A comparative model of bargaining: theory and evidence. American Economic Review, 81, 1096–1136.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bolton, G., & Ockenfels, A. (2000). ERC: A theory of equity, reciprocity and competition. American Economic Review, 90, 166–193.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bolton, G., & Zwick, R. (1995). Anonymity versus punishment in ultimatum bargaining. Games and Economic Behavior, 10, 95–121.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bowlby, J. (1969). Attachment and loss. vol. I: Attachment. New York: Basic Books.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bowlby, J. (1973). Attachment and loss, vol. II: Separation, anxiety, and anger. New York: Basic Books.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bowles, S., & Gintis, H. (2002). Homo reciprocans. Nature, 415, 125–126.

    Google Scholar 

  • Boyd, R., Gintis, H., Bowles, S., & Richerson, P. J. (2003). The evolution of altruistic punishment. Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences, 100, 3531–3535.

    Google Scholar 

  • Breazeal, C. (2003). Emotion and sociable humanoid robots. International Journal of Human–Computer Studies, 59, 119–155.

    Google Scholar 

  • Breazeal, C., & Scassellati, B. (2002). Robots that imitate humans. Trends in Cognitive Science, 6, 481–487.

    Google Scholar 

  • Brothers, L. (1990). The neural basis of primate social communication. Motivation & Emotion, 14, 81–91.

    Google Scholar 

  • Brothers, L. (1996). Brain mechanisms of social cognition. Journal of Psychopharmacology, 10, 2–8.

    Google Scholar 

  • Brothers, L., Ring, B., & Kling, A. (1990). Response of neurons in the macaque amygdala to complex social stimuli. Behavioural Brain Research, 41, 199–213.

    Google Scholar 

  • Burnham, T. C. (1997). Essays on genetic evolution and economics. Parkland, FL. Retrieved from www.dissertation.com.

  • Burnham, T. C. (2001). Altruism and spite in a selfish gene model of endogenous preferences. Journal of BioEconomics, 3, 123–148.

    Google Scholar 

  • Burnham, T. C. (2003). Engineering altruism: A theoretical and experimental investigation of anonymity and gift giving. Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, 50, 133–144.

    Google Scholar 

  • Burnham, T. C. (2007). High-testosterone men reject low ultimatum game offers. Proceedings of the Royal Society B, Biological Sciences (in press).

  • Burnham, T. C., & Johnson, D. (2005). The biological and evolutionary logic of human cooperation. Analyse & Kritik, 27(2), 113–135.

    Google Scholar 

  • Burnham, T. C., McCabe, K., & Smith, V. L. (2000). Friend-or-Foe priming in an extensive form trust game. Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, 43, 57–73.

    Google Scholar 

  • Byrne, R. W., & Whiten, A. (1988). Machiavellian intelligence: Social expertise and the evolution of intellect in monkeys, apes, and humans. Oxford: Clarendon.

    Google Scholar 

  • Call, J., Brauer, J., Kaminski, J., Tomasello, M. (2003). Domestic dogs (Canis familiaris) are sensitive to the attentional state of humans. Journal of Comparative Psychology, 117, 257–263.

    Google Scholar 

  • Camerer, C. (2003). Strategizing in the brain. Science, 300, 1673–1675.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cameron, L. (1999). Raising the Stakes in the ultimatum game: Experimental evidence from Indonesia. Economic Inquiry, 37, 47–59.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Campbell, R., Heywood, C. A., Cowey, A., Regard, M., & Landis, T. (1990). Sensitivity to eye gaze in prosopagnosic patients and monkeys with superior temporal sulcus ablation. Neuropsychologia, 28, 1123–1142.

    Google Scholar 

  • Chagnon, N. (1992). Yanomamo, 4th ed. New York: Harcourt Brace Jovanovich.

    Google Scholar 

  • Corballis, M. C., & Lea, S. E. G. (1999). The descent of mind: Psychological perspectives on hominid evolution. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Corkum, V., & Moore, C. (1995). Development of joint visual attention in infants. In C. Moore, & P. Dunham (Eds.) Joint attention: Its origins and role in development (pp. 61–83). Hillsdale, NJ: Lawrence Erlbaum Associates.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cosmides, L., & Tooby, J. (1992). Cognitive adaptations for social exchange. In J. H. Barkow, L. Cosmides, & J. Tooby (Eds.), The adapted mind: Evolutionary psychology and the generation of culture (pp. 163–228). New York: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Coss, R. G. (1978). Delayed plasticity of an instinct: Recognition and avoidance of 2 facing eyes by the jewel fish. Developmental Psychobiology, 12, 335–345.

    Google Scholar 

  • Damasio, A. D., Damasio, H., & Van Hoesen, G. W. (1982). Prosopagnosia: Anatomic basis and behavioral mechanisms. Neurology, 32, 331–342.

    Google Scholar 

  • Dawes, R., & Thaler, R. (1988). Cooperation. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 2, 187–197.

    Google Scholar 

  • Dawkins, R. (1976). The selfish gene. New York: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Driver, J., Davis, G., Ricciardelli, P., Kidd, P., Maxwell, E., & Baron-Cohen, S. (1999). Gaze perception triggers reflexive visuospatial orienting. Visual Cognition, 6, 509–540.

    Google Scholar 

  • Eckel, C., & Grossman, P. (1996). Altruism in anonymous dictator games. Games and Economic Behavior, 16, 181–191.

    Google Scholar 

  • Emery, N. J. (2000). The eyes have it: The neuroethology, function and evolution of social gaze. Neuroscience and Biobehavioral Reviews, 24, 581–604.

    Google Scholar 

  • Fehr, E., & Fischbacher, U. (2003). The nature of altruism. Nature, 425, 785–791.

    Google Scholar 

  • Fehr, E., & Gächter, S. (2002). Altruistic punishment in humans. Nature, 415, 137–140.

    Google Scholar 

  • Fehr, E., & Henrich, J. (2003). Is strong reciprocity a maladaptation? On the evolutionary foundations of human altruism. In: P. Hammerstein (Ed.), The genetical and cultural evolution of cooperation (pp. 55–82). Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Fehr, E., & Rockenbach, B. (2003). Detrimental effects of sanctions on human altruism. Nature, 422, 137–140.

    Google Scholar 

  • Fehr, E., & Schmidt, K. (1999). A theory of fairness, competition, and cooperation. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 114, 817–868.

    Google Scholar 

  • Fehr, E., Fischbacher, U., & Gächter, S. (2002). Strong reciprocity, human cooperation and the enforcement of social norms. Human Nature, 13, 1–25.

    Google Scholar 

  • Forsythe, R., Horowitz, J. L., Savin, N. E., & Sefton, M. (1994). Fairness in simple bargaining experiments. Games and Economic Behavior, 6, 347–369.

    Google Scholar 

  • Frank, R. H. (1987). If Homo economicus could choose his own utility function, would he want one with a conscience? American Economic Review, 77, 593–604.

    Google Scholar 

  • Frank, R. H. (1988). Passions within reason: The strategic role of emotions. New York: Norton.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gächter, S., & Fehr, E. (1999). Collective action as a social exchange. Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, 39, 341–369.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gallup, G., Wallnau, L., & Suarez, S. (1980). Failure to find self-recognition in mother–infant and infant–infant rhesus monkey pairs. Folia Primatologica, 33, 210–219.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gintis, H. (2000). Strong reciprocity and human sociality. Journal of Theoretical Biology, 206, 169–179.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gintis, H., Bowles, S., Boyd, R., & Fehr, E. (2003). Explaining altruistic behavior in humans. Evolution and Human Behavior, 24, 153–172.

    Google Scholar 

  • Guth, W., & Tietz, R. (1990). Ultimatum bargaining behavior: A survey and comparison of experimental results. Journal of Economic Psychology, 11, 417–449.

    Google Scholar 

  • Guth, W., Schmittberger, R., & Schwarze, B. (1982). An experimental analysis of ultimatum bargaining. Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, 3, 367–388.

    Google Scholar 

  • Haley, K., & Fessler, D. (2005). Nobody’s watching? Subtle cues affect generosity in an anonymous economic game. Evolution and Human Behavior, 26, 245–256.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hampton, R. R. (1994). Sensitivity to information specifying the line of gaze of humans in sparrows (Passer domesticus). Behaviour, 130, 41–51.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hare, B., Brown, M., Williamson, C., & Tomasello, M. (2002). The domestication of social cognition in dogs. Science, 298, 1634–1636.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hare, B., Call, J., Tomasello, M. (2001). Do chimpanzees know what conspecifics know? Animal Behaviour, 61, 139–151.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hare, B., Call, J., & Tomasello, M. (2006). Chimpanzees deceive a human by hiding. Cognition, 101, 495–514.

    Google Scholar 

  • Haxby, J. V., Hoffman, E. A., & Gobbini, I. (2000). The distributed human neural system for face perception. Trends in Cognitive Science, 4, 223–233.

    Google Scholar 

  • Henrich, J. (2000). Does culture matter in economic behavior? Ultimatum game bargaining among the machiguenga of the Peruvian Amazon. American Economic Review, 90, 973–979.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Henrich, J., Boyd, R., Bowles, S., Camerer, C., Fehr, E., Gintis, H., et al. (2001). In search of Homo economicus: Behavioral experiments in 15 small-scale societies. American Economic Review, 91, 73–78.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Heywood, C. A., & Cowey, A. (1992). The role of the “face-cell” area in the discrimination and recognition of faces by monkeys. Philosophical Transactions of the Royal Society of London B: Biological Sciences, 335, 31–38.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hill, K., & Hurtado, M. (1996) Ache life history: The ecology and demography of a foraging people. New York: Aline de Gruyter.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hoffman, E. A., & Haxby, J. V. (2000). Distinct representations of eye gaze and identity in the distributed human neural system for face perception. Nature Neuroscience, 3, 80–84.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hoffman, E., McCabe, K., Shachat, K., & Smith, V. (1994). Preferences, property rights, and anonymity in bargaining games. Games and Economic Behavior, 7, 346–380.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hoffman, E., McCabe, K., & Smith, V. (1996a). Social distance and other-regarding behavior in dictator games. American Economic Review, 86, 653–660.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hoffman, E., McCabe, K., & Smith, V. L. (1996b). On expectations and the monetary stakes in ultimatum games. International Journal of Game Theory, 25, 289–301.

    Google Scholar 

  • Jerison, H. (1973). Evolution of the brain and intelligence. New York: Academic Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kahneman, D. (2003). A psychological perspective on economics. American Economic Review, 93, 162–168.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kahneman, D., & Tversky, A. (1984). Choices, values, and frames. American Psychologist, 39, 341–350.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kahneman, D., Knetsch, J., & Thaler, R. (1986). Fairness and the assumptions of economics. Journal of Business, 59, S285–S300.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kawashima, R., Sugiura, M., Kato, T., Nakamura, A., Hatano, K., Ito, K., et al. (1999). The human amygdala plays an important role in gaze monitoring. A PET study. Brain, 122, 779–783.

    Google Scholar 

  • Klein, R. (1999). The human career: Human biological and cultural origins. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Krebs, J. R., & Dawkins, R. (1984). Animal signals: Mind reading and manipulation. In J. R. Krebs, & N. B. Davies (Eds.), Behavioural ecology: An evolutionary approach, 2nd ed. (pp. 380–402). Oxford: Blackwell.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kurzban, R. (2001). The social psychophysics of cooperation: Nonverbal communication in a public goods game. Journal of Nonverbal Behavior, 25, 241–259.

    Google Scholar 

  • Landis, T., Cummings, J. L., Christen, L., Bogen, J. E., & Imhof, H. G. (1986). Are unilateral right posterior cerebral lesions sufficient to cause prosopagnosia? Clinical and radiological findings in six additional patients. Cortex, 22, 243–252.

    Google Scholar 

  • Laury, S. J., Walker, J. M., & Williams, A. W. (1995). Anonymity and voluntary provision of public goods. Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, 27, 365–380.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ledyard, J. O. (1995). Public goods. In J. H. Kagel, & A. E. Roth, (Eds.), Handbook of experimental economics (pp. 111–194). Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lee, R. (1993). The Dobe Júhoansi. New York: Harcourt Brace.

    Google Scholar 

  • Levine, D. (1998). Modeling altruism and spitefulness in experiments. Review of Economic Dynamics, 1, 593–622.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mayr, E. (1961). Cause and effect in biology. Science, 134, 1501–1506.

    Google Scholar 

  • McCabe, K. (2003). A cognitive theory of reciprocal exchange. In E. Ostrom, J. Walker (Eds.), Trust and reciprocity: Interdisciplinary lessons from experimental research (pp. 147–169). New York: Sage.

    Google Scholar 

  • McCabe, K., Houser, D., Ryan, L., Smith, V., & Trouard, T. (2001). A functional imaging study of cooperation in two-person reciprocal exchange. Proceedings of the National Academy of Science, 98, 11832–11835.

    Google Scholar 

  • McCabe, K. A., Rassenti, S. J., & Smith, V. L. (1996). Game theory and reciprocity in some extensive form experimental games. Proceedings of the National Academy of Science, 93, 113421–113428.

    Google Scholar 

  • McCabe, K., & Smith, V. L. (2001). Goodwill accounting in economic exchange. In G. Gigerenzer, & R. Selten (Eds.), Bounded rationality: The adaptive toolbox (pp. 319–340). Cambridge: MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • McCabe, K. A., Smith, V. L., & LePore, M. (1997). Intentionality detection and “Mindreading”: Why does game form matter? Proceedings of the National Academy of Science, 97, 4404–4409.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mistlin, A. J., & Perrett, D. I. (1990). Visual and somatosensory processing in the macaque temporal cortex: The role of “Expectation.” Experimental Brain Research, 82, 437–450.

    Google Scholar 

  • Nowak, M. A., Page, K. M., & Sigmund, K. (2000). Fairness versus reason in the ultimatum bargaining game. Science, 289, 1773–1775.

    Google Scholar 

  • Perrett, D. I., Rolls, E. T., & Caan, W. (1982). Visual neurones responsive to faces in the monkey temporal cortex. Experimental Brain Research, 47, 329–342.

    Google Scholar 

  • Perrett, D. I., Smith, P. A. J., Potter, D. D., Mistlin, A. J., Head, A. S., Milner, A. D., et al. (1985). Visual cells in the temporal cortex sensitive to face view and gaze direction. Proceedings of the Royal Society of London B: Biological Sciences, 223, 293–317.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pickens, R., & Harris, W. C. (1968). Self-administration of d-amphetamine by rats. Psychopharmacologia, 12, 158–163.

    Google Scholar 

  • Povinelli, D. (2000). Folk physics for apes. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Puce, A., Allison, T., Bentin, S., Gore, J. C., & McCarthy, G. (1998). Temporal cortex activation in humans viewing eye and mouth movements. Journal of Neuroscience, 18, 2188–2199.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rabin, M. (1993). Incorporating fairness into game theory and econometrics. American Economic Review, 83, 1281–1303.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rege, M., & Telle, K. (2004). The impact of social approval and framing on cooperation in public good situations. Journal of Public Economics, 88, 1625–1644.

    Google Scholar 

  • Renfrew, C., & Bahn, C. (1991). Archeology: Theories, methods, and practice. London: Thames and Hudson.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rilling, J. K., Gutman, D., Zeh, T., Pagnoni, G., Berns, G., & Kilts, C. (2002). A neural basis for social cooperation. Neuron, 35, 395–405.

    Google Scholar 

  • Roth, A. E., Prasnikar, V., Okuno-Fujiwara, M., & Zamir, S. (1991). Bargaining and market behavior in Jerusalem, Ljubljana, Pittsburgh, and Tokyo: An experimental study. American Economic Review, 81, 1068–1095.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sanfey, A. G., Rilling, J. K., Aronson, J. A., Nystrom, L. E., & Cohen, J. D. (2003). The neural basis of economic decision-making in the ultimatum game. Science, 300, 1755–1758.

    Google Scholar 

  • Schelling, T. (1978). Altruism, meanness and other potentially strategic behaviors. American Economic Review, 68, 229–230.

    Google Scholar 

  • Silk, J. (2003). Social bonds of female baboons enhance infant survival. Science, 302, 1231–1234.

    Google Scholar 

  • Smith, K., Dickhaut, J., McCabe, K., & Pardo, J. V. (2002). Neuronal substrates for choice under ambiguity, risk, gains and losses. Management Science, 48, 711–718.

    Google Scholar 

  • Smith, K., Dickhaut, J., McCabe, K., & Pardo, J. V. (2003). The impact of the certainty context on the process of choice. Proceedings of the National Academy of Science, 100, 3536–3541.

    Google Scholar 

  • Stahl, I. (1972). Bargaining theory. Stockholm: Economic Research Institute.

    Google Scholar 

  • Stroop, J. R. (1935) Studies of interference in serial verbal reactions. Journal of Experimental Psychology, 18, 643–662.

    Google Scholar 

  • Thaler, R. H. (1992). The Winner’s curse: Paradoxes and anomalies of economic life. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tinbergen, N. (1963). On aims and methods in ethology. Zeitschrift für Tierpsychologie, 20, 410–433.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tinbergen, N. (1968) On war and peace in animals and man. An ethologist’s approach to the biology of aggression. Science, 160, 1411–1418.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tomasello, M. (2000). The cultural origins of human cognition. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tomasello, M., Call, J., & Hare, B. (1998). Five primate species follow the visual gaze of conspecifics. Animal Behaviour, 55, 1063–1069.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tooby, J., & Cosmides, L. (1989). Evolutionary psychology and the generation of culture, I: Theoretical considerations. Ethology & Sociobiology, 10, 29–49.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tooby, J., & Cosmides, L. (1990). The past explains the present: Emotional adaptations and the structure of ancestral environments. Ethology & Sociobiology, 11, 375–424.

    Google Scholar 

  • Weeks, J. R. (1962). Experimental morphine addiction: Method for automatic intravenous injections in unrestrained rats. Science, 138, 143–144.

    Google Scholar 

  • Wilson, E. O. (1975). Sociobiology: The new synthesis. Cambridge, MA: Belknap Press of Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Wilson, E. O. (1978). On human nature. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Wilson, E. O. (1998). Consilience. New York: Knopf.

    Google Scholar 

  • Winston, J. S., Strange, B. A., O’Doherty, J., & Dolan, R. J. (2002). Automatic and intentional brain responses during evaluation of trustworthiness of faces. Nature Neuroscience, 5, 277–283.

    Google Scholar 

  • Yamagishi, T. (1986). The provision of a sanctioning system as a public good. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, 51, 110–116.

    Google Scholar 

  • Yamane, S., Kaji, S., & Kawano, K. (1988). What facial features activate face neurons in the inferotemporal cortex of the monkey? Experimental Brain Research, 73, 209–214.

    Google Scholar 

  • Young, A. W., Aggleton, J. P., Hellawell, D. J., Johnson, M., Broks, P., & Hanley, J. R. (1995). Face processing impairments after amygdalotomy. Brain, 118, 15–24.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

Brian Hare’s research is supported by a Sofja Kovalevskaja award received from The Alexander von Humboldt Foundation and the German Federal Ministry for Education and Research. In implementing and running the experiment, we benefited from the excellent work of the staff of the HBS experimental laboratory, including Steve Oliveira, Nick McKinney, Alyssa Knotts, Jill Hogue, and Toni Wegner. We appreciate the help and/or comments of Ernst Fehr, Urs Fishbacher, Simon Gächter, Kevin McCabe, Keith Murgnihan, Al Roth, and Lise Vesterlund. The paper was improved by comments from Steve Platek and two anonymous referees.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Terence C. Burnham.

Appendix

Appendix

Instructions

Welcome!

This is an experiment about decision-making. There are other people in this room who are also participating in this experiment. You must not talk to them or communicate with them in any way until the experiment is over. The experiment will take about an hour and a half, and at the end you will be paid in private and in cash. The amount of money you will earn depends on the decisions that you and the other participants make.

In this experiment you will perform a decision task six times. We refer to each decision task as a round. In each round you will be in a group with three other people, but you will not know which of the other people in this room are in your group. The decisions made by you and the three other people in your group will determine how much you earn.

Each round you will be matched with three new group members. You will never be matched with the same person more than once.

You have been paid $10 to show up today. In addition to your show-up fee, you will earn money in each round. Your total earnings for the experiment today will be the show-up fee plus the sum of what you earn in all six rounds.

In each round you will have ten tokens, which you can place in your private account or in a shared group account. The other members of your group will also have ten tokens each and can place them in either their own private account or the shared group account. Your earnings depend on how much you keep in your private account and the total amount placed in the group account by you and the other three members of your group.

You will be paid based on the number of tokens that you collect throughout the experiment. Each token that you earn will convert to $0.20 to be paid in cash at the end of the experiment.

In each round you decide how many of your ten tokens to keep in your private account and how many to place in the group account. You will retain each token that you keep in your private account. Each token that you place in the group account will be doubled and then divided equally among the four members of the group. Likewise, each of the three other members of your group will decide on dividing their tokens between their own private account and the group account.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Burnham, T.C., Hare, B. Engineering Human Cooperation. Hum Nat 18, 88–108 (2007). https://doi.org/10.1007/s12110-007-9012-2

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s12110-007-9012-2

Keywords

Navigation