In recent years, the consumer market has been transitioning to an era of sustainable development. Many corporations have come to realize that they are part of a larger entity and must help protect the common good [71]. For instance, General Electric has introduced a credit card to help consumers earn greenhouse gas emissions credits to reduce their personal carbon footprint [7], and Wal-Mart has initiated a Sustainability Index Consortium [83]. In fact, a new job category, professional pollution calculator, has emerged [84].

These are just a few examples of the advent of sustainable development, an emerging mainstream concept. They are representative of a larger trend of internal and external forces forcing social change by firms. Illustrating this trend, 45 of the 50 largest US companies included sustainability efforts in their 2008 annual reports or on their websites. The increasing concern with sustainability is not unwarranted; as the world’s population has surpassed 7 billion, sustainability is justifiably of concern [25].

Sustainable development is defined as “development that meets the needs of the present without compromising the ability of future generations to meet their own needs”Footnote 1 ([85] S3, A27, p. 16). Surprisingly, of corporate social responsibility (CSR) articles in the leading marketing journalsFootnote 2 from 2000 to 2013, only three mentioned sustainability. MacCannell [51] questioned whether ego-based consumption was sustainable and [87] examined consumers’ choice of green products based on their attributes. We seek to stimulate attention to sustainability in the marketing literature by providing guidelines that can help to focus future research in this important area. Thus, we argue that it is crucial to study sustainability in a measurable form.

One effective way to quantitatively convey a firm’s level of sustainability is through a carbon footprint label. A product’s carbon footprint represents the increase in carbon dioxide in the atmosphere resulting from the manufacture, transportation, usage, and disposal of that product. A smaller carbon footprint means a smaller increase in carbon dioxide and a lesser degree of harmful impact on the earth’s sustainability. Consumers, in addition to firms, are increasingly familiar with the term “carbon footprint” through extended news coverage of climate change, multi-national treaties, and green investment [61].

Carbon footprint labeling is an efficient means for consumers to recognize the sustainability of a firm’s products or services, and to compare them with those of other firms and their own preferences. Thus, how consumers and firms will be affected by the introduction of a universal carbon footprint label merits careful study. Similarly, a firm’s attributes, industry, customer base, and carbon footprint label details are factors that would potentially impact a firm’s reputation and financial outcomes. Research may reveal surprising or counterintuitive findings. For a parallel, consider nutritional information labels. Ippolito and Mathios [38] find that the advent of labels detailing food fat content coincided with reductions in fat consumption. Applying this outcome to carbon emissions suggests that carbon footprint labeling could increase consumers’ level of attention to carbon emissions levels, potentially affecting their purchase decisions resulting in purchase of fewer product or products with lower carbon emission levels.

Specifically, in this paper we derive predictions regarding how consumers may respond to sustainability activities undertaken by firms. We base our propositions on the assumption that through a combination of industry adoption and government regulation and enforcement, carbon footprint labeling will become widespread and familiar to the average consumer in the near future. In Fig. 1, we provide a framework for our discussion. This research roadmap is based upon examination of related research in marketing, related business fields, news media, and websites of companies and carbon footprint organizations.

Fig. 1
figure 1

Proposal framework

1 Background

1.1 Carbon Footprint Labeling

Until recently, carbon emissions were measured only at the national or firm level, which does not aid consumers in monitoring their personal carbon emissions levels. A carbon footprint label seeks to detail the emissions in the four stages of a product’s lifetime, manufacture, transportation, usage, and disposal [15]. Because creating products with zero carbon emissions is often not possible, firms may offset some of their carbon emissions through means such as carbon sinksFootnote 3 or living machinesFootnote 4 and report these on the label.

A carbon footprint label provides a comparison metric for consumers to consider a product’s carbon emissions when making purchasing decisions. As yet, there is no universally agreed upon label. In order to facilitate our discussion, we present a hypothetical carbon footprint label that includes various carbon emissions and offsets from current and proposed systems. The label is adapted from existing labels (see the on-line appendix for all labels).

This illustrative label presents a product’s carbon footprint using a single metric (e.g., grams) to provide common measurement for manufacturers and consumers. Carbon emission is displayed for each of the four product life cycle stages, the sum of the four stages, offsets (recycling, carbon sinks), the sum of the offsets, and net emissions (total carbon emission less total offsets). Emission data with different aggregate levels should assist those consumers who desire more detailed information, but mitigate information overload for those who do not. To facilitate consumer interpretation, we add an icon system so that consumers can compare carbon footprints across similar products. These footprint icons are scaled from 0 to 4, incrementing in half footprints. Fewer footprint icons indicate a smaller footprint and a one word assessment (e.g., poor, average, or good) accompanies the icons. Comparison across products is useful because it facilitates consumer juxtaposition among goods with similar labels (e.g., nutritional data) [57].

Products vary in how the different stages of their life cycle contribute to their carbon footprint levels. A lawnmower’s greatest carbon footprint impact is its gas emissions during usage. Bottled water has a high carbon footprint in the transportation stage because it is bulky and expensive to transport. Beef requires considerable resources to manufacture (to be raised to maturity). Finally, a television has high levels in each stage; high weight impacts transportation, a multi-year consumption of electricity impacts usage, and with few recyclable components, and hazardous materials that impact disposal.

1.2 Current State of Sustainability and Carbon Footprint Labeling

Consumer advocacy for sustainability and the ability to choose products based on their carbon footprint, is emerging already [37]. In response, a number of corporate, non-profit, and government entities have begun to address this issue (e.g., [16]). Similarly, several companies, including I.B.M., Nike, Coca-Cola, Google, and Dell, are investigating ways to reduce their carbon footprint and have joined forces to create a common carbon footprint label. Sapporo displays carbon emissions per can of beer from growing the ingredients, brewing them, manufacturing the can, and transporting it to distributors. Quaker Oats has shown carbon usage in cooking usage [79].

Groundwork for carbon footprint labeling arises from a combination of social trends, legislation, and product innovations. Fuel economy levels for cars are mandated. Recycling of plastic, metals, paper, and food products is now widespread. Energy efficient appliances are common, often qualifying for government rebates. Companies manufacture and distribute products with less packaging. Firms are cutting green-house gases used in manufacture and transportation; Empty Miles, for example, aims to reduce the miles that trucks travel empty [60]. In summary, technology, consumer demand, firm willingness, and government legislation will make carbon emission labeling a likelihood in the near future. This outcome increases the importance of understanding what leads firms and consumers to use carbon footprint labels.

2 Proposition Development

2.1 Industry Characteristics

Industry characteristics will affect firms’ implementation of carbon footprint labeling, consumer responses to this labeling, and its financial outcomes. Banerjee et al [6] propose four industry level attributes that together define the natural business environment. We discuss two in this section: regulation (of carbon footprint labeling) and industry complexity as measured by concentration. A third, public concern, is discussed in a later section. Finally, we consider the fourth, managerial commitment, to be self-evident; increased managerial commitment will reduce carbon footprint levels.

To noticeably affect consumer behavior and industry practice, carbon footprint labeling should have what Kirmani and Rao [40] call the attributes of a strong signal. That is, the labeling should be salient, reduce information asymmetry between firms and their customers, and provide information clarity, payoff transparency, and credibility. Carbon footprint labels must be reliable and there should be negative consequences (e.g., fines) for their misuse. Industry standards usually lack an enforcement mechanism, which might compromise consumer faith in such a system [17]. In contrast, governmental regulation of carbon footprint labeling would have the authority to dictate uniformity and specificity across industries, states, and perhaps national borders [45]. As a result, consumers would be able to rely on clear, honest, and standardized criteria to verify manufacturer claims and make product comparisons and purchases [47]. The increased understanding, verifiability [43], and elimination of consumer confusion resulting from nutritional labeling was one of the primary impetuses for that legislation [26].

Existing labeling efforts suggest that voluntary industry labeling does not always produce the desired result for consumers. For example, organic labeling has minimal existing regulation associated with it, and critics argue that it misleads and confuses consumers and hampers interstate commerce [1]. Such controversies damage industry-led programs’ credibility. The food industry-sponsored Smart Choice program that qualified Froot Loops, Cocoa Krispies, and Fudgsicle bars as “Smart Choices” drew the ire of the FDA [59]. Campbell [13] summarizes: “research suggests that government statutes are most effective in facilitating socially responsible corporate environmental behavior.” Thus:

Proposition 1

Consumers will have more trust in a governmentally regulated carbon emission label than a voluntary industry-led one.

Note that mandating carbon emission labeling does not mandate specific goals for carbon levels, just that levels be reported. Thus, firms will be free to decide how much to reduce carbon emissions, but this transparency provided by carbon emission reporting will influence competitors’ emissions. Thus, the level of industry competition may affect how much firms decrease their carbon emissions. Firms in more concentrated industries typically face lower levels of competition, and, when competition is present, it is likely to be less intense than in less concentrated industries (e.g., [76]). As competition increases, firms often must differentiate themselves and provide more choice for consumers (e.g., [22]). One method of differentiation may relate to carbon footprints. As competition increases, firms may expend more resources on carbon emission reduction activities to differentiate themselves. Once one firm in an industry differentiates itself by lowering its carbon footprint, other firms may feel compelled to match that level to counteract the original firm, thereby leading to a beneficial cycle of carbon emission reduction.

However, the decrease in carbon emissions as industry competition increases may not continue; competition may force firms to invest in responding to more pressing issues, such as customer satisfaction or firm efficiency. On the other hand, a less concentrated industry may comprise many small firms. While small firms may be more nimble than larger firms, they also have less slack resources [19]. Reducing carbon emissions to low levels requires access to slack resources. Thus firms in more highly concentrated industries may not have a need to reduce emissions whereas firms in less concentrated industries may not have the necessary resources to reduce emissions.

Proposition 2

Industry concentration will have an inverted U-shaped effect on the level of carbon emissions; firms in moderately concentrated industries will have less carbon emissions than firms in either low or high concentration industries.

2.2 Firm Characteristics

Firm-specific characteristics should affect carbon emissions. We focus on three firm characteristics relevant to sustainability: a firm’s level of innovation, the level of consumer influence on a firm, and a firm’s diversification through product portfolio breadth and geographic expansion. Carbon emission reduction requires technological innovation and consumer demand to become important. Firms, through their product breadth and market width, can affect its level and rate of reduction.

Innovation long has been considered a major function of a firm and a source of value creation [74]. It improves firm performance and lowers firm risk by facilitating the creation of competitive advantage through firm and product differentiation (e.g., [53]). Innovative firms are responsive to markets and customer needs [55] and thus should recognize the need to reduce emission levels. Firms with an innovative culture should be able to harness and direct this energy [41] toward lowering emission levels. In turn, a firm’s brand equity may be improved through emissions reductions; consumers may feel that they are supporting an environmental cause by purchasing the product. Research indicates that CSR helps to create a reputation for reliability and honesty [53] and to increasing stakeholder perceptions of and identification with a firm [11]. Further, CSR also reduces firm risk [49], and we anticipate similar effects with carbon footprint labeling.

Empirical evidence suggests that firms benefit financially through the interaction of high levels of innovation, CSR, and customer satisfaction. The financial benefits of coupling high levels of customer satisfaction or CSR with high levels of innovation can occur indirectly through enhanced perceptions of firms [11], or directly by increasing Tobin’s q and stock return [50]. Thus:

Proposition 3

Firm technological innovation and carbon emission level will interact to affect firm performance; high innovation firms with low emissions will have higher financial performance and less financial risk than others.

Arora and Cason [4] find that firms with less contact with the general public are less likely to comply with voluntary EPA environmental programs. Greater consumer preference for lower carbon emissions should lead to increased firm emphasis on emission reduction goals. Similarly, firms that sell products to businesses that do not use these products to produce consumer goods may face less little pressure to reduce emissions. These “upstream” firms may find that their business customers place less importance on carbon emissions than attributes such as price or product specification adherence. If so, they will not be as concerned with emissions reduction and labeling as firms producing parts or raw materials for consumer goods producers.

Motivations to reduce carbon emissions may differ even among consumer goods firms. Some firms create and sell products directly to consumers, such as McDonalds, while other firms, such as P&G, sell through an intermediary retailer, such as Wal-Mart. Firms that sell directly to consumers are more likely to feel the need to reduce their carbon footprint levels than those that do not. On the other hand, retailers such as Wal-Mart may be sufficiently powerful and willing to coerce suppliers to conform to their aims with respect to carbon footprint labeling. Thus, the degree to which our predictions are borne out with respect to proximity of connection to the consumer will be moderated by the aims and power of the retailer.

Proposition 4A

The extent to which firms lower their carbon emissions will be moderated by the extent to which consumer reactions affect the firm. Firms that are less affected by consumer reaction will be less likely to lower their emissions.

Proposition 4B

Firms that are more distant from customers (e.g., B2B firms) will expend fewer resources toward reducing carbon emissions than will firms that are directly involved with consumers (e.g., B2C firms).

Market size and market share should be relevant predictors of lower carbon emission levels for firm products. Szymanski et al. [78] find positive relationships between market share and a firm’s quality, advertising expenditure, R&D expenditure, and product line breadth. On the other hand, studies show that increased market share correlates with reduced customer satisfaction [2], lower prices, and suboptimal profits (e.g., [80]). Moreover, because large firms have more diverse customer bases than smaller firms, the pursuit of projects that do not appeal to a majority of customers may not be in a large firm’s best interest. We argue that the same logic holds for carbon emissions.

Firms may achieve lower levels of emissions in other ways, such as through diversification and globalization. The improvement of intangible assets, in this case carbon emission knowledge, has been suggested as one of the main benefits that firms achieve through diversification and becoming multi-national (e.g., [30]). Firms with multiple product lines may be able to transfer the knowledge gained in reducing the carbon footprint for one product to its other products. In other words, a diversified firm should accumulate more knowledge of how to reduce carbon footprints than should a less diversified firm. Similarly, knowledge about carbon emissions management also can be developed by diversified firms via learning curve economies (e.g., [14]). Recent research shows that knowledge acquisition is a primary motivation and reason for success for diversification-based mergers (e.g., [75]).

The argument for increased carbon emission knowledge for globalized firms is similar to that for diversified firms because globalization is considered one type of diversification. Multi-national firms face different regulations across the countries in which they do business, and may be able to apply insights from their experiences throughout their enterprise [88].

The relationship between firm diversification and the firm’s ability to reduce carbon footprint levels may not be linear. However, the more a firm diversifies, the more complex it becomes, and managerial attention may become more divided (e.g., [66]). This increased complexity may limit how much the firm can decrease emission levels; managerial attention has been shown to be a key driver of innovation [86]. On the one hand, the more a firm diversifies the more likely it is to encounter external stakeholders who press the firm to improve its emission levels. On the other hand, such requests may not yield fruit because firms that are diversified tend to be less externally oriented [82].

One factor influencing motivation to respond to these stakeholders with respect to carbon emission reduction may be a firm’s degree of market orientation. Firms that are more market oriented are more likely to take advantage of opportunities to assimilate knowledge and learn from their environment [42]. More importantly, market orientation focuses on both expressed and latent customer needs [73]. Since consumers are likely to value carbon emission level reduction, diversified market oriented firms should be more willing and able to outperform other firms in reducing their carbon footprint levels.

Proposition 5A

Diversification, through both breadth and globalization, will have a U-shaped effect on the level of carbon emissions; moderately diversified firms will have lower levels of emissions than more or less diversified firms.

Proposition 5B

As a firm’s level of market orientation increases, its product’s carbon emissions will decrease.

Proposition 5C

The U-shaped effect of diversification will be less pronounced for firms as their market orientation increases.

2.3 Consumer Response to Carbon Footprint Levels

Whether consumers prefer that Net Emissions level occur through reduction in actual emissions or offsets from carbon offset programs is important because, with limited resources, a company may have to choose between reducing actual emissions in the four life cycle stages of the product to reduce total emissions or investing in offset programs to reduce net emissions. We propose that offset-based emission reductions will influence consumer perceptions less than reducing actual emissions by an equivalent amount. Our prediction is based on consumers’ willingness to expend cognitive effort in reading/using carbon footprint labels. Most consumers will focus on bottom-line net emissions rather than expend more cognitive effort and weigh the pros and cons of how the levels of emissions and offsets combine to create net emissions.

Research suggests that most consumers focus on less complicated options or simplifying heuristics in making decisions (e.g., [77]). For our label, this would mean examining the bottom line, net emissions, rather than any antecedent numbers in the calculation. Thus, in the scenario below, we expect that consumers will tend to view Product A1 more favorably than Product B1 because A1 has a lower net emissions level than B1, even though its actual emissions level is higher.

 

Product A1

Product B1

Emissions

120

100

Offsets

40

10

Net Emissions

80

90

Proposition 6A

In comparing two similar products, consumers will weight Net Emissions (Emissions—Offsets) over Emissions alone.

The decision becomes more complex when a consumer faces a choice between products with equal levels of net emissions but different actual emission levels, recycling levels, and/or offset levels. In making this decision, the consumer must allocate weights to emissions and offsets. In the example below, we argue that Product A2 should be viewed more favorably than Product B2 or Product C2 because offsets, both in the form of recycling and carbon sinks, are uncertain and therefore may be more difficult to accept at 100 % of their face value.

 

Product A2

Product B2

Product C2

Emissions

120

160

160

Offsets

   

 Recycling

10

10

50

 Carbon Sinks

30

70

30

Net Emissions

80

80

80

Proposition 6B

In comparing two similar products with the same Net Emissions, consumers will prefer lower Emissions over higher Offsets.

Finally, consider carbon sink offsets compared with recycling. Carbon sinks are harder to verify than recycling in which consumers can actively participate. Recycling depends on the consumer taking action to recycle. Yet, the trust consumers place in carbon sink calculations is influenced by unknowns—how long they will work, measurement accuracy, and whether the emission reduction actually is achieved [12]. Consumers have been found to distrust hard-to-verify claims on food labels [5]. Because consumers will tend to be more familiar with recycling than carbon sinks, consumers may prefer them due to a type of affect-based hedonic fluency model mere exposure effect presented by Fang et al. [24]. Thus, consumers may discount carbon sinks compared with recycling. In the scenario below, Product A3 will be viewed more favorably than Product B3.

 

Product A3

Product B3

Emissions

100

100

Offsets

  

 Recycling

20

10

 Carbon Sinks

10

20

Net Emissions

70

70

Proposition 6C

When comparing two similar products with the same Offsets, consumers will put more weight on Recycling than on Carbon Sinks.

Another important decision for the firm is whether to undertake an offset program itself or to rely on a third-party firm to manage it. From the firm’s perspective, outsourcing the offset program may provide the most benefits. A firm specializing in offsets should be able to create and monitor an offset program at lower costs and with less risk. On the other hand, consumers may not view this decision the same way. Because consumers use different information as signals with which to infer firm motivations or product quality (e.g., [67]), they may view an outsourced offset program as an indication that the firm is not fully invested in carbon footprint reduction. Because product quality is signaled in part by reputation [21], it is reasonable to suggest that outsourcing carbon offset programs may signal lower product quality to some consumers.

Proposition 6D

When comparing two similar products with the same Offsets, consumers will prefer products from firms that manage their own Offset programs to those from firms that outsource their Offset programs.

2.4 Consumer Characteristics and Their Response to Carbon Footprint Labeling

Consumer characteristics—demographics, cognitive and personality factors—may affect how consumers react to carbon footprint labels and to their constituent parts. Prior research indicates that three common demographic characteristics affect ethical and food label choice; gender, age, and education; use of nutritional labels is higher among females, younger consumers, and the more highly educated [58]. Consumers who read nutritional labels should be more likely to read carbon footprint labels on the package, which should lead to greater awareness of carbon emissions. Because more highly educated consumers tend to be less price sensitive [32], they may be more likely to pay a premium for lower levels of carbon emissions.

Goolsby and Hunt [28] find that younger, more highly educated females score high on cognitive moral development, an indicator of socially responsible attitudes and behavior. Loe et al. [48], in their summary of empirical studies in ethical decision making, note that females and those who are more highly educated are more ethically sensitive. Thus, we predict:

Proposition 7A

Females will use carbon footprint labels to make product decisions more than males.

Proposition 7B

More highly educated consumers will use carbon footprint labels to make product decisions more than less educated consumers.

Proposition 7C

Younger consumers will use carbon footprint labels to make product decisions more than older consumers.

An individual difference variable that may play a prominent role in carbon emissions decision making is locus of control. Locus of control (LOC) is the degree to which a person believes that their behavior is internally motivated or controlled, contingent on their own actions or personal characteristics, versus external, beyond their control and a function of chance or the control of powerful others (e.g., [20]). Bierhoff et al. [10] find that people who are more likely to be altruistic have higher levels of internal LOC, while Singhapakdi and Vitell [72] find that high levels of internal LOC indicate increased moral identity. Cleveland et al. [20] find that an internal environmental LOC relates to recycling levels, while an external environmental LOC relates to exoneration of humans from responsibility for sustainability. These results suggest that consumers with higher internal LOC will focus more on carbon emissions, especially aspects of it in their control, such as recycling.

Proposition 8

The attention consumers pay to carbon emissions across the four stages of the product life cycle will be moderated by locus of control:

  1. i.

    Consumers with higher levels of internal locus of control will pay more attention to the carbon footprint label than those with lower levels of internal locus of control.

  2. ii.

    Consumers with higher levels of internal locus of control will place higher emphasis on the recycling part of the carbon footprint label compared to those with lower levels of internal locus of control.

The symbolic aspect of moral identity [3] and a general need for social approval should affect a consumer’s decisions involving carbon footprints. Consumers generally are more involved in decisions about issues that are important to them, especially regarding their environmental consciousness [18], which is likely to trigger one’s moral identity. The literature tells us that positive firm outcomes occur when there is a perceived fit regarding social issues between the firm’s products and the individual consumer [9], but not when there is a disconnect between the firm’s and customers’ CSR values [69]. One reason for these findings may relate to a consumer’s moral environmental involvement [3]. Moral identity is triggered for those who have a higher level of it when it becomes salient to the situation [68] such as when a fair trade label on coffee induces consumers with higher levels of ethical obligation to purchase more [64]. The existence of products with lower levels of carbon emissions compared to other products may trigger a consumer to demonstrate their higher level of symbolic moral identity and achieve a higher level of social approval [33].

Proposition 9A

Consumers with higher levels of symbolic moral identity will place greater emphasis on carbon footprint labels when making product decisions than those with lower levels of symbolic moral identity.

At the basic level, prior research [50] implies that firms must exceed the expectations of their customers in order to achieve benefits from their CSR. Thus, consumers who desire lower carbon footprints will place a higher weight on carbon footprint levels. Disconfirmation in expectations also may disproportionally affect those firms that consumers perceive to be more moral. For example, Ben and Jerry’s is known as a firm that has a goal of improving the quality of life locally (using local farmers when possible), nationally (sustainable forestry for paper packaging), and internationally (some profits from Rainforest Crunch were reinvested to preserve rainforests). Customers may therefore expect such firms to have higher levels of carbon footprint reduction. Thus, these firms may face higher penalties for greater carbon footprints compared with firms for which consumers have no prior expectations regarding carbon footprint levels. In addition, these same firms may have to greatly exceed the industry average before they achieve any benefits from consumers.

Proposition 9B

Consumers’ prior expectations of the producer’s carbon emissions will moderate the effect of the perception of a product’s emission level on their purchase decision; a product with the same level of carbon emissions will be preferred more if the customer has low expectations than if the customer has high expectations.

Similar to social approval is the effect that peers may have on a carbon footprint label choice. Griskevicius et al. [29] discuss at length the unconscious copying behavior of humans in a sustainability context. Their examples consist of normative social behavior, where the desired behavior is influenced by notifying the decision maker of the level of positive societal group behavior in areas such as energy usage [62] or hotel towel reuse [27]. Solely informing people of sustainability issues seems to have little influence on behavior (e.g., [31]), however peers within a group can positively or negatively affect another individual’s use of carbon footprint labels. Group adaptation increases trust [44] which should increase faith in offsets. Thus, group adoption of carbon footprint labels should increase faith in more questionable parts of the label, such as carbon sinks, moderating proposition 6C.

Cultural group also should have a significant effect on carbon footprint label adoption. Collectivist cultures have tight bonds, and the members look after the interests of the group as a whole [35]. Such cultures have an increased interest in sustainability [46]. Yet, we reason that because of the high, initial level of attention this implies for carbon footprint labels in a collectivist culture, the influence of a pro-sustainability sub-group within the collectivist culture may not be as significant compared to a similar group in a more individualistic culture.

Another moderating influence on the role of peer influence in carbon emissions adoption is a group’s socio-economic status. Clearly, price should matter more to low-income groups, but how will economic disadvantage affect the response to carbon labels? Economically disadvantaged groups may not find sustainability as relevant to them as other issues [52]. Thus, the overall importance of societal pressure should be less for more economically disadvantaged groups.

Proposition 10A

The greater the amount of attention one’s peers pay to carbon emissions the more the individual will pay attention to carbon emissions.

Proposition 10B

Collectivist cultures will pay more attention to carbon emissions than individualist cultures.

Proposition 10C

Group adoption of carbon footprint labels will moderate belief in the efficacy of carbon sinks. As group adoption of carbon footprint labels increases, so will the emphasis placed on carbon sinks.

Proposition 10D

Cultural style will moderate the relationship between peer influence and attention paid to carbon emissions labels. As societal collectivism increases the influence of a peer group will decrease.

Proposition 10E

The economic level of a group will moderate the relationship between peer influence and attention paid to carbon emissions labels. As the level of economic disadvantage increases the influence of a peer group will decrease.

An additional influence on attention to a carbon emission label may be the intended use of the product. Hedonic or experiential purchases are more tempting than utilitarian or functional, economic based purchases [8]. Since utilitarian purchases focus on product usage, the more utilitarian a product is the more attention will be paid to the usage stage of a carbon footprint label.

Proposition 11

The usage part of the carbon footprint label will carry more weight for utilitarian than hedonic products.

Frequently purchased products are usually chosen using simple choice heuristics, producing quick decisions [36]. Thus, carbon footprint labels on frequently purchased products are likely to play less of a role in the decision making process with frequently purchased products.

Proposition 12

As purchase frequency increases the carbon footprint label will play less of a role in product choice.

2.5 Carbon Footprint Reduction and Firm Performance

In theory it may seem beneficial for firms to reduce the carbon footprints of their products. For example, when positive health and nutritional information increases, purchase intentions also increase [43], which in turn increases actual purchases [70]. Perhaps more importantly, evidence suggests that nutritional labels increase the attention paid to nutritional aspects of food [5]. Translating these findings to carbon emission labeling, we would expect that labeling increases awareness of carbon emissions and their negative impact on the environment, while at the same time increasing purchase intentions and actual purchases for low emission products. However, the relationship between carbon footprint level reduction and increases in firm revenue may be nonlinear. That is, firms may see diminishing returns from sustainability investments in terms both of customer perceptions and financial returns. Customer satisfaction researchers have found a negative quadratic relationship between customer satisfaction and accounting measures [39], and between corporate reputation and price premiums [63]. Ittner and Larcker [39] report an increase in customer retention rate at a customer satisfaction score of about 67, but no further increase for scores above 70. In terms of carbon footprint labels, a greater increase in revenue may be achieved by improving a product’s rating from the industry norm to one standard deviation higher than the industry norm, rather than improving it to two standard deviations above the industry norm. If this non-linear relationship holds for carbon emission levels, the increased revenue associated with emission reduction may at some point be outweighed by the increased costs required to further reduce emissions. In addition, investors may balk at increasing investment in lowering emissions levels.

Proposition 13A

Carbon footprint improvements beyond the product category average will produce positive but diminishing marginal financial returns.

An important question is how firms’ financial outcomes will change as their carbon footprint becomes worse than the industry average (p. 25 [34]). We argue that firms will experience increasing marginal negative financial returns and customer perception of the firm as their products’ carbon footprints further exceed the industry mean. Eventually, though, a plateau will be reached where customer perception will not drop any further due to carbon emissions levels, producing an S-shaped response function.

In many choice decisions, loss aversion dictates that the risk of losses outweighs equivalent gains (e.g., [81]). Thus, higher levels of carbon emissions than the industry average should weigh more heavily than achieving emissions (gains) below the industry average. However, higher levels of carbon emissions should be weighted even more heavily. For example, Mittal et al. [54] find that negative performance has a disproportionate effect on customer satisfaction, and, more importantly, that while there is diminishing sensitivity to positive performance, this is not true for negative performance. Luo and Bhattacharya [50], in their study of CSR, customer satisfaction, and corporate ability, find that when firm innovation and CSR are disconnected, firm revenue suffers more. In investigating nutritional labeling, researchers found that consumers pay more attention care more about negative than positive nutrition attributes (e.g., [5]).

Proposition 13B

Increases of carbon footprint levels above the product category average will produce asymmetric (accelerated) negative financial effects before flattening out (S-Shaped response)

2.6 Testing Propositions

The thrust of this paper is conceptual in nature, so empirical testing of the propositions is an important next step. To assist researchers in testing our propositions, we present possible approaches and methodologies in Table 1. Most of the propositions (P1-P5) that focus on industry and firm attributes can best be tested using secondary data sources. The propositions (P6-P13), that focus on label and consumer attributes, lend themselves to laboratory studies, scanner data, and possibly surveys. One challenge with testing our propositions is the current lack of information about carbon emissions levels, which we view as an opportunity rather than an obstacle. As the marketplace adopts carbon footprint labeling, researchers will be better able to trace changing consumer attitudes and purchase behavior. In other words, the time is ripe for natural, quasi-experimental field studies in the area of carbon labeling, as Moorman et al. [56] did with the Nutrition Labeling and Education Act of 1990.

Table 1 Suggestions to test propositions

3 Conclusion

As more of the world’s population becomes concerned with protecting the environment, the relevance of sustainable development to firm management will increase. Our paper posits one measurable aspect of sustainability, universal carbon footprint labeling, and examines the impact on firms and consumers. We have analyzed industry, firm, consumer and label attributes affecting firm action, content of carbon footprint labels, consumer preferences, and finally financial outcomes. We hope that the research community will build upon and test our propositions, and that managers will utilize insights from our paper.

First, managers should recognize that carbon footprint labeling is not just a benefit to society but can be used to improve the firm’s competitive position. Managers should mobilize resources to prepare for this eventuality. Second, practitioners need to consider how consumers will interpret the information displayed on the carbon footprint label. As with other managerial decisions, cost efficiency must be balanced with understanding consumers’ response and its firm profitability implications. Being better than the industry average in terms of carbon emissions is probably preferable, but, at some point, emissions reductions may have diminishing returns. On the other hand, falling below the industry average may have negative financial consequences for a firm. Because brand credibility increases the likelihood of inclusion in consideration sets [23], there may be multiple benefits to firms with low emissions during the consumer decision and purchase making process.

Third, any carbon labeling system must account for carbon emitted during the product’s entire life cycle. If consumers place more weight on the parts of the product life cycle that are more within their control, firms may wish to emphasize usage and disposal, although the firm has the most control over manufacture and transportation, which may be valued by other consumers. Yet, it may be difficult to reduce carbon emissions during some or all of the life-stages of many products, so firms may opt to use offsets in these cases. Consumers may view these programs with varying degrees of skepticism, thus firms should apply discretion in managing these programs.

Fourth, management should recognize how carbon footprint labeling will interact with other firm and industry characteristics such as advertising, innovation, competition, and product category. Finally, firms should be aware of possible changes in consumption habits. For instance, more consumers may switch to filtering their own water rather than buying bottled water which comes with a large transportation carbon footprint. Likewise, when consumers recognize the high levels of carbon to create one pound of beef, they may eat less meat in general or choose pork, which has a much lower carbon footprint.

Our paper has not touched on every aspect of sustainability. For example, although we addressed several customer characteristics, others, such as guilt, may also have an effect. Additionally, we did not discuss other issues, such as legislated market-based approaches or other relevant environmental issues such as water usage, deforestation, and nitrogen emission. These issues may be included in future product labeling, but the underlying propositions should remain applicable. We hope our manuscript prompts research and dialogue regarding an issue that will significantly affect the field of marketing for years to come.