Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

Skilled-unskilled wage inequality and structural transformation in a dual economy

  • Article
  • Published:
Indian Economic Review Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

In this paper, we develop a sectoral model of a less developed economy with a backward agricultural sector dependent on unskilled labour and with an advanced industrial sector dependent on capital and skilled labour and also with a private education sector whose role is to transform an unskilled labourer into a skilled one. Using a Ramsey framework of consumption saving allocation, we analyse how the economy grows over time through accumulation of capital and through transformation of unskilled labour into skilled labour. Such a model helps us to analyse how the structural shift from agriculture to industry takes place and what role do sector specific polices play in this context. We analyse short-run as well as long run effects of sector specific policies on the degree of wage income inequality as well as on the endogenous rate of economic growth; and find that sector specific policies produce opposite effects. Subsidization to agricultural sector leads to an improvement in the degree of wage income inequality but lowers the rate of economic growth in the long run. On the other hand, subsidization or protection to the manufacturing sector produces just the opposite result.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. See, for example, Katz et al. (1992), Bound and Johnson (1992), Borjas and Ramey (1993),Lawrence (1994), Feenstra and Hanson (1997), Wood (1997, 1998), Harrison and Hanson (1999), Hanson and Harisson (1999), Beyer et al.(1999), Green et al. (2001), Leamer (2000), Behrman et al. (2000), Dev (2000), Isgut (2001), Gorg and Strobl (2002), Esquivel and Lopez (2003), Marjit and Acharyya (2003), Banga (2005) etc.

  2. See, for example, Bound and Johnson (1992), Leamer (2000), Marjit and Acharyya (2003) etc. Table 2.1 in page no.-10 in Marjit and Acharyya (2003) is important in this context.

  3. See, for example, Lawrence (1994), Katz et al. (1992) etc.

  4. See, for example, Wood (1997), Dev (2000), Borjas and Ramey (1993), Banga (2005), Beyer et al.(1999) etc.

  5. See, for example, Wood (1997).

  6. According to Wood (1998)Beyer et al.(1999), Green et al. (2001), Behrman et al. (2000), Isgut (2001) etc. trade liberalization is to blame for this growing wage inequality. However, Wood (1997, 1998), Dev (2000) and Gorg and Strobl (2002) are of the view that technological progress worsens wage inequality through an increase in the relative demand for skilled labour. Esquivel and Lopez (2003) shows that technological change aggravates but trade liberalization lowers wage inequality in Mexico.

  7. See Feenstra and Hanson (1997) in this context.

  8. See Harrison and Hanson (1999), Hanson and Harisson (1999) and Beyer et al.(1999) in this context.

  9. See Wood (1997) in this context.

  10. A few works, for example, Gupta and Dutta (2011), Acemoglu (1998, 1999, 2002a, b), Kiley (1999), Sener (2001), Ranjan (2001), Fang et al. (2008), Wang et al. (2009) etc. analyse how technological change affects skilled-unskilled wage inequality in dynamic models. However, Anwar and Rice (2009), Anwar (2006, 2009) etc. shows how trade liberalization affects wage inequality using static product variety models of imperfect competition.

  11. See Lewis (1954), Ranis and Fei (1961), Bose (1968), Hornby (1968), Dixit (1969) etc.

  12. See Lewis (1954), Ranis and Fei (1961), Bose (1968), Hornby (1968), Dixit (1969) etc.

  13. See Jorgenson (1961), Zarembka (1970), Bardhan (1971), Sato and Niho (1971) etc.

  14. See, for example, Alesina and Rodrik (1994), Galor and Zeira (1993), Perotti (1993), Persson and Tabellini (1994) etc.

  15. Results are not dependent on any specific algebraic form.

  16. We shall consider their intertemporal accumulation in the dynamic part of this model.

  17. Derivation is shown in the “Appendix”.

  18. Derivation is given in the “Appendix”.

  19. Results may change if initially \( W_{\text{S}} < W_{\text{U}} \) because then Δ may be negative. This may happen when aL is very low and, as a result, WU is very high.

  20. Derivation of Eq. (10) is presented in the “Appendix”.

  21. This is a simplifying assumption and rules out the possibility of savings of unskilled workers. In less developed countries, unskilled workers are very poor and contribute marginally to aggregate savings.

  22. Derivation of Eq. (15) is shown in the “Appendix”.

  23. Derivation of Eq. (16) is presented in the “Appendix”.

  24. The derivation of the determinant is shown in the “Appendix”.

  25. The derivation of the trace of the matrix is shown in the “Appendix”.

  26. These include Duarte and Restuccia (2010), Liu and Yang (2015), Wingender (2015) etc.

  27. One of the reviewers suggests that FDI flows are a positive function of interest rate differential, \( \left( {r - r^{*} } \right) \) where \( r^{*} \) is the interest rate at the international capital market. Effects of changes in \( r^{*} \) on growth path will be interesting to study. However, this requires substantial revision.

References

  • Acemoglu, D. (1998). Why do new tecchnologies complement skills? Directed technical change and wage inequality. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 113, 1055–1089.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Acemoglu, D. (1999). Changes in unemployment and wage inequalty: An alternative theory and some evidence. American Economic Review, 89, 1258–1278.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Acemoglu, D. (2002a). Directed technical change. Review of Economic Studies, 69, 781–809.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Acemoglu, D. (2002b). Technical change, inequality, and the labor market. Journal of Economic Literature, 40, 7–72.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Alesina, G., & Rodrik, D. (1994). Distributive politics and economic growth. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 109, 465–490.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Anwar, S. (2006). Factor mobilty and wage inequality in the presence of specialistion-based external economics. Economics Letters, 93(1), 88–93.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Anwar, S. (2009). Wage inequality, welfare and downsizing. Economics Letters, 103, 75–77.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Anwar, S., & Rice, J. (2009). Labour mobility and wage inequality in the presence of endogenous foreign investment. Economic Modelling, 26(6), 1135–1139.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Banga, R. (2005). Liberalisation and wage inequality in India. ICRIER working paper 156 March.

  • Bardhan, P. (1971). Optimum trade policy in a dual economy. In J. M. Bhagwati (Ed.), Trade, balance of payments and growth, essays in honor of C. P. Kindelberger. Amsterdam: North Holland Publishing Co.

    Google Scholar 

  • Behrman, J. R., Birdsall, N., & Szekely, M. (2000). Economic reform and wage differentials in Latin America. BID working paper 435 October.

  • Beladi, H., Chaudhuri, S., & Yabuuchi, S. (2008). Can international factor mobility reduce wage inequality in a dual economy? Review of International Economics, 16, 893–903.

    Google Scholar 

  • Beladi, H., Marjit, S., & Broll, U. (2011a). Capital mobility, skill formation and polarization. Economic Modeling, 28, 1902–1906.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Beladi, H., Marjit, S., & Weiher, K. (2011b). An analysis of the demand for skill in a growing economy. Economic Modeling, 28, 1471–1474.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Beyer, H., Rojas, P., & Vergara, R. (1999). Trade liberalization and wage inequality. Journal of Development Economics, 59, 103–123.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Borjas, G., & Ramey, V. A. (1993). Foreign competition, market power and wage inequality: Theory and evidence. NBER working paper 4556. NBER, Cambridge, Massachusetts, December.

  • Bose, S. (1968). Optimal growth and investment allocation. Review of Economic Studies, 35, 465–480.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bound, J., & Johnson, G. (1992). Changes in the structure of wages in the U980s: An evaluation of alternative explanations. American Economic Review, 82, 371–392.

    Google Scholar 

  • Caselli, F., & Coleman, W. J. (2001). The US structural transformation and regional convergence: A reinterpretation. Journal of Political Economy, 109, 584–616.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chaudhuri, S. (2004). International migration of skilled and unskilled labour, welfare and skilled-unskilled wage inequality: A simple model. Journal of Economic Integration, 19(4), 726–741.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chaudhuri, S. (2008). Wage inequality in a dual economy and international mobility of factors: Do factor intensities always matter? Economic Modelling, 25, 1155–1164.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chaudhuri, S., & Yabuuchi, S. (2007). Economic liberalization and wage inequality in the presence of labour market imperfection. International Review of Economics and Finance, 16, 592–603.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chaudhuri, S., & Yabuuchi, S. (2008). Foreign capital and skilled- unskilled wage inequality in a developing economy with non-traded goods. In S. Marjit & E. Yu (Eds.), Contemporary and emerging issues in trade theory and policy (pp. 225–250). Amsterdam: Elsevier Science & Technology Books.

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Dev, M. (2000). Economic liberalization and employment in South Asia. Economic and Political Weekly, 35, 40–51.

    Google Scholar 

  • Dixit, A. K. (1969). Marketable surplus and dual development. Journal of Economic Theory, 1, 203–219.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Duarte, M., & Restuccia, D. (2010). The role of the structural transformation in aggregate productivity. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 125, 129–173.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Esquivel, G., & Lopez, J. A. (2003). Technology, trade and wage inequality in Mexico before and after Nafta. Journal of Development Economics, 72, 543–565.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fang, C., Huang, L., & Wang, M. (2008). Technology spillover and wage inequality. Economic Modelling, 25, 137–147.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Feenstra, R. C., & Hanson, G. H. (1997). Foreign direct investment and relative wages: evidence from Mexico’s maquiladoras. Journal of Inrenational Economics, 42, 371–394.

    Google Scholar 

  • Galor, O., & Zeira, J. (1993). Income distribution and macroeconomics. Review of Economic Studies, 60, 35–52.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gorg, H., & Strobl, E. (2002). Relative wages, openness and skill-baised technological change. IZA discussion paper series 596 October.

  • Green, F., Dickerson, A., & Arbache, J. (2001). A picture of wage inequality and the allocation of labour through a period of trade liberalization: The case of Brazil. World Development, 29(11), 1923–1939.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gupta, M. R., & Dutta, P. B. (2010a). Skilled–unskilled wage inequality, nontraded good and endogenous supply of skilled labour: A theoretical analysis. Economic Modelling, 27, 923–934.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gupta, M. R., & Dutta, P. B. (2010b). Skilled–unskilled wage inequality: A general equilibrium analysis. Research in Economics, 64, 247–263.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gupta, M. R., & Dutta, P. B. (2011). Skilled–unskilled wage inequality and unemployment: A general equilibrium analysis. Economic Modelling, 28, 1977–1983.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hanson, G. H., & Harisson, A. (1999). Trade liberalization and wage inequality in Mexico. Industrial and Labor Economics Review, 52, 271–288.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Harrison, A., & Hanson, G. (1999). Who gains from trade refrom? Some remmaning puzzles. Journal of Development Economics, 59, 125–154.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hornby, J. M. (1968). Investment and trade policy in the dual economy. The Economic Journal, 78, 96–107.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Isgut, A. E. (2001). What’s different about exporters? Evidence from Colombian manufacturing. Journal of Development Studies, 37, 57–82.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jones, R. W. (1965). The structure of simple general equilibrium models. Journal of Political Economy, 73, 557–572.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jorgenson, D. W. (1961). The development of a dual economy. The Economic Journal, 71, 309–334.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kar, S., & Beladi, H. (2004). Skill formation and international migration: Welfare perspective of developing countries. Japan and the World Economy, 16, 33–54.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Katz, L., Loveman, G. W., & Blanchflower, D. G. (1992). A comparison of changes in the structure of wages in four OECD countries . Cambridge: NBER.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kiley, M. T. (1999). The supply of skilled labor and skilled-baised technological progress. Economic Journal, 109, 708–724.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lawrence, R. Z. (1994). Trade, multinationals and labour. NBER working paper 4836.

  • Leamer, E. (2000). What’s the use of factor contents? Journal of International Economics, 50, 51–71.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lewis, W. A. (1954). Economic development and unlimited supplies of labour (Vol. 22, pp. 139–191). Manchester: Manchester School.

    Google Scholar 

  • Liu, H., & Yang, T. (2015). Explaining the productivity growth gap between China and India: The role of structural transformation. The Developing Economies, 53, 100–121.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lucas, R. E. (1988). On the mechanics of economic development. Journal of Monetary Economics, 22, 3–42.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lucas, R. (2004). Life earnings and rural-urban migration. Journal of Political Economy, 112, S29–S59.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Marjit, S., & Acharyya, R. (2003). International trade, wage inequality and the developing economy—a general equilibrium approach. Berlin: Springer.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Marjit, S., & Acharyya, R. (2006). Trade liberalization, skill-linked intermediate production and the two-sided wage gap. The Journal of Policy Refrom, 9, 203–217.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Marjit, S., Beladi, H., & Chakrabarti, A. (2004). Trade and wage inequality in developing countries. Economic Inquiry, 42(2), 295–303.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Marjit, S., & Kar, S. (2005). Emigration and wage inequality. Economics Letters, 88, 141–145.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Perotti, R. (1993). Political equilibrium, income distribution and growth. Review of Economic Studies, 60, 755–776.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Persson, T., & Tabellini, G. (1994). Is inequality harmful for growth? American Economic Review, 84, 600–621.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ranis, G., & Fei, J. C. (1961). A theory of economic development. American Economic Review, 51, 533–565.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ranjan, P. (2001). Dynamic evaluation of income distribution and crerdit constrained human development investment in open economies. Journal of International Economics, 55, 329–358.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rogerson, R. (2008). Structural transformation and the deterioration of European labor market outcomes. Journal of Political Economy, 116, 235–259.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sato, R., & Niho, Y. (1971). Population growth and the development of a dual economy. Oxford Economic Papers, 23, 418–436.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sener, F. (2001). Schumpeterian unemployment, trade and wages. Journal of International Economics, 54, 119–148.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wang, M., Fang, C., & Huang, L. (2009). International knowledge spillovers and wage inequality in developing countries. Economic Modelling, 26(6), 1208–1214.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wingender, A. M. (2015). Skill complementarity and the dual economy. European Economic Review, 74, 269–285.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wood, A. (1997). Openness and wage inequality in developing countries—the Latin American challenge to East Asian conventional wisdom. World Bank Research Observer, 11, 33–57.

    Google Scholar 

  • Wood, A. (1998). Globalisation and the rise in labor market inequalities. The Economic Journal, 108, 1463–1482.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Yabuuchi, S., & Chadhuri, S. (2007). International migration of labour and skilled-unskilled wage inequality in a developing economy. Economic Modelling, 24(1), 128–137.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Yabuuchi, S., & Chaudhuri, S. (2009). Skill formation, capital adjustment cost and wage inequality. Review of Urban and Regional Development Studies, 21(1), 2–13.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Zarembka, P. (1970). Marketable surplus and growth in the dual economy. Journal of Economic Theory, 2, 107–121.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Priya Brata Dutta.

Additional information

Publisher's Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Appendix

Appendix

1.1 Derivation of Eqs. (8), (9) and (20)

Differentiating both sides of Eq. (1), we obtain

$$ \widehat{{P_{\text{U}} }} = \widehat{{W_{\text{U}} }} $$
(A.1)

Differentiating both sides of Eq. (2), we obtain

$$ \widehat{{P_{\text{M}} }} = \theta_{\text{SM}} \widehat{{W_{\text{S}} }} + \theta_{\text{KM}} \widehat{r} $$
(A.2)

From Eqs. (3) and (4), we have

$$ W_{\text{S}} - W_{\text{U}} = a_{\text{SE}} W_{\text{S}} + a_{\text{KE}} r $$
(A.3)

Differentiating both sides of equation (A.3), we have

$$ \left( {\theta_{\text{SE}} - \frac{{W_{\text{S}} }}{{W_{\text{S}} - W_{\text{U}} }}} \right)\widehat{{W_{\text{S}} }} + \frac{{W_{\text{U}} }}{{W_{\text{S}} - W_{\text{U}} }}\widehat{{W_{\text{U}} }} + \theta_{\text{KE}} \widehat{r} = 0 $$
(A.4)

Using equations (A.1) and (A.4), we have

$$ \left( {\theta_{\text{SE}} - \frac{{W_{\text{S}} }}{{W_{\text{S}} - W_{\text{U}} }}} \right)\widehat{{W_{\text{S}} }} + \theta_{\text{KE}} \widehat{r} = - \frac{{W_{\text{U}} }}{{W_{\text{S}} - W_{\text{U}} }}\widehat{{P_{\text{U}} }} . $$
(A.5)

Solving equations (A.2) and (A.5), we have

$$ \widehat{{W_{\text{S}} }} = \frac{1}{\Delta }\left[ {\frac{{W_{\text{U}} }}{{W_{\text{S}} - W_{\text{U}} }}\theta_{\text{KM}} \widehat{{P_{\text{U}} }} + \theta_{\text{KE}} \widehat{{P_{\text{M}} }}} \right] $$
(A.6)

and

$$ \widehat{r} = \frac{1}{\Delta }\left[ { - \frac{{W_{\text{U}} }}{{W_{\text{S}} - W_{\text{U}} }}\theta_{\text{SM}} \widehat{{P_{\text{U}} }} - \left( {\theta_{\text{SE}} - \frac{{W_{\text{S}} }}{{W_{\text{S}} - W_{\text{U}} }}} \right)\widehat{{P_{\text{M}} }}} \right] $$
(A.7)

Equation (A.7) is same as Eq. (20).

From equations (A.1) and (A.6), we have

$$ \widehat{{W_{\text{S}} }} - \widehat{{W_{\text{U}} }} = \frac{{\theta_{\text{KE}} }}{\Delta }\widehat{{P_{\text{M}} }} + \left( {\frac{{\theta_{\text{KM}} \frac{{W_{\text{U}} }}{{W_{\text{S}} - W_{\text{U}} }}}}{\Delta } - 1} \right)\widehat{{P_{\text{U}} }} $$
(A.8)

where

$$ \Delta = \theta_{\text{KE}} + \theta_{\text{KM}} \frac{{W_{\text{U}} }}{{W_{\text{S}} - W_{\text{U}} }} $$

Equation (A.8) is same as Eq. (8).

From equations (A.6) and (A.7), we have

$$ \widehat{{W_{\text{S}} }} - \widehat{r} = \frac{{\frac{{W_{\text{U}} }}{{W_{\text{S}} - W_{\text{U}} }}}}{\Delta }\left[ { - \widehat{{P_{\text{M}} }} + \widehat{{P_{\text{U}} }}} \right] $$
(A.9)

Equation (A.9) is same as Eq. (9).

1.2 Derivation of Eq. (10)

Differentiating both sides of Eq. (6), we have

$$ \begin{aligned} \lambda_{\text{SM}} \widehat{{X_{\text{M}} }} + \lambda_{\text{SE}} \widehat{{X_{\text{E}} }} & = \widehat{S} - \lambda_{\text{SM}} \widehat{{a_{\text{SM}} }} - \lambda_{\text{SE}} \widehat{{a_{\text{SE}} }} \Rightarrow \lambda_{\text{SM}} \widehat{{X_{\text{M}} }} + \lambda_{\text{SE}} \widehat{{X_{\text{E}} }} \\& = \widehat{S} - \left( {\lambda_{\text{SM}} S_{\text{SS}}^{\text{M}} + \lambda_{\text{SE}} S_{\text{SS}}^{\text{E}} } \right)\left( {\widehat{{W_{\text{S}} }} - \widehat{r}} \right) \\ \end{aligned} $$
(A.10)

Similarly, differentiating both sides of Eq. (7), we have

$$ \lambda_{\text{KM}} \widehat{{X_{\text{M}} }} + \lambda_{\text{KE}} \widehat{{X_{\text{E}} }} = \widehat{K} - \left( {\lambda_{\text{KM}} S_{\text{KS}}^{\text{M}} + \lambda_{\text{KE}} S_{\text{KS}}^{\text{E}} } \right)\left( {\widehat{{W_{\text{S}} }} - \widehat{r}} \right) $$
(A.11)

Solving equations (A.10) and (A.11) we obtain

$$ \widehat{{X_{\text{E}} }} = \frac{1}{\left| \lambda \right|}\left[ {\lambda_{\text{SM}} \widehat{K} - \lambda_{\text{KM}} \widehat{S} + \left\{ {\lambda_{\text{KM}} \left( {\lambda_{\text{SM}} S_{\text{SS}}^{\text{M}} + \lambda_{\text{SE}} S_{\text{SS}}^{\text{E}} } \right) - \lambda_{\text{SM}} \left( {\lambda_{\text{KM}} S_{\text{KS}}^{\text{M}} + \lambda_{\text{KE}} S_{\text{KS}}^{\text{E}} } \right)} \right\}\left( {\widehat{{W_{\text{S}} }} - \widehat{r}} \right)} \right] $$
(A.12)

Here, \( \left| \lambda \right| = \lambda_{\text{SM}} \lambda_{\text{KE}} - \lambda_{\text{SE}} \lambda_{\text{KM}} \).

Finally, using equations (A.8) and (A.12), we obtain

$$ \widehat{{X_{\text{E}} }} = \frac{1}{\left| \lambda \right|}\left[ {\lambda_{\text{SM}} \widehat{K} - \lambda_{\text{KM}} \widehat{S} + \frac{{\lambda_{\text{KM}} \left( {\lambda_{\text{SM}} S_{\text{SS}}^{\text{M}} + \lambda_{\text{SE}} S_{\text{SS}}^{\text{E}} } \right) - \lambda_{\text{SM}} \left( {\lambda_{\text{KM}} S_{\text{KS}}^{\text{M}} + \lambda_{\text{KE}} S_{\text{KS}}^{\text{E}} } \right)}}{\Delta }\frac{{W_{\text{U}} }}{{W_{\text{S}} \left( {1 - \eta } \right) - W_{\text{U}} }}\left\{ { - \widehat{{P_{\text{M}} }} + \widehat{{P_{\text{U}} }}} \right\}} \right] $$
(A.13)

Equation (A.13) is same as Eq. (10).

1.3 Derivation of Eq. (15)

The dynamic optimization problem is to maximize \( \mathop \smallint \limits_{0}^{\infty } e^{ - \rho t} \frac{{C^{1 - \sigma } }}{1 - \sigma }{\text{d}}t \) with respect to control variable C subject to Eq. (12) and given \( K(0) \) and satifying \( 0 \le C \le Y \).

The Hamiltonian to be maximized at each point of time is given by

$$ H = e^{ - \rho t} \frac{{c^{1 - \sigma } }}{1 - \sigma } + e^{ - \rho t} \lambda_{\text{K}} \left[ {Y - C} \right] $$
(A.14)

Where λK is the co-state variable. Assuming an interior solution, we obtain

$$ C^{ - \sigma } = \lambda_{\text{K}} $$
(A.15)

Also the optimum time path of \( \lambda_{K} \) satisfies the following.

$$ \frac{{\dot{\lambda }_{K} }}{{\lambda_{K} }} = \rho - \frac{dY}{dK} $$
(A.16)

Using Eqs. (13) and (A.16) we have

$$ \frac{{\dot{\lambda }_{\text{K}} }}{{\lambda_{\text{K}} }} = \rho - r $$
(A.17)

Using equations (A.15) and (A.17), we have

$$ \frac{{\dot{C}}}{C} = \frac{1}{\sigma }\left( {r - \rho } \right) $$
(A.18)

Equation (A.18) is same as Eq. (15).

1.4 Derivation of Eq. (16)

Using Eqs. (6) and (7) we have

$$ X_{\text{S}} = \frac{{\left( {a_{\text{SM}} K - a_{\text{KM}} S} \right)}}{\left| \lambda \right|} $$
(A.19)

where, \( \left| \lambda \right| = a_{\text{SM}} a_{\text{KE}} - a_{\text{SE}} a_{\text{KM}} = \lambda_{\text{SM}} \lambda_{\text{KE}} - \lambda_{\text{SE}} \lambda_{\text{KM}} \).

Using Eqs. (14) and (A.19) we obtain

$$ \frac{{\dot{S}}}{S} = \frac{{a_{\text{SM}} }}{\left| \lambda \right|}\frac{K}{S} - \frac{{a_{\text{KM}} }}{\left| \lambda \right|} - \eta $$
(A.20)

Equation (A.20) is same as Eq. (16).

1.5 Determinant and trace of Jacobian matrix

Here the Jacobian matrix corresponding to differential Eqs. (23) and (24) is given by

$$ J = \left[ {\begin{array}{*{20}c} {\frac{{\partial \dot{z}}}{\partial z}} & {\frac{{\partial \dot{z}}}{\partial y}} \\ {\frac{{\partial \dot{y}}}{\partial z}} & {\frac{{\partial \dot{y}}}{\partial y}} \\ \end{array} } \right] $$

where,

$$ \frac{{\partial \dot{z}}}{\partial z} = - \frac{{a_{\text{SM}} }}{\left| \lambda \right|}\frac{1}{{z^{2} }} - W_{\text{S}} $$
$$ \frac{{\partial \dot{z}}}{\partial y} = 1 $$
$$ \frac{{\partial \dot{y}}}{\partial z} = - W_{\text{S}} $$

and

$$ \frac{{\partial \dot{y}}}{\partial y} = 1 $$

So the determinant of the Jacobian matrix can be written as follows.

$$ \left| J \right| = - \frac{{a_{\text{SM}} }}{\left| \lambda \right|}\frac{1}{{z^{2} }} $$

This is same as that shown in Sect. 3.3.

The trace of the Jacobian matrix is given by

$$ {\text{Tr J}} = - \frac{{a_{\text{SM}} }}{\left| \lambda \right|}\frac{1}{{z^{2} }} - W_{\text{S}} + 1 $$

This is same as that shown in Sect. 3.3.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Gupta, M.R., Dutta, P.B. Skilled-unskilled wage inequality and structural transformation in a dual economy. Ind. Econ. Rev. 53, 311–332 (2018). https://doi.org/10.1007/s41775-018-0029-8

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s41775-018-0029-8

Keywords

JEL classification

Navigation