Skip to main content
Log in

Household income requirements and financial conditions

  • Published:
Empirical Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Understanding the income requirements of households is important for examining why households become financially stressed and liquidity constrained. Our econometric approach relies on actual incidences of household-specific financial stress to determine household income requirements. Using an extensive longitudinal dataset of Australian households, we find significant lifecycle effects in income requirements and identify the household types which benefit or are disadvantaged by the typical 30% debt to income measure of financial stress. We also find that, in general, households are locked into tight spending patterns such that, with the exception of households in the top income quintile, financial stress occurs when negative income shocks exceed 30%.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Institutional subscriptions

Fig. 1
Fig. 2

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Income requirements may differ across households for a range of reasons, including the household’s capacity to smooth its spending level (Clarida 1991; Chetty and Szeidl 2007), the idiosyncratic shocks it experiences (Deaton 1991; Aiyagari 1994), its spending habits and marginal propensity to consume (Kaplan and Violante 2014; McKay and Reis 2016a) and its position on the consumption lifecycle (Attanasio and Weber 1995; Gourinchas and Parker 2002; Fernandez-Villaverde and Kruger 2007).

  2. Given the use of financial stress to identify household income requirements, the paper is also related to the literature regarding the drivers of household financial stress and vulnerability (Morduch 1994; Kochar 1995; Gertler and Gruber 2002).

  3. These heterogeneities may impact on the propagation of economic shocks, and the effectiveness of fiscal and monetary policy and social insurance mechanisms (Kaplan et al. 2016; Krueger et al. 2016; McKay and Reis 2016b). They are also important in terms of their behavioural ramifications, particularly since there is a significant body of research, indicating that the capacity to make rational decisions appears to be compromised during periods of stress (Fehrm and Tyran 2005; De Martino et al. 2006; Tom et al. 2007).

  4. Our treatment of housing accommodation expenditure as being markedly different to non-housing consumption is also consistent with research indicating a different consumption lifecycle for housing costs; whilst the consumption of non-housing goods is typically hump-shaped over the lifecycle, housing consumption appears to increase monotonically before flattening out (Fernandez-Villaverde and Kruger 2007; Yang 2009).

  5. In line with van Praag (1971) and Goedhart et al. (1977), the standard deviation of \(u_{it}\) partially reflects household i’s welfare (or stress) sensitivity and also reflects the econometrician’s uncertainty about the household’s stress response.

  6. Accordingly, our decision rule is based on observed instances of financial stress whereby households do not have enough income or savings to engage in necessary activities. Households reporting financial stress have therefore already breached the point where they can draw down on any savings. Since households do not have recourse to wealth in their financial stress determination, the decision rule also reflects the economic environment described in Challe et al. (2016), Ravn and Sterk (2015), Challe and Ragot (2016) and McKay (2017) where households behave as if they have little or no wealth and limited capacity for self-insurance. This is justified on the basis that the vast majority of household wealth is in the form of illiquid assets (see, further, Kaplan et al. 2014).

  7. This is evident in the discussion on the distribution of income requirements in online supplementary material (Appendix S4), where the resulting distribution of income requirements is clearly non-normal, with a heavy right tail that reflects the inability of a sizeable proportion of households to adjust their spending requirements.

  8. The primary income earner is used to identify the household. The household’s income includes income received by all household members.

  9. The iteration is commenced at wave 2 since the variables used to estimate \(z_{it}\) are not available in wave 1.

  10. Technically, since \(\widehat{k}_{it}\) is a generated regressor, the OLS standard error associated with the estimated coefficient may no longer be correct. In our setting, however, we simply seek an approximate value of c for expositional purposes. An alternative value of c (for example, \(c=0.3\)) can also be used with little change to the findings.

  11. http://portal.hud.gov/hudportal/HUD?src=/program_offices/comm_planning/affordablehousing.

  12. Technically, this should be equal to \(\min \left( \widehat{p}_{it},1\right) \) since there are households with expenditure requirements that exceed their income. We do not impose this constraint since we are interested in the quantum of income support needed to transition a stressed household away from financial distress.

References

  • Aguiar M, Hurst E (2005) Consumption vs. expenditure. J Polit Econ 113(5):919–48

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Aiyagari SR (1994) Uninsured idiosyncratic risk and aggregate saving. Q J Econ 109(3):659–684

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ampudia M, Vlokhoven HV, Zochowski D (2014) Financial fragility of Euro area households. ECB Working Paper no. 1737

  • Attanasio O, Weber G (1995) Is consumption growth consistent with intertemporal optimization? Evidence from the Consumer Expenditure Survey. J Polit Econ 103(6):1121–1157

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Australian Bureau of Statistics (ABS) (2013) Household Income and Income Distribution 2011–12. Cat. No. 6230.0, Canberra

  • Blundell R, Pistaferri L, Preston I (2008) Consumption inequality and partial insurance. Am Econ Rev 98(5):1887–1921

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Buera FJ, Monge-Naranjo A, Primiceri GE (2011) Learning the wealth of nations. Econometrica 79(1):1–45

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Carroll C, Slacalek J, Tokuoka K (2014) The distribution of wealth and the marginal propensity to consume. ECB Working Paper No. 1655

  • Celidoni M (2015) Decomposing vulnerability to poverty. Rev Income Wealth 61(1):59–74

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Challe E, Matheron J, Ragot X, Rubio-Ramirez JF (2016) Precautionary saving and aggregate demand. Quant Econ 8(2):435–478

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Challe E, Ragot X (2016) Precautionary saving over the business cycle. Econ J 126:135–164

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chetty R, Szeidl A (2007) Consumption commitments and risk preferences. Q J Econ 122(2):831–877

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Clarida RH (1991) Aggregate stochastic implications of the life cycle hypothesis. Q J Econ 106(3):851–867

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • De Martino B, Kumaran D, Seymore B, Dolan RJ (2006) Frames, biases, and rational decision-making in the human brain. Science 313(5787):684–687

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Deaton AS (1991) Saving and liquidity constraints. Econometrica 59(4):1221–1248

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Deaton AS, Ruiz-Castillo J, Thomas D (1989) The influence of household composition on household expenditure patterns: theory and Spanish evidence. J Polit Econ 97(1):179–203

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Deaton AS (1992) Understanding consumption. Oxford University Press, Oxford

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Donaldson D, Pendakur K (2003) Equivalent-expenditure functions and expenditure-dependent equivalence scales. J Pub Econ 88(1):175–208

    Google Scholar 

  • Donaldson D, Pendakur K (2006) The identification of fixed costs from consumer behavior. J Bus Econ Stat 24(3):255–265

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dynan KE, Skinner J, Zeldes SP (2004) Do the rich save more? J Polit Econ 112(2):397–444

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fehrm E, Tyran JR (2005) Individual irrationality and aggregate outcomes. J Econ Perspect 19(4):43–66

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fernandez-Villaverde J, Kruger D (2007) Consumption over the life cycle: some facts from Consumer Expenditure Survey data. Rev Econ Stat 89(3):552–565

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gertler P, Gruber J (2002) Insuring consumption against illness. Am Econ Rev 92(1):51–70

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Goedhart T, Halberstadt V, Kapteyn A, van Praag BM (1977) The poverty line: concept and measurement. J Hum Resour 12(4):503–520

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gourinchas PE, Parker J (2002) Consumption over the life cycle. Econometrica 70(1):47–89

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Japelli T, Pistaferri L (2014) Fiscal policy and MPC heterogeneity. AEJ Macroecon 6(4):107–136

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kaplan G, Violante GL (2014) A model of the consumption response to fiscal stimulus payments. Econometrica 82(4):1199–1239

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kaplan G, Violante GL, Weidner J (2014) The wealthy hand-to-mouth. Brook Pap Econ Act 2014)(1):77–138

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kaplan G, Moll B, Violante GL (2016) Monetary policy according to HANK. NBER Working Paper No. 21897

  • Karasulu M (2008) Stress testing household debt in Korea. IMF Working Paper no. 08/225

  • Kochar A (1995) Explaining household vulnerability to idiosyncratic income shocks. Am Econ Rev 85(2):159–164

    Google Scholar 

  • Koulovatianos C, Schroder C, Schmidt U (2005) On the income dependence of equivalence scales. J Pub Econ 89(5–6):967–996

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Krueger D, Perri F (2006) Does income inequality lead to consumption inequality? Evidence and theory. Rev Econ Stud 73(1):163–193

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Krueger D, Mitman K, Perri F (2016) Macroeconomics and household heterogeneity. NBER Working Paper No. 22319

  • Lusardi A, Schneider D, Tufano P (2011) Financially fragile households: evidence and implications. Brook Pap Econ Act 42(1):83–150

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mazzocco M (2007) Household intertemporal behaviour: a collective characterization and a test of commitment. Rev Econ Stud 74(3):857–895

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • McKay A (2017) Time-varying idiosyncratic risk and aggregate consumption dynamics. J Monet Econ 88:1–14

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • McKay A, Reis R (2016a) The role of automatic stabilizers in the U.S. business cycle. Econometrica 84(1):141–194

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • McKay A, Reis R (2016b) Optimal automatic stabilizers. http://people.bu.edu/amckay/pdfs/OptStab.pdf

  • Morduch J (1994) Poverty and vulnerability. Am Econ Rev 84(2):221–225

    Google Scholar 

  • OECD (2008) The OECD list of social indicators. Paris

  • OECD (2011) Divided we stand—why inequality keeps rising. Paris

  • Piazzesi M, Schneider M (2016) Housing and macroeconomics, Chapter 20. In: Taylor JB, Uhlig H (eds) Handbook of macroeconomics, vol 2b. North Holland, Amsterdam

    Google Scholar 

  • Pollak RA, Wales TJ (1979) Welfare comparisons and equivalence scales. Am Econ Rev 69(2):216–221

    Google Scholar 

  • Ravn MO, Sterk V (2015) Job uncertainty and deep recessions. Centre for Macroeconomics (UK) Paper No. CFM-DP2015-1

  • Ruiz-Arranz M (2014) Vulnerabilities of household and corporate balance sheets in the United Kingdom and risks for the financial sector. In: Ong LL (ed) A guide to IMF stress testing. International Monetary Fund, Washington, DC

    Google Scholar 

  • Sugawara N, Zalduendo J (2011) Stress-testing Croatian households with debt: implications for financial stability. World Bank Policy Research Working Paper no. 5906

  • Tom SM, Fox CR, Trepel C, Poldrack RA (2007) The neural basis of loss aversion in decision-making under risk. Science 315(5811):515–518

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tsiaplias S (2017) The welfare implications of unobserved heterogeneity. MIAESR, The University of Melbourne, Working Paper No. 21/17

  • van Praag BM (1971) The welfare function of income in Belgium: an empirical investigation. Eur Econ Rev 2(3):337–69

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Yang F (2009) Consumption over the life cycle: How different is housing? Rev Econ Dyn 12(3):423–443

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Sarantis Tsiaplias.

Additional information

We thank two anonymous referees, an associate editor, the editor Michael Lechner, members of the HILDA team Mark Wooden and Roger Wilkins, Andrew J. Rettenmaier and participants at the Southern Economic Association 85th annual meeting and participants at the 2016 Department of Social Services (Australia) Longitudinal Data Conference for helpful comments and suggestions. This paper uses unit record data from the Household, Income and Labour Dynamics in Australia (HILDA) Survey. The HILDA Project was initiated and is funded by the Australian Government Department of Social Services (DSS) and is managed by the Melbourne Institute of Applied Economic and Social Research (Melbourne Institute). The findings and views reported in this paper, however, are those of the authors and should not be attributed to either DSS or the Melbourne Institute.

Electronic supplementary material

Below is the link to the electronic supplementary material.

Supplementary material 1 (pdf 119 KB)

Appendix: Approach to model estimation

Appendix: Approach to model estimation

Model estimation broadly follows the approach used in Buera et al. (2011). The relevant steps for the model proposed in this paper are:

1. Formulate a binary decision rule that involves unobserved information, subject to the restriction that the decision or outcome is observed. In our case, the decision rule is given by

$$\begin{aligned} m_{it}=1\left( h_{it}^{y^{*}}>h_{it}^{y}\right) , \end{aligned}$$

where \(m_{it}\) is an observed instance of financial stress and \(h_{it} ^{y^{*}}\) is not observed.

2. Specify a stochastic functional form for \(h_{it}^{y^{*}}\). In our case,

$$\begin{aligned} h_{it}^{y^{*}}=f_{it}^{h}+\gamma _{0i}+x_{it}^{\prime }\gamma +z_{it}^{\prime }\beta +u_{it}, \end{aligned}$$

where \(u_{it}\sim N\left( 0,\eta _{i}^{2}\right) \).

3. Given that \(u_{it}\) is Gaussian and the decision rule for \(m_{it}\) is binary, the conditional density of \(m_{it}\) is given by

$$\begin{aligned}&L_{i}\left( m_{i}|\beta ,\gamma ,\gamma _{0i},\eta _{i},X_{i}\right) \\&\quad = {\displaystyle \prod \limits _{t=t_{0i}}^{T_{i}}} \Phi \left( \frac{\gamma _{0i}+x_{it}^{\prime }\gamma +z_{it}^{\prime } \beta +f_{it}^{h}-h_{it}^{y}}{\eta _{i}}\right) ^{m_{it}}\\&\qquad \times \left( 1-\Phi \left( \frac{\gamma _{0i}+x_{it}^{\prime }\gamma +z_{it}^{\prime }\beta +f_{it}^{h} -h_{it}^{y}}{\eta _{i}}\right) \right) ^{1-m_{it}}. \end{aligned}$$

4. Specify priors for the model parameters \(\beta ,\gamma ,\gamma _{0i},\eta _{i} \). It is natural to specify a Gaussian prior for \(\gamma _{0i}\) and an inverse-gamma prior for \(\eta _{i}\). We change this slightly, specifying a Gaussian prior for \(\widehat{k}_{it}\) rather than \(\gamma _{0i}\) since it is easier for the econometrician to consider the prior distribution of non-housing income requirements \(\widehat{k}_{it}\) rather than the individual parameters \(\gamma _{0i}\). In our case, we specify

$$\begin{aligned} \widehat{k}_{it}&\sim N\left( \mu _{0},\sigma _{0}^{2}\right) , \\ \eta _{i}^{2}&\sim IG\left( n_{0},s_{0}\right) {.} \end{aligned}$$

5. Formulate the posterior density given by the product of the model’s likelihood function and the prior densities and choose the model parameters that maximise the resulting posterior density.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Lim, G.C., Tsiaplias, S. Household income requirements and financial conditions. Empir Econ 57, 1705–1730 (2019). https://doi.org/10.1007/s00181-018-1512-x

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s00181-018-1512-x

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation