1 Introduction

A pivotal year in the German labor market development was 2005: After the German reunification the unemployment rate grew from 7.30 to 11.4% in 1997. Followed by a phase of recovery, which was mainly driven by the “new economy”. The bursting of the dot-com bubble led to an increase of the German unemployment rate to its all-time high in 2005 with 11.7%. However, up to the financial crisis in 2008 the unemployment rate fell sharply to 7.8% and even to 5% in the following decade. Figure 1 illustrates the development of the unemployment rate and the number of unemployed over the period 1991–2019. Hereby, the question about the cause of the strong decrease in the unemployment rate since 2005 naturally arises.

Fig. 1
figure 1

Source Statistik der Bundesagentur für Arbeit (2020); Author’s own calculations

Development of Unemployment in Germany.

At this time, an important labor market policy milestone took place in Germany. In this regard, the German Hartz reforms stand out as a potential channel for the reversal of unemployment.Footnote 1 They had their focus on the restructuring of the low-wage sector in Germany. The labor market reforms were implemented between 2003 and 2005 in four stages (Hartz I–Hartz IV). Especially through the fourth stage (Hartz IV) and the introduction of the long-term unemployment benefit “Arbeitslosengeld II” (hereafter “ALG II”) on January 1st, 2005 it was hoped to cut the unemployment: On the one hand, the long-term unemployment benefit was initiated to provide a life of human dignity for all people living in Germany between the age of 15 and 65 (or 67), who are capable of working and cannot afford to satisfy their basic material needs.Footnote 2 On the other hand, the long-term unemployment benefit is conditional, and the recipients are obliged to aim actively for integration into the labor market. In the case of a breach of duty, the long-term unemployment benefit is reduced by 30%, in the case of a second time by 60%, and in the case of a third time the benefit is cut all together. The long-term unemployment benefit is financed by the federal government via the Federal Employment Agency (“Bundesagentur f\(\ddot{\textrm{u}}\)r Arbeit”), except for housing and other costs that are usually paid by municipalities and counties (§6 SGB II). Typically, the long-term unemployment benefit (“ALG II”) is paid after a person is unemployed for more than 12 months and thus is not eligible for the short-term unemployment benefit “Arbeitslosengeld I” (“ALG I”) anymore. Moreover, a person can be eligible for the long-term unemployment benefit even if the person is working, yet earns less than he needs to satisfy the basic demands. This group makes about one third of all long-term unemployment benefit (“ALG II”) recipients.Footnote 3

This paper investigates the impact of the German labor market reform (Hartz IV) on the German labor market at the German county level (“Kreisebene”). For my analysis I build on the new spatial multi-country and multi-sector equilibrium model of Caliendo et al. (2019). It includes a dynamic set-up, which considers the adjustments of the labor market, as the economic and policy effects on employment differ for each sector and need time to adapt. Further, the model provides a rich theoretical framework which takes input–output linkages, labor mobility frictions, goods mobility frictions as well as spatial factors into account. In order to incorporate the German labor market reform (Hartz IV) in a dynamic general equilibrium setting I apply the extension of the basic Caliendo et al. (2019) model, as it considers the policy effects of the Social Security Disability Insurance (SSDI) program in the United States. In doing so, I borrow closely from the SSDI framework and modify the model to make it suitable for analyzing the effects of German labor market reform.

I add value through my empirical and counterfactual analysis. In particular, I conduct an analysis of the Hartz IV reform’s employment and welfare effects. Thereby, I answer the question: How would German employment and welfare have evolved, if the Hartz IV reform would not have taken place? I do this by constructing first a baseline economy where the data develop as they actually did. Second, I then construct a counterfactual economy for the case of the Hartz IV reform. By taking the difference between the baseline and the counterfactual economy I am able to identify the employment and welfare impact of the Hartz IV reform. In this regard, I undertake a comprehensive study of the German labor market effect that includes the county level and covers all 402 German counties (NUTS-3 level).

The time of interest of my analysis are the years between 2005 and 2014, as during that time the German labor market reforms were introduced. Hereby, I construct an input–output table for the German counties, compatible with the World Input–Output Database (WIOD). I follow the approach of Krebs and Pflüger (2018) and use the production value added data for each county. The data is obtainable from the regional statistic data (“Regionalstatistik”) of the German Federal and Regional Statistical Offices, Statistische Ämter des Bundes und der Länder (2020). It includes seven sectors, which are the sectors of interest in my analysis.Footnote 4 With those seven sectors I am able to construct the input–output table on the county level. Further I include a short-term unemployment sector and a sector for the long-term unemployment (“ALG II”).Footnote 5 To identify income taxes and the costs of the long-term unemployment benefit (“ALG II”) I rely on the data of the federal government budget (“Bundeshaushalt”). Employment, short-term unemployment and long-term unemployment data are provided by the Statistics of the Federal Employment Agency (“Bundesagentur f\(\ddot{\textrm{u}}\)r Arbeit”). In order to identify the movement of households across sectors and counties, I construct a labor mobility matrix. In addition, I identify the probabilities of households becoming employed, short-term unemployed and long-term unemployed.

My analysis shows, that without the labor market reform (Hartz IV) the German short-term unemployment would have been 0.4 percentage points larger. This is equivalent to a 385,000 decrease in the number of unemployed and explains a 25% decrease in unemployment between 2005 and 2014. Furthermore, I can demonstrate that welfare would decline as a result of the labor market reform, since the increased labor supply puts pressure on wages and thus reduces welfare. This is especially true for the East German counties.

In the empirical part of this paper, I am additionally interested in the employment effects of German labor market reform through the rise of the East. That is the increase in trade between Germany and Eastern Europe due to strong productivity growth in Eastern Europe and Germany. Figure 2 shows that the German imports from Eastern Europe and the German exports to Eastern Europe grew stronger since 2005 (up to the financial crisis in 2008/09), compared to the previous years. This is indicated by the fact that the actual German imports from and exports to Eastern Europe are lager since 2005 than the import and export trend (if the imports and exports of 2005 would rise as between 2004 and 2005).

Fig. 2
figure 2

Source World Bank (2021); Author’s own calculations

German Trade Development to Eastern Europe. The analysis in my study includes eleven Eastern European countries. Thus, the data on Eastern Europe (in this graph) include those same countries, namely Czech Republic, Hungary, Poland, Slovakia, Estonia, Latvia, Lithuania, Slovenia, Bulgaria, Croatia, Romania.

Dauth et al. (2014) find that the growing trade flows have led to net-employment gains in Germany, as new export opportunities economically stimulated regions with strong export-oriented sectors. Yet, other regions with sectors vulnerable to import competition experienced higher levels of unemployment triggered by the trade exposure. This led to unevenly distributed employment gains or even losses across different regions.Footnote 6 Dauth et al. (2021) suggest the rising productivity in Eastern Europe as a driving force behind the increasing trade flows.Footnote 7 Especially through the economic transformation the Eastern European productivity levels grew substantially, and hence, could have led to more pressure on the German labor market through increasing import competition. At the same time the German productivity grew as well and could have contributed to the increase in exports to Eastern Europe. However, less is known about the precise impact of productivity on the rising trade between Germany and Eastern Europe, and henceforth on the effects on the German labor market.

Depending on which effect prevails, the rise of the East can contribute to the decline in German unemployment and accelerate the effect of the Hartz IV reform. The question then becomes, how would the German labor market have reacted if the Hartz IV reform had taken place, but without the simultaneous rise of the East? In other words: How substantial would the marginal employment effects of the Hartz IV reform have been as a result of the rise of the East?

My focus is on eleven Eastern European countries, which are represented in the World Input–Output Database (WIOD) (Release 2016) by Timmer et al. (2015). Namely Czech Republic, Hungary, Poland, Slovakia, Estonia, Latvia, Lithuania, Slovenia, Bulgaria, Croatia and Romania. Since productivities play a crucial part in my study, I identify the precise productivity changes on the sectoral level driving the rising trade between Germany and Eastern Europe. I calibrate for Germany the changes in productivity that corresponds to the increase of Eastern European imports. For Eastern Europe I conduct the productivity changes, which are responsible for the import increase in Germany. I calibrate the productivity changes in two steps: In the first step, I use the instrumental-variable strategy by Autor et al. (2013) to conduct the predicted import changes for Germany and also for Eastern Europe, which arise from the productivity shocks. In the second step, I apply the iteration approach of Caliendo et al. (2019) to detect the productivity changes. By iteration the productivity changes are identified, when the predicted import changes match with the model’s import changes.

I then conduct the counterfactual simulation in the following manner, closely using the approach of the SSDI model: First, I carry out a counterfactual analysis in which the rise of the East happens, but the Hartz IV reform does not occur. Second by running a counterfactual analysis in which both the rise of the East and the Hartz IV reform do not take place. The difference between the two analyses then gives the marginal effects of the Hartz IV reform through rise of the East. I observe that the rise of the East leads to an additional positive contribution to the labor market, as employment increases by 0.05%. The largest impact is in the manufacturing sector, where 40,000 additional jobs are created.

My paper is based on several ideas from previous research. The approach of “dynamic hat algebra” used in my paper and developed by Caliendo et al. (2019) is based on the approach of relative changes of Dekle et al. (2008) and its “hat algebra”. Moreover, the applied Caliendo et al. (2019) model builds on the work of Eaton and Kortum (2002), Artuç et al. (2010) and Dvorkin (2014). It is linked to a strand of dynamic equilibrium models such as Artuc and McLaren (2010) and Dix-Carneiro (2014). Compared to the reduced form approach à la Autor et al. (2013), the general equilibrium framework of Caliendo et al. (2019) has several advantages: It allows for a comprehensive general equilibrium setting with input–output linkages and a spatial multi-country and multi-sector framework. Furthermore, it makes it possible to evaluate many different policy interventions. The general equilibrium framework enables analysis in multiple domains, e.g., employment and welfare effects in different labor markets. As Caliendo et al. (2019) point out that the reduced-form approach can only determine changes in workers in one labor market relative to another labor market. It is therefore more straightforward to examine aggregate welfare and employment effects in a general equilibrium framework. Muendler (2017) argues that the reduced-form approach delivers empirical results, albeit with less conclusiveness, and indicates that general equilibrium models provide clearer outcomes.

Concerning the effect of the Hartz reforms several major studies have been conducted. Using different approaches and matching models the results vary from an unemployment decrease of 0.1% estimated by Launov and Wälde (2013) to 2% by Hochmuth et al. (2021) and of 2.82% by Krause and Uhlig (2012) as well as around 3% by Hartung et al. (2018). Krebs and Scheffel (2014) discover an unemployment reduction through the German labor market reforms (Hartz I to Hartz IV) by around 3%. However, they trace a 2% decrease to the impact of Hartz I to Hartz III (e.g. restructuring and increasing the number of “jobcenters” as well as the establishment of “minijobs”) and a 1% reduction to Hartz IV. I am able to show that using the comprehensive dynamic general equilibrium model that takes into account multiple sectors and counties, the impact of Hartz IV might be smaller. In addition, I complement the literature with a detailed evaluation of the labor market reform at the level of German counties. As a further effect, I include the rise of the East (increase in trade between Germany and Eastern Europe due to productivity growth in Germany and Eastern Europe), which amplifies the employment impact of the Hartz IV reform. The most recognizable work on the German trade exposure of Eastern Europe with its effect on the German labor market has been explored in a series of papers by Dauth et al. (2014, 2017, 2021). However, they do not explore the underlying fundamentals of the rising trade flows, e.g. fall of trade costs and rise in productivity. Related work has explored the effect of the “China Shock” on the U.S. labor market. Autor et al. (2013, 2014) and Acemoglu et al. (2016) suggest the productivity growth in China led to the “China Shock”, whilst Pierce and Schott (2016) demonstrate that the reduction of trade barriers, e.g. China joining the World Trade Organization (WTO) in 2001, led to the growth of Chinese trade flows.

The structure of this paper is as follows: In Sect. 2, I introduce a long-term unemployment state into an otherwise standard dynamic trade model à la Caliendo et al. (2019). Section 3 provides a description of the calibration of the data necessary to numerically solve the model. In Sect. 4 I present my findings of the economic impact of the German labor market reform (Hartz IV) and the additional labor market effects due to the rise of the East. In Sect. 5 I conclude.

2 Model

The Caliendo et al. (2019) model is a dynamic version of a multi-sector, multi-country Ricardian trade model à la Eaton and Kortum (2002). It incorporates a spatial general equilibrium and allows for labor market dynamics via labor mobility. I closely follow the extension of the Social Security Disability Insurance (SSDI) model and include long-term unemployment benefits in the framework. The model further consists of many exogenous factors (fundamentals) which are constant or time-varying. To avoid the need to solve the fundamentals the model applies the equilibrium conditions in relative changes. Thus it includes the ”dynamic hat algebra” approach, which embeds the ”hat algebra” method of Dekle et al. (2008) in a time-varying environment. Regarding the mechanisms of the Hartz IV reform, it is argued that the Hartz IV reform has two main mechanisms that lead to a decrease in short-term unemployment via negative incentives. In the old labor market system, the unemployment benefits “Arbeitslosengeld” (60% of income) was paid for 12 and even up to 32 months. Afterwards the lower unemployment help “Arbeitslosenhilfe” (53% of income) was paid. Under the new system the “Arbeitslosengeld I” (60% of income) is only paid 12 months (in rare occasions 18 months). Hence, the unemployed would have an incentive to get a job. In addition, the long-term unemployment benefit “Arbeitslosengeld II” is much lower than the former unemployment help “Arbeitslosenhilfe” which gives an additional incentive for the unemployed to get into workforce again. In the model I focus on the effect of the “Arbeitslosengeld II” and not explicitly count for the time of the first mechanism.

2.1 Households

The model consists of a world with N regions labeled as n or i and of J sectors, indexed as j or k. As the model concentrates on the labor market reform in Germany regions can be seen as German counties. In the numerical analysis the German labor market model is incorporated into the multi-country context. A competitive labor market exists in each sector j of region n. Households can either be employed and work in sector j or they can be short-term unemployed (in “sector 0”) or long-term unemployed (in “sector A”). Representative consumers in region n that are employed in sector j get the market wage \(w_j^{nj}\) and provide in turn one-unit of labor. Depending on their preferences \(U(C_t^{nj})\), they can choose from a consumption bundle of final local goods \(C_t^{nj}\). The consumption bundle consists of local consumption goods \((c_t^{nj,k})\) from different sectors: \(C_t^{nj}=\prod \nolimits _{k=1}^J(c_t^{nj,k})^{\eta ^k}\), where \(\eta ^k\) is the share of final consumption of sector k and \(\sum ^J_{k=1}\eta ^k=1\). The households are forward looking and consider their potential future utility levels. This also includes the option of becoming short-term unemployed and even long-term unemployed.

The households decide, depending on the expected value, in what region-sector combination they want to provide their unit of labor. I apply a standard approach used in dynamic discrete choice models to solve the households’ optimization problem. A key to identify the lifetime utility plays the idiosyncratic shock \(\epsilon _t^{ik}\), which is standardized distributed Type I Extreme Value. In this context, the idiosyncratic shock can be interpreted as additional benefits the households receive, when moving into region i and sector k (including the short-term unemployment “sector 0”). However, the households do not know the value of the idiosyncratic shock beforehand.Footnote 8

The value of being employed in region n and sector j at time t is given by:

$$\begin{aligned} \begin{aligned} V_t^{nj}=U(C_t^{nj})+\upsilon (1-\alpha _{t+1}^{nj}) \log \Bigg (\sum _{i=1}^N\sum _{k=0}^J \exp (\beta V_{t+1}^{ik}-\tau ^{nj,ik})^{1/v}\Bigg )+\alpha _{t+1}^{nj} \beta V_{t+1}^{nA} \end{aligned} \end{aligned}$$
(2.1)

The discount factor is given by \(\beta\) and the scale variance of the idiosyncratic shock is denoted by \(\upsilon\). The second term is the expected value when working in any sector of any region. Hereby \(\tau ^{nj,ik}\) is the transition cost of moving from region n in sector j into region i and sector k. The third term is the expected value of being long-term unemployed. Thus, \(V_{t+1}^{nA}\) is the value of the long-term unemployed households in period \(t+1\). Furthermore, \(\alpha _{t+1}^{nj}\) is the probability that workers from region n of sector j end up in the long-term unemployed “sector”. Vice versa \((1-\alpha _{t+1}^{nj})\) is the probability that households in region n and sector j in that particular region-sector combination either earn an income above the ALG II threshold or are short-term unemployed.

The utility value for short-term unemployed households is

$$\begin{aligned} V_t^{n0}=\log b^{n}+\upsilon (1-\delta _{t+1})\log \Bigg (\sum _{i=1}^N\sum _{k=0}^J\exp {(\beta V_{t+1}^{ik}-\tau ^{nj,ik})}^{1/\upsilon }\Bigg )+\delta _{t+1} \beta V_{t+1}^{nA} \end{aligned}$$
(2.2)

The households in the short-term unemployment sector receive and consume the value of their home production \(b^{n}\). I assume the value of home production to be time invariant, as the home production value is less changing over time and therefore can be seen as a constant in the model. With a probability \(\delta _{t+1}\) the households become long-term unemployed,Footnote 9 while the probability \(1-\delta _{t+1}\) denotes the likelihood that households will not enter into ALG II in the next period. The second term indicates the expected value if one is moving to any sector in any region. This includes the possibility of being short-term unemployed denoted by \(k=0\). The third term represents the expected value if short-term unemployed households become long-term unemployed in the next period.

The value of the long-term unemployed households at time t can be written as

$$\begin{aligned} V_t^{nA}=\log (b_t^{A}/P_t^n)+(1-\rho _{t+1}^{nA})\beta V_{t+1}^{nj}+\rho _{t+1}^{nA}\beta V_{t+1}^{nA} \end{aligned}$$
(2.3)

Recipients receive long-term unemployed benefit of \(b_t^{A}\), which is time varying. Unlike the short-term unemployed benefit \(b^{n}\) (in terms of home production), the real long-term unemployed benefits \(b_t^{A}/P_t^n\) depend on the price index of the specific region n. With \(1-\rho _{t+1}^{nA}\), it is the probability that the households start working again, the second term denotes the expected value if the households will enter into the workforce. With the probability of \(\rho _{t+1}^{nA}\), the third term indicates the expected utility value if the households will stay in the long-term unemployment program.

2.2 Migration share and labor mobility

The share of moving households is given by

$$\begin{aligned} \mu _t^{nj,ik}=\frac{\exp (\beta V_{t+1}^{ik}-\tau ^{nj,ik})^{1/v}}{\sum _{m=1}^N\sum _{h=0}^J \exp (\beta V_{t+1}^{mh}-\tau ^{nj,mh})^{1/v}} \end{aligned}$$
(2.4)

which is the expected utility value a household would gain from moving to region i in sector k relative to the sum of the expected value of all sectors J and all regions N. In other words, region-sector combinations which have higher expected values attract more households than other region-sector combinations.Footnote 10

Next, I show how the employed, short-term unemployed and long-term unemployed mass of households evolve over time. The mass of employed households in period \(t+1\) in region n and sector j is given by:

$$\begin{aligned} L_{t+1}^{nj}=\sum _{i=1}^N\sum _{k \ne 0}^J \mu _t^{ik,nj}(1-\alpha _t^{ik})L_t^{ik}+\sum _{i=1}^N\mu _t^{i0,nj}(1-\delta )L_t^{i0}+(1-\rho _t^{nA})L_{t}^{nA}/J \end{aligned}$$
(2.5)

The first term is the mass of employed households, which earn enough to satisfy their basic needs. The second term represents the mass of short-term unemployed households that are moving into the workforce of sector j. The third term displays the mass of households which transfer from long-term unemployment into a new job in region n in sector j.Footnote 11 Further, the mass of households which are short-term unemployed is:

$$\begin{aligned} L_{t+1}^{n0}=\sum _{i=1}^N\sum _{k \ne 0}^J \mu _t^{ik,n0}(1-\alpha _t^{ik})L_t^{ik}+\sum _{i=1}^N\mu _t^{i0,n0}(1-\delta _t)L_t^{i0} \end{aligned}$$
(2.6)

It consists of the mass of employed households that become short-term unemployed and those households that stay short-term unemployed in period t. The number of households that are long-term unemployed in period \(t+1\) can be represented as:

$$\begin{aligned} L_{t+1}^{nA}=\rho _t^{nA}L_t^{nA}+\delta _t L_t^{n0}+\sum _{j \ne 0}^J\alpha _t^{nj} L_t^{nj} \end{aligned}$$
(2.7)

The first part is the mass of ALG II households that stay in the program, the second part shows the amount of short-term unemployed households getting into ALG II and the third part of the equation represents the mass of employed households earning too less and therefore are applicable for ALG II.Footnote 12

2.3 Production

On the production side, intermediate goods are produced with labor, materials, and structures. The structures are composite local factors; firms rent the structures from rentiers. The intermediate goods go into the production of local sectoral aggregate goods from the same sector. The local sectoral aggregate goods are then used by the firms either to produce intermediate goods or final goods. The firms’ productivities are Fréchet distributed and depend on the sectoral Fréchet distribution parameter \(\theta ^j\). The model then yields the remaining equilibrium conditions, following the SSDI extention:

Unit price of an input bundleFootnote 13

$$\begin{aligned} x_t^{nj}=B^{nj}((r_t^{nj})^{\xi ^n}(\omega _t^{nj})^{1-\xi ^n})^{\gamma ^{nj}}\prod \limits _{k=1}^J(P_t^{nj,nk})^{\gamma ^{nj,nk}} \end{aligned}$$
(2.8)

Price of the sectoral aggregate goodFootnote 14

$$\begin{aligned} P_t^{nj}=\Gamma ^{nj}\Bigg (\sum _{i=1}^N(x_t^{ij}\kappa _t^{nj,ij})^{-\theta ^j}(A_t^{ij})^{\theta ^j\gamma ^{ij}}\Bigg )^{-1/\theta ^j} \end{aligned}$$
(2.9)

Share of total expenditure

$$\begin{aligned} \pi _t^{nj,ij}=\frac{(x_t^{ij}\kappa _t^{nj,ij})^{-\theta ^j}(A_t^{ij})^{\theta ^j\gamma ^{ij}}}{\sum _{m=1}^N(x_t^{mj}\kappa _t^{nj,mj})^{-\theta ^j}(A_t^{mj})^{\theta ^j\gamma ^{mj}}} \end{aligned}$$
(2.10)

Total expenditureFootnote 15

$$\begin{aligned} \begin{aligned} X_t^{jn}&=\sum _{k=1}^J\gamma ^{nk,nj}\sum _{i=1}^N\pi _t^{ik,nk}X_t^{ik}\\&\quad +\eta ^j \Bigg ((1-\tau ^T_t)\sum _{k=1}^{J}\omega _t^{nk}L_t^{nk}+b_t^{A}L_t^{A}+\iota ^n \chi _t-G_t/N\Bigg ) \end{aligned} \end{aligned}$$
(2.11)

Labor market clearing in region n and sector j

$$\begin{aligned} L_t^{nj}=\frac{\gamma ^{nj}(1-\xi ^n)}{\omega _t^{nj}}\sum _{i=1}^N\pi _t^{ij,nj}X_t^{ij} \end{aligned}$$
(2.12)

Market clearing for structures in region n and sector j

$$\begin{aligned} H^{nj}=\frac{\gamma ^{nj}\xi ^n}{r_t^{nj}}\sum _{i=1}^N\pi _t^{ij,nj}X_t^{ij} \end{aligned}$$
(2.13)

2.4 Solving the model

The model consists of two types of equilibria. Equations 2.12.7 represent the sequential competitive equilibrium. These are dynamic equations in which households decide where to move depending on the evolution of real wages over time and across labor markets. The temporary equilibrium is composed of Eqs. 2.82.13. It is a static subproblem that solves prices and wages under the condition of labor supply in a given market. The model contains a large number of exogenous state parameters, and the amount of necessary parameters increases with each time period. These exogenous state parameters are defined as constant fundamentals \({\tilde{\Theta }}=(\Upsilon ,H,b)\) or time-varying fundamentals \(\Theta =(A_t,\kappa _t)\). To make the model more tractable, the concept of ”dynamic hat algebra” based on Dekle et al. (2008) is introduced. It transforms the equilibrium conditions into relative time differences. Thus, the baseline economy is constructed, with \(\dot{y}_{t+1}\equiv \Bigg (\frac{y^1_{t+1}}{y^1_{t}},\frac{y^2_{t+1}}{y^2_{t}},...\Bigg )\) as the relative change of a vector’s value y between two periods. This approach has the advantage that it does not require information about the initial fundamentals.

To perform the counterfactual analysis, the counterfactual equilibrium in relative time differences is introduced. That is, the counterfactual economy in relative time differences, which includes the change in policy, is set in relation to the baseline economy. In this setting, the ratio of time changes between the counterfactual variable \(y_{t+1}'\) and the baseline economy variable \(\dot{y}_{t+1}\) is given by \({\hat{y}}_{t+1}=\frac{\dot{y}_{t+1}'}{\dot{y}_{t+1}}\). To solve the counterfactual sequential equilibrium in relative time differences, requires the initial allocation of the economy \(\{L_t,\mu _{t-1},\pi _t,X_t\}_{t=0}^\infty\) and the baseline allocations in relative time differences \(\{\dot{L}_t,\dot{\pi }_t,{\dot{\mu }}_{t-1},\dot{X}_t\}_{t=0}^\infty\) as well as the changes in counterfactual fundamentals \(\{{\hat{\Theta }}_t\}_{t=1}^\infty\) as inputs. Moreover, for the counterfactual sequential equilibrium in relative time differences, and thus for the solution of the model, the conditions of the counterfactual temporary equilibrium must be satisfied for each period.

3 Data sources & measurement

In this chapter I concentrate on the empirical strategy to bring the data to the model. Thus, I pave the way to simulate the impact of the long-term unemployment benefit on employment in Germany. The strategy for the empirical simulation is provided in online appendix A.1, which involves the algorithm to solve the sequential competitive equilibrium and the algorithm for counterfactuals.Footnote 16 My analysis centers its attention on the German county-level “Kreisebene” which includes in total 402 counties. The sectors of interest consist of four manufacturing and three service sectors plus a short-term unemployment and a long-term unemployment sector. Moreover, the years after the introduction of the long-term unemployment benefit in 2005 are in the spotlight of my study (2005 to 2014). In the following Sect. 1 describe the data calibration of those parameters used in the simulation that have to be empirically determined.Footnote 17

3.1 Country- and county-trade data

As a main data source, I rely on the World Input–Output Database (WIOD) (Release 2016) by Timmer et al. (2015). I use the input–output data for the time period between 2005 and 2014, which cover in total 43 countries plus an aggregate of the rest of the world. To simulate the “rise of the East” I rely on the 11 eastern European countries provided in the data set: Czech Republic, Hungary, Poland, Slovakia, Estonia, Latvia, Lithuania, Slovenia, Bulgaria, Croatia and Romania. In addition, the data includes in total 56 sectors which are classified according to the ISIC Rev. 4.

However, since I am interested in the policy effects on the county level in Germany, I need the input–output data on the regional level. Unfortunately, the input–output data at this level is not available for Germany. Therefore, I construct the input–output table following the approach of Krebs and Pflüger (2018): Hereby, I use value added data on the county level from the “Regionalstatistik” of the German Federal and State Statically Office. I consider that the production value added share for each sector is constant, therefore it is possible to determine the county share for each sector in Germany. Through the county share I can construct the German input–output table at the county level, that is then put in alignment to the World Input–Output Database (WIOD). As the value added data of the regional statistic includes only seven sectors, I put my focus on these industries: Agriculture and forestry, fisheries (Sector 1); production industry without construction (Sector 2); manufacturing and processing (Sector 3); construction (Sector 4); trade, transport, hotels and restaurants, communication (Sector 5); financial, insurance services (Sector 6); public services, education, health services (Sector 7). To bring the input–output data on the sectoral level in alignment with the data of the World Input–Output Database (WIOD), I aggregate the 56 sectors to those seven described above. For the purpose of data preparation, eliminate the negative inventories using the approach of Costinot and Rodríguez-Clare (2014). I do this to avoid possible negative values when summing up for the final demand. In addition, I compute the bilateral trade flows and the gross outputFootnote 18 for the 43 countries plus the 402 German counties.

3.2 Population composition

The population composition consists of employed, short-term unemployed and long-term unemployed people, I am interested in the distribution of those groups on the county level.Footnote 19 Regarding the employment data \(L_t^{nj}\), I rely on the data “Besch\(\ddot{\textrm{a}}\)ftigungsstatistik” of the Federal Employment Agency. I aggregate the sectors to obtain the seven sectors used in my analysis. Data of short-term unemployment \(L_t^{n0}\) (according to SGB III people are short-term unemployed if they are out of work for up to 12 months) are taken from the statistics of the Federal Employment Agency as well.Footnote 20 As mentioned in the introduction, recipients of the long-term unemployment benefit do not necessarily have to be long-term unemployed to be applicable for the long-term unemployment benefit. To be applicable for the benefits people have to be able to work, but are not able to satisfy their basic material needs by their employment. Out of this group, people can be long-term unemployed recipients “arbeitslose Erwerbsf\(\ddot{\textrm{a}}\)hige Leistungsberechtigte” (over 12 months unemployed) and non-unemployed recipients “nicht-arbeitslose Erwerbsf\(\ddot{\textrm{a}}\)hige Leistungsberechtigte”. The group of non-unemployed recipients can consist of different cases: 1. People can be employed, but earn less than a certain minimum existence wage to be applicable. 2. People are able to receive “ALG II” benefit if they are in job training programs with the goal of getting into the workforce again (“in arbeitsmarktpolitischen Maßnahmen”). 3. People can be in school or in university and can receive under certain conditions “ALG II” benefit (“in Schule, Studium, ungef\(\ddot{\textrm{a}}\)rderter Ausbildung”). 4. People are in full-time caring for their family members (“in Erziehung, Haushalt, Pflege”). 5. People are unable to work (“in Arbeitsunf\(\ddot{\textrm{a}}\)higkeit”). 6. Under some conditions elderly people are applicable for “ALG II” benefit (§§428 SGB III/65 SGB II, 53a SGB II). As my analysis focuses on the employment effects, I consider, out of the mass of people which are in principle applicable for the “ALG II” benefit, those who are already working, but earn less than the minimum existence wage (“in ungef\(\ddot{\textrm{o}}\)rderter Erwerbst\(\ddot{\textrm{a}}\)tigkeit”) and those who are over 12 months long-term unemployed. Those two groups make up the majority of people who receive the “ALG II” benefit. I collect the data for each county from the statistics of the Federal Employment Agency.Footnote 21 In Table 1 I provide an overview of the development of the population composition in Germany.

Table 1 Overview uemployment, long-term uemployment and employment sares in Germany.

3.3 Probabilities

In this section let us turn to the probabilities that households are changing their status between employed, short-term unemployed and long-term unemployed. The probability that an employed person of region n of sector j at time t earns less than the minimum existence wage (“in ungef\(\ddot{\textrm{o}}\)rderter Erwerbst\(\ddot{\textrm{a}}\)tigkeit”) and therefore is applicable for the “ALG II” benefit is given by \(\alpha _t^{nj}\). In this case the person receives a certain part of the benefit, till the total income is equivalent to the amount of the primary “ALG II” benefit.Footnote 22 To calculate \(\alpha _t^{nj}\) I rely on the data of the statistics of the Federal Employment Agency for the years 2007 to 2014. Hereby I consider \(\alpha _t^{nj}\) at t for each year. The probability \(\alpha _t^{nj}\) is calculated as the share of people in unsubsidized employment (“in ungef\(\ddot{\textrm{o}}\)rderter Erwerbst\(\ddot{\textrm{a}}\)tigkeit”) in terms of total employment.Footnote 23 For the years 2005 and 2006 the dataset is restricted, therefore I construct the average of the years 2007 to 2014 for each sector and apply them for each sector in 2005 and 2006.

The probability that a short-term unemployed person at time t is longer than 12 months unemployed and therefore enters into the status of long-term unemployment is given by \(\delta _t\). In order to conduct \(\delta _t\) I use the unemployment data of the statistics of the Federal Employment Agency. I define \(\delta _t\) as the inflow of people who are short-term unemployed and are getting long-term unemployed compared to the total stock of short-term unemployed people at time t. As the data of inflows are only available at the national level, I consider \(\delta _t\) to be a constant for each region-sector combination. I construct \(\delta _t\) for the years 2005 to 2014. The inflow data as well as the stock data of short-term unemployed people are merely available for the years 2007 to 2014. For the years 2005 and 2006 only the stock data are available, for the inflow data I rely on the change rate between 2007 and 2008. I use this as a trend to construct the data for 2005 and 2006.

\(\rho _t^{nA}\) defines the probability that a person in region n who is long-term unemployed will stay in the long-term unemployed program and will further receive the long-term unemployed benefit. My focus of interest is again on the time between 2005 and 2014 for each county. I make use of the short-term and long-term unemployment data of the statistics of the Federal Employment Agency and use the outflow of people of long-term unemployment compared to the stock of the long-term unemployed.Footnote 24 However, the county data is only available for the years 2009 to 2014. For the years 2005 to 2008 I take the average of the years 2009 to 2014. In some cases data for sector-region combination are not available. Hence, I use the average of the previous year of the sector-region combination as an approximation.

3.4 Productivity shock

As the growing productivities of the Eastern European countries and Germany are thought to be possible drivers of the “rise of the East“, they play a crucial role in my simulation. I am specifically interested in those productivity changes, which are responsible for the increasing trade flows between Germany and Eastern Europe.

By applying the approach of Caliendo et al. (2019) I calibrate the productivity changes. For Germany, I conduct the changes in productivity corresponding with the rising imports into the eleven Eastern European countries. Vice versa I calibrate for each of those eleven Eastern European countries the productivity changes which cause the import increase to Germany (imports from the particular country into Germany). Moreover, I conduct for every country the productivity changes on the sectoral level. In order to attain the productivity changes two steps based on Caliendo et al. (2019) are necessary: First, I apply the instrumental-variable strategy of Autor et al. (2013) to get the predicted import changes for Germany and the eleven Eastern European countries respectively. In the second step I calibrate by iteration the productivity changes as the model;s import changes have to match with the predicted import changes. The instrumental-variable strategy of Autor et al. (2013) contains the import change from Germany (or one of the eleven Eastern European countries) by other advanced economies. At the core of the instrumental-variable strategy lies a first-stage regression:

$$\begin{aligned} \Delta M_{GER,j}=a_1+a_2\Delta M_{other,j}+u_j \end{aligned}$$
(3.1)

The dependent variable \(\Delta M_{GER,j}\) is the sectoral j import change in Germany for the years between 2005 and 2014, which the regression tries to predict by the explanatory variable. \(\Delta M_{other,j}\) is the sectoral change of imports by advanced countries. Following Caliendo et al. (2019) I use here Australia, Denmark, Finland, Japan and Spain as advanced economic countries and rely on the World Input Output Database (WIOD) as data source. For Germany, I find the coefficient \(a_2\) to be 3.058 with a standard error of 0.022 and a high R-squared of 0.99.Footnote 25 The regressions for each of the eleven Eastern European countries are similar:

$$\begin{aligned} \Delta M_{EE_i,j}=a_1+a_2\Delta M_{other,j}+u_j \end{aligned}$$
(3.2)

Where \(\Delta M_{EE_i,j}\) denotes the sectoral import change for each Eastern European country i in the same time period. Likewise, \(\Delta M_{other,j}\) is the change of sectoral j imports of the advanced economies between 2005 and 2014. The results are displayed in Table 2, most countries, besides Estonia and Latvia, have high R-squared values that indicate respectable prediction power.

Table 2 Coefficient Results for \(a_2\) (for Eastern European Countries).

After having estimated the coefficients I use the baseline economy and the counterfactual economyFootnote 26 of the model to calibrate the sectoral productivity changes for each of the eleven Eastern European countries and Germany. This is done by iteration to find the optimal productivity change of each sector and country in order that the model’s import changes matches the predicted import changes \(a_2\Delta M_{other,j}\) respectively. For Germany, I find a productivity change in “agriculture and forestry, fisheries” (Sector 1) of 0.1%; in “production industry without construction” (Sector 2) of 2,8%; in “manufacturing and processing” (Sector 3) of 3.4% and in “construction” (Sector 4) of 9.4%. The findings are supported by a high correlation between the model’s import changes and the predicted import changes \(a_2\Delta M_{other,j}\) of 0.998. The results of the sectoral productivity changes of the eleven Eastern European countries are displayed in the online appendix Table A.4.

3.5 Labor income tax & long-term unemployment benefit

The labor income tax \(\tau ^T_t\) plays a major role in financing the long-term unemployment benefit. The tax is levied on every German labor income. The total amount of labor income tax revenue various each year. To compute the labor income tax, I rely on the data of the federal budget (“Bundeshaushalt”). Thereby \(\tau ^T_t\) is composed by using the federal expenditure of the long-term unemployment benefit as a share of the total amount of income taxes. An overview of the development of the labor income tax for the years between 2005 and 2014 is provided in Table 3. Besides that, it is necessary for my analysis to identify the per capita long-term unemployment benefit \(b^A\) for the base year of 2005. By taking the data from statistics of the Federal Employment Agency I calculate a per capita expenditure for the recipients of 4080 Euro.Footnote 27 Having identified the labor income tax and the long-term unemployment benefit I can endogenously determine the lump sum tax/transfer \(G_t\) charged by the German rentiers by applying the equation of the government budget.

Table 3 Development of Labor Income Tax responsible for financing ALG II.

3.6 Share of value added in gross production

The share of the value added in gross production by sector j of region n (countries and counties) is denoted as \(\gamma ^{nj}\). In order to conduct the share of the value added in gross production for the 42 countries (without Germany) of the year 2005 I rely on the value added and gross production data provided by the socio-economic accounts (WIOD 2016 Release). For each country, I aggregate the 56 sectors of the dataset to fit the seven sectors used in my analysis. Regarding the aggregate of the “Rest of the World” of the World Input–Output Database (WIOD), I take the average of the 42 countries for each of those seven sectors. For the 402 counties in Germany I set up the share of the value added in gross production by applying the data from the regional statistic and of the German Federal and State Statistics Office. Especially for the manufacturing and processing (Sector 3) and construction sector (Sector 4) the value added and the gross production is available by the regional statistic.Footnote 28 For the other five sectors the value-added data is provided, however, I have no gross output data available on the county level. Therefore, I construct the value added in gross production of Germany from the socio-economic accounts for those sectors and apply those shares as a constant on the county level.Footnote 29

3.7 Share of structures in value added

The value-added share of structures is denoted as \(\xi ^n\). On the country level I make use of the socio-economic accounts (WIOD 2016 Release) to construct the share of structures in value added for each of the 42 countries (Germany not included) plus the aggregate of the “rest of the world” for the year 2005. The value-added share of structures is not directly taken from the data. However, as a work-around I use the relationship of one minus the share of labor compensation in value added which gives the value-added share of structures. I apply this relationship and use the labor compensation (in millions of national currency) and the gross value added at current basic prices (in millions of national currency) to identify the value-added share of structures for each country. As there is no data available for the aggregate of the “rest of the world” I use the average of the 42 countries as an approximation for the value-added share of structures. For the German county level, I make use of the regional statistics data of the German Federal and State Statistics Office. Since no data are available for the year 2005 I rely on the closest available data of 2004 to construct the value added share of structures. I apply the same approach as above for the relationship of the share of labor compensation in value added to identify the share of value added for the structures at the county level. I construct the share of labor compensation in value added by dividing the total amount of income per person in employment by the gross domestic product per person in employment of each county. For some counties data points are missing, thus, I use the average of the other German counties as an estimate.

3.8 Dispersion of sector productivity

In my analysis \(\theta\) reflects the dispersion of productivity of each sector. I rely on the values for Germany on the sector-specific productivity dispersion parameter of Aichele et al. (2014),Footnote 30 which are based on the approach of Eaton and Kortum (2002) and are Fréchet distributed. For agriculture and forestry, fisheries (Sector 1) I take the average of the dispersion of productivity of the grains & crops; cattle, sheep, goats, horses; forestry; fishing sectors in Aichele et al. (2014). The same approach holds true for the production industry without construction (Sector 2), manufacturing and processing (Sector 3); construction (Sector 4) as I rely on the respective sectors of Aichele et al. (2014). Regarding the service sectors: Trade, transport, hotels and restaurants, communication (Sector 5); financial, insurance services (Sector 6); public services, education, health services (Sector 7). I consider the approach of Egger et al. (2012) which is applied in Aichele et al. (2014) and Walter (2022). Hereby \(\theta\) can be considered a constant in the service sectors. Egger et al. (2012) estimate an inverse \(\theta\) of 5.959. This translates in my case to a \(\theta\) of 0.1678. Table 4 summarizes all dispersion productivity parameters used in my paper.

Table 4 Dispersion of German Sector Productivity.

3.9 Labor mobility & mobility elasticity

In order to estimate the labor mobility \(\mu\) for the years 2005 to 2014, I construct a matrix of counties-sector input-outflows. The matrix shows the mobility of labor across counties and sectors (including the short-term unemployed and long-term unemployed sector). The value of each element of the county-sector input-outflow matrix represents the probability that a household working in sector j of county n and will be doing work in this county-sector combination (of the element) in the following year. Hereby, I denote higher probabilities to the circumstance that the household will stay in the same sector j and the same county n in the next time period. I make further assumptions that when a household decides to move, it is more likely to move into another neighbor region but staying in the same sector. Moving to more distant regions further decreases the probability. Also changing jobs to less similar sectors (e.g. having a job in construction and moving to the financial sector is less likely) reduces the probability of the element. My assumptions are based on the findings of Dauth et al. (2021), who identify the labor mobility across the county and sector level in Germany by using the data of Integrated Labor Market Biographies (IEB) from the German Institute for Employment Research (2020). 70% of the workforce stay in the sector and do not move to a different county. Out of the remaining 30% I assume that roughly two-third stay in the same sector, but move into other counties.Footnote 31 The other one third consists of the people staying in the same county, but switching work to another sector (25%), the rest being people who move to other counties and switching work. My assumptions of the 30% of worker switching jobs and/or counties are differing to the findings of Dauth et al. (2021) which find that 10% get a new job in the same sector with or without switching counties, and the other 20% changing sectors with or without switching counties. As they consider 3-digit industry and I am only considering 7 sectors, my probability to stay in the same sector is higher than the finding of Dauth et al. (2021). In order to construct the mobility for short-term unemployed and long-term unemployed people I rely on the regional statistics data and as well the statistics of the Federal Employment Agency. Applying those assumptions, I denote for each possible element of the region-sector input-outflow matrix a certain probability, by which I can construct the labor mobility matrix \(\mu\) for 2005 to 2014. As an estimation for the mobility elasticity \(\nu\) I adopt the result of the annual rate of \(\nu = 2.02\) of Caliendo et al. (2019).

3.10 Discount interest rate

As my analysis relies on a dynamic model and considers the time change, it is necessary to identify the interest rates. In particular, \(\beta\) reflects the discount interest rate. To conduct the discount factor, I rely on the long-term interest-rate data from the OECD (2020) for the years 2005 to 2014. I find an average discount factor of annually 0.9687 and apply this value in my analysis.

4 Simulation

After having derived the key variables let us turn our attention to the analysis. In the following I present a short outline of the approach to conduct the simulation. Hereby the simulations build on the Caliendo et al. (2019) extension of the Social Security Disability Insurance (SSDI) program. I construct the baseline economy for the years 2005 and 2014 which consist of the development of the actual fundamentals. The baseline economy is needed to solve for the counterfactual equilibrium. In my counterfactual analysis I simulate the impact of the German labor market reform. In order to estimate the impact of the German labor market reform (in particular Hartz IV) I conduct the counterfactual economy. Specifically, I let the fundamentals develop as they did, but eliminate the parameters of the long-term unemployment benefit and cut the respective labor income tax.Footnote 32

4.1 Long-term unemployment benefit

I start by focusing on the impact of long-term unemployment benefits introduced as part of labor market reforms. My counterfactual question to answer is: What would have happened to the German labor market, if the long-term unemployment benefit would have been eliminated? Through this question I can examine the labor market changes due to Hartz IV. In addition, I examine the welfare implications of labor market reform. Figure 3 shows the effect of the long-term unemployment benefits on the German unemployment between 2005 and 2014.

Fig. 3
figure 3

Short-Term Unemployment Decrease due to the Long-Term Unemployment Benefit. The figures are based on the Author’s own calculations and rely on the data explained in chapter 3

Thus, the long-term unemployment benefit would account for an around 0.4% decrease in short-term unemployment.Footnote 33 That would correspond to an approximated reduction of unemployed people by 385,000 over time. This explains a 25% decrease in unemployment between 2005 and 2014. I further find that some sectors are profiting from the introduction of the long-term unemployment benefit as for example the employment of the manufacturing sector would increase by 0.15%. I also see an increase in the service sectors: Trade and commerce increase by 0.2%, public sector by 0.2% and finance sector by 0.08%. Other sectors as for example agriculture, production and construction would decrease in the long run, see online appendix A.5.

Fig. 4
figure 4

Change in Regional Unemployment Shares. The figures are based on the Author’s own calculations and rely on the data explained in chapter 3

Fig. 5
figure 5

Regional Contribution to total Short-Term Unemployment Decrease. The figures are based on the Author’s own calculations and rely on the data explained in chapter 3

Next, I present the findings for the impact of the long-term unemployment benefit introduction on the German county level. Figure 4 displays the decreasing regional short-term unemployment shares. The regional unemployment shares are more affected by the German labor market reform than counties in the west. Although, some counties, especially in Bavaria experience a stronger decline as well. However, as Fig. 5 shows, the counties in the East contribute more to the decline of aggregate unemployment in Germany. Berlin has with 1.25% the highest contribution to the total reduction of Germany’s unemployment.

Fig. 6
figure 6

Changes in Regional Manufacturing Shares. The figures are based on the Author’s own calculations and rely on the data explained in chapter 3

Fig. 7
figure 7

Regional Contribution to total Manufacturing Increase. The figures are based on the Author’s own calculations and rely on the data explained in chapter 3

The decrease of short-term unemployment leads to an increase of employment in other sectors. For the manufacturing sector I find an increase in the regional manufacturing share in Baden-Württemberg and Bavaria. In Mecklenburg-Western Pomerania and Brandenburg some counties experience the highest increase in the regional manufacturing share, which together with the named counties in the south contribute the largest to the aggregate increase of the manufacturing sector in Germany, see Figs. 6 and 7. Further, I discover a shift into the trade and commerce sector as well as into the public sector. I find a similar pattern for counties in the southern part of Germany as well as in Mecklenburg-Western Pomerania and Brandenburg that contribute the largest to the employment increase in those sectors.

Fig. 8
figure 8

Regional Welfare Effects. The figures are based on the Author’s own calculations and rely on the data explained in chapter 3

Fig. 9
figure 9

Manufacturing Welfare Effects. The figures are based on the Author’s own calculations and rely on the data explained in chapter 3

Next, I conduct a welfare analysis of labor market reform that looks at the overall change in real wages. Figure 8 shows the long-term percentage change in welfare in each county. I find that welfare falls by \(-\) 0.08% in the long run due to Hartz IV reform. Welfare is falling above all in the new federal states. Especially in the federal states of Saxony Anhalt, Saxony and Thuringia. The impact of the labor market reform on welfare in the western German counties is small and almost negligible. However, there are some exceptions, e.g. in Neunkirchen in Saarland, where welfare falls by \(-\) 0.12%. The labor market reform has a negative impact on welfare, because although the reform employs more people, the increase in labor supply puts pressure on wages, which has a negative impact on real wages. The increase in employment does reduce production costs, which lowers overall prices. However, these effects are smaller than the decline in wages, so that welfare falls. Particularly in the counties with higher employment effects of the Hartz IV reform, there is therefore a decline in overall welfare. Looking at the sectoral level, Fig. 9, the largest impact on employment, as mentioned above, is in manufacturing, which also generates the largest welfare effects at the regional level. In the manufacturing sector, welfare falls by \(-\) 0.1% on average. Here, again, it can be seen that welfare is declining most sharply in the eastern German counties. But welfare in the manufacturing sector is also declining overall in southern Germany, for example in Baden-Württemberg and Bavaria, where there is a strong manufacturing sector. But also in the counties of North Rhine-Westphalia due to the increase in labor supply.

4.2 Rise of the east

Having examined the effects of the Hartz IV reform, I want to turn to another possible cause of the decline in unemployment in Germany that occurred at the same time. As mentioned in the introduction, I will now focus on the joint analysis of the Hartz IV reform and the rise of the East. Since the rise of the East may have had an impact on the effects of the Hartz IV reform, I am interested in the labor market’s reaction to the Hartz IV reform due to the rise of the East.

To identify the effects, I first conduct a counterfactual analysis in which the rise of the East takes place, but the Hartz IV reform would not occur. In my second counterfactual analysis, I compute the analysis in which the rise of the East and also the Hartz IV reform do not occur. The difference between the two analyses then yields the marginal effects of the Hartz IV reform due to the rise of the East.

My first finding is that the overall employment effect of the rise of the East is positive. In doing so, I consider the overall effect of the rise of the East, i.e. the productivity growth of Germany and Eastern Europe. Analyzing and decomposing the effects of the respective productivities, I find that German productivity growth has a positive effect on the German labor market, while Eastern European productivity growth has a negative effect on the German labor market. However, the impact of German productivity growth is by far larger than that of Eastern European productivity growth.

Fig. 10
figure 10

German Productivity Effect on the German Labor Market (between 2005 and 2014). The figures are based on the Author’s own calculations and rely on the data explained in chapter 3

Figure 10 shows the contour of labor market effects in Germany. I find that the rise of the East makes a positive contribution to the labor market as employment increases by 0.05%. In particular, short-term unemployment falls by \(-\) 0.036% and long-term unemployment by \(-\) 0.014%. The change in employment is largely driven by manufacturing, as this sector records an increase of 0.041%. Other sectors vary only slightly. This corresponds to about 40,000 additional jobs in manufacturing and about 10,000 new jobs in the other sectors attributable to the rise of the East. In Fig. 11 the regional short-term unemployment shares decrease more strongly in Eastern German counties. Districts close to the Polish border are facing the strongest reduction of the regional unemployment shares, due to increasing exports to Eastern Europe. Counties in the north west experience almost no changes of the regional unemployment shares, while in the south the reduction of the regional unemployment shares varies between counties. As regards the weight of the aggregate reduction in short-term unemployment, counties in the east contribute the strongest to the decline, Fig. 12. Cities with a larger population as Berlin and Munich, but also Magdeburg and Dresden are the highest contributors in the reduction of unemployment.

Fig. 11
figure 11

Changes in Regional Unemployment Shares. The figures are based on the Author’s own calculations and rely on the data explained in chapter 3

Fig. 12
figure 12

Regional Contribution to total Short-Term Unemployment Decrease. The figures are based on the Author’s own calculations and rely on the data explained in chapter 3

Looking at the changes in regional shares of long-term unemployment as shown in Fig. 13, I find that due to the decline in the labor force in Saxony-Anhalt, Thuringia and Saxony, the share of long-term unemployment in these areas is growing. Together with larger cities such as Berlin, Leipzig and Dresden those counties are in fact contributing the most to the decline of the total long-term unemployment in Germany, Fig. 14. The manufacturing sector is highly impacted by the German productivity gain. Figure 15 shows that the manufacturing sector in the counties of North Rhine Westphalia and Hessen are profiting the most as a consequence of the productivity improvement. Especially Kassel is experiencing the highest growth of the regional manufacturing share with an increase of 0.3%. Likewise, some counties in the south are showing increasing regional manufacturing shares. However, regions in the east as well in Bavaria are mostly unaffected by a change, though some even display negative regional manufacturing shares. Further, I can show that those counties which have increasing regional manufacturing shares, add correspondingly to the aggregate employment rise of the manufacturing sector, see Fig. 16.

Fig. 13
figure 13

Changes in Regional Long-Term Unemployment Shares. The figures are based on the Author’s own calculations and rely on the data explained in chapter 3

Fig. 14
figure 14

Regional Contribution to total Long-term Unemployment Decrease. The figures are based on the Author’s own calculations and rely on the data explained in chapter 3

Fig. 15
figure 15

Changes in Regional Manufacturing Shares. The figures are based on the Author’s own calculations and rely on the data explained in chapter 3

Fig. 16
figure 16

Regional Contribution to total Manufacturing Increase. The figures are based on the Author’s own calculations and rely on the data explained in chapter 3

5 Conclusion

Germany has seen a rapid decline in unemployment after 2005. This paper attempts to shed more light on the causes of this development, focusing on the employment effects of the Hartz IV reform (especially the long-term unemployment benefit effect). In order to capture the full impact of labor market reform, my work builds on the dynamic spatial multi-country and multi-sector equilibrium Caliendo et al. (2019) model. I apply the model by including the structure of the long-term unemployment benefit in order to simulate the impact of the Hartz IV reform. I conduct a comprehensive study on the Hartz IV reform at the German county level, covering 402 German counties and 43 states with 7 sectors plus an unemployment sector and a long-term unemployment sector. To run the analysis, I use the World Input–Output Database (WIOD) and data from the German Federal and Regional Statistical Offices as well as the statistics from the Federal Employment Agency as the main data sources.

My main finding is that the Hartz IV reform reduces the short-term unemployment by 0.4%. Futher I find evidence that Hartz IV reform reduces short-term unemployment in eastern German counties. The results suggest that the long-term unemployment benefit (Hartz IV) certainly had its impact on the unemployment in Germany, though other parts of the Hartz reform (e.g. restructuring the Federal Labor Institution) could have played a major role as well.

Moreover, I identify a modest impact of the Hartz IV reform through the rise of the East. Without the productivity growth of the rise of the East the short-term unemployment would have been 0.036% larger. Dissecting the effects on employment I find that the labor market effects caused by the German productivity shock is larger than those of Eastern Europe.