Skip to main content
Log in

A comparison of family policy designs of Australia and Norway using microsimulation models

  • Published:
Review of Economics of the Household Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Many of the Australian family support schemes are income-tested transfers, targeted towards the lower end of the income distribution, whereas the Norwegian approach is to provide subsidized non-parental care services and universal family payments. We contrast these two types of policies and discuss policy changes within these policy types by presenting results from simulations, using microsimulation models developed for Australia and Norway. Labor supply effects and distributional effects are discussed for the hypothetical policy changes of replacing the means-tested family payments of Australia by the Norwegian universal child benefit schedule and vice versa, and of reducing the childcare fees in both countries. The analysis highlights that the case for policy changes is restricted by the economic environment and the role of family policy in the two countries. Whereas there is considerable potential for increased labor supply of Australian mothers, it may have detrimental distributional effects and is likely to be costly. In Norway, mothers already have high labor supply and any adverse distributional effects of further labor supply incentives occur in an economy with low initial income dispersion. However, expenditure on family support is already high and the question is whether this should be further extended.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Institutional subscriptions

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4
Fig. 5
Fig. 6

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. A disadvantage of using microsimulation is that it is a partial equilibrium approach which does not account for the potential effect of policy changes on other parts of the economy. For example, labor demand is not taken into account.

  2. According to Hotz and Scholz (2003), the EITC started as a universal anti-poverty program.

  3. A third type is the in-work benefit schedules present in the UK and in the US.

  4. For an approximate exchange rate between the Australian and Norwegian currencies, use 1AU$ ≈ 5NOK. In addition, with reference to exchange rates in June 2007: 1US$ ≈ 6NOK and 1AU$ ≈ 0.85US$.

  5. In the latest Federal Budget (May 2009), a national paid parental leave scheme was announced to be introduced in 2011. This will provide paid parental leave at the minimum wage level for 18 weeks.

  6. Deductions for childcare expenses are limited by an upper threshold; in 2007, this was set at NOK25,000 for the first child, to which NOK5,000 is added for each additional child.

  7. In 2008, the rebate percentage increased to 50% and the rebatable amount increased to AU$7,500.

  8. This may include some double counting, if children use more than one type of formal care.

  9. We use population totals for children aged 0–12 (ABS 2009).

  10. Some children start school at age 5 and others start school at 6. Therefore, in our calculations we use population totals for children aged 0–5 and children aged 0–4, respectively (ABS 2009).

  11. The 2003/2004 tax revenue was AU$209 billion (ABS 2005).

  12. We restrict the comparison to families with children aged between 1 and 4, because Australian children usually enter school at the age of 5 and many Norwegian mothers of infants are on paid parental leave in the first year.

  13. Estimates presented in Table 1 are derived using the data sources of the microsimulation model for Norway and Australia; see descriptions of LOTTE (Norway) in Aasness et al. (2007) and of the Melbourne Institute Tax and Transfer Simulator (Australia) in Buddelmeyer et al. (2007). Income is measured by equivalent income, which is derived by aggregating income over all household members and divided by an equivalence scale to allow for economies of scale. The equivalence scale is defined as the square root of the number of household members, children included (Buhmann et al. 1988). Each household is represented with as many persons as there are household members.

  14. The Norwegian sample consists of couple families in which the male partner works full-time.

  15. Several contributions handle quantity constraints in the labor supply literature; see for instance Kapteyn et al. (1990), Ilmakunnas and Pudney (1990) and Dickens and Lundberg (1993).

  16. Differences in the type of information available in data for the two countries have also influenced the modeling approach.

  17. It is the gross wage rate that enters the model, but it is the net wage rate that affects labor supply. Gross and net wage are often related in a non-linear way. Therefore the tax and transfer system in place will affect labor supply elasticities.

  18. This policy change will also affect families with older children who are eligible for child benefit, but here we focus on families with preschool children.

  19. It appears that the policy makers have decided to end waiting lists first, before considering further fee reductions. The efficacy of this strategy is supported by new estimates of the costs of this reform.

  20. For instance, the official estimate of costs reported in Kornstad and Thoresen (2006) was too low.

  21. This estimate is derived from a simulation without availability restrictions and may somewhat overestimate the access to care in 2007, therefore representing a potentially upwardly biased estimate of the effect from an increased tax base.

  22. The 2002–2003 payments were very similar to the current situation, except for the Child Care Tax Rebate, which was introduced in 2004–2005.

  23. To some extent, Rent Assistance is linked to receipt of the maximum rate of Family Tax Benefit.

  24. The labor supply model only predicts the labor supply changes for wage and salary workers between 15 and 64 years of age. Those who are self-employed, full-time students or disabled remain at their observed labor supply in the simulation.

  25. Changes in disposable income (net of childcare cost) are calculated at fixed labor supply levels. At the moment, the change in income when allowing for labor supply responses cannot be calculated for this simulation. However, given the small labor supply responses the results will be similar to the results assuming fixed labor supply.

  26. This reinforces the need for more information about social and cognitive outcomes of early education systems.

  27. Datta Gupta et al. (2008) discuss the positive and negative impacts of Nordic countries’ family-friendly policies on employment, wages, fertility, and children’s well-being more generally (that is, without a focus on Australia).

  28. This means that choices need to satisfy the Independence from Irrelevant Alternatives (IIA) property.

  29. This means that choices need to satisfy the Independence from Irrelevant Alternatives (IIA) property.

References

  • Aaberge, R., Dagsvik, J. K., & Strøm, S. (1995). Labor supply responses and welfare effects of tax reforms. Scandinavian Journal of Economics, 97, 635–659.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Aasness, J., Dagsvik, J. K., & Thoresen, T. O. (2007). LOTTE—The Norwegian tax-benefit model system. In A. Gupta & A. Harding (Eds.), Modelling our future: Population ageing, health and aged care, international symposia in economic theory and econometrics (Vol. 16, pp. 513–518). Amsterdam: Elsevier.

  • ABS. (2005). Taxation revenue, australia (reissue), 2003–04. Catalogue No. 5506.0, Canberra.

  • ABS. (2006). Yearbook Australia, 2005. Catalogue No. 1301.0, Canberra.

  • ABS. (2007). Births Australia, 2006. Catalogue No. 3301.0, Canberra.

  • ABS. (2009). Population by age and sex, Australian states and territories, Jun 2008. Catalogue No. 3201.0, Canberra.

  • Acs, G., & Toder, E. (2007). Should we subsidize work? Welfare reform, the earned income tax credit and optimal transfers. International Tax and Public Finance, 14, 327–343.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Averett, S. L., Gennetian, L. A., & Peters, H. E. (2005). Paternal child care and children’s development. Journal of Population Economics, 18, 391–414.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Berger, L. M., Hill, J., & Waldfogel, J. (2005). Maternity leave, early maternal employment and child health and development in the US. The Economic Journal, 115, F29–F47.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bergstrøm, T., & Blomquist, S. (1996). The political economy of subsidized day care. European Journal of Political Economy, 12, 443–457.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Blau, D. M., & Hagy, A. P. (1998). The demand for quality in child care. Journal of Political Economy, 106, 104–146.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Blau, F. D., & Kahn, L. M. (2007). Changes in the labor supply behavior of married women: 1980–2000. Journal of Labor Economics, 25, 393–438.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Blomquist, S., & Christiansen, V. (1995). Public provision of private goods as a redistributive device in an optimum income tax model. Scandinavian Journal of Economics, 97, 547–567.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Blundell, R., Duncan, A., McCrae, J., & Meghir, C. (2000). The labour market impact of the working families’ tax credit. Fiscal Studies, 21, 75–104.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brewer, M., Duncan, A., Shephard, A., & Suárez, M. J. (2006). Did working families’ tax credit work? The impact of in-work support on labour supply in Great Britain. Labour Economics, 13, 699–720.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brink, A., Nordblom, K., & Wahlberg, R. (2007). Maximum fee vs. child benefit: A welfare analysis of Swedish child-care fee reform. International Tax and Public Finance, 14, 457–480.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Buddelmeyer, H., Creedy, J., & Kalb, G. (2007). Tax policy design and behavioural microsimulation modelling. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.

    Google Scholar 

  • Buhmann, B., Rainwater, L., Schmaus, G., & Smeeding, T. M. (1988). Equivalence scales, well-being, inequality, and poverty: Sensitivity estimates across ten countries using the Luxembourg income study (LIS), DATABASE. Review of Income and Wealth, 34, 115–142.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cai, L., Kalb, G., Tseng, Y. P., & Vu, H. (2008). The effect of financial incentives on labour supply: Evidence for sole parents from microsimulation and quasi-experimental evaluation. Fiscal Studies, 29(2), 285–325.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Creedy, J. (1998). Means-tested versus universal transfers: Alternative models and value judgements. Manchester School of Economic and Social Studies, 66, 100–117.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Creedy, J., & Duncan, A. S. (2002). Behavioural microsimulation with labour supply responses. Journal of Economic Surveys, 16, 1–39.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Creedy, J., & Kalb, G. (2005). Discrete hours labour supply modelling: Specification, estimation and simulation. Journal of Economic Surveys, 19, 697–734.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dagsvik, J. K., & Strøm, S. (2006). Sectoral labor supply, choice restrictions and functional form. Journal of Applied Econometrics, 21, 803–826.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Datta Gupta, N., & Simonsen, M. (2007). Non-cognitive child outcomes and universal high quality child care. Institute for the Study of Labor (IZA) Discussion Paper No. 3188, Bonn.

  • Datta Gupta, N., Smith, N., & Verner, M. (2008). The impact of Nordic countries’ family friendly policies on employment, wages, and children. Review of Economics of the Household, 6, 65–89.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dearing, H., Hofer, H., Lietz, C., Winter-Ebmer, R., & Wrohlich, K. (2007). Why are mothers working longer hours in Austria than in Germany? A comparative microsimulation analysis. Fiscal Studies, 28, 463–495.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Del Boca, D., & Vuri, D. (2007). The mismatch between employment and child care in Italy: The impact of rationing. Journal of Population Economics, 20, 805–832.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Department of Education, Employment, Workplace Relations. (2008). 2006 Australian government census of child care services: Summary booklet. Canberra: Commonwealth of Australia.

    Google Scholar 

  • Department of Families, Community Services, Indigenous Affairs. (2005). 2004 Census of child care services: Summary booklet. Canberra: Commonwealth of Australia.

    Google Scholar 

  • Diamond, P. A. (1980). Income taxation with fixed hours of work. Journal of Public Economics, 13, 101–110.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dickens, W., & Lundberg, S. J. (1993). Hours restrictions and labor supply. International Economic Review, 34, 169–191.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Doiron, D., & Kalb, G. (2005). Demands for childcare and household labour supply in Australia. Economic Record, 81, 215–236.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Eibak, E. E. (2003). Undersøking om foreldrebetaling i barnehagar August 2003. Notater 2003/77, Statistics Norway (in Norwegian).

  • Eissa, N., & Hoynes, H. W. (2004). Taxes and the labour market participation of married couples: The earned income tax credit. Journal of Public Economics, 88, 1931–1958.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Förster, M. F., & Vleminckx, K. (2004). International comparisons of income inequality and poverty: Findings from the Luxembourg income study. Socio-Economic Review, 2, 191–212.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gottschalk, P., & Smeeding, T. M. (2000). Empirical evidence on income inequality in industrialized countries. In A. B. Atkinson & F. Bourguignon (Eds.), Handbook of income distribution (Vol. 1, pp. 261–307). New York: Elsevier-North Holland.

    Google Scholar 

  • Graafland, J. J. (2000). Childcare subsidies, labour supply and public finance: An AGE approach. Economic Modelling, 17, 209–246.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gregg, P., Washbrook, E., Propper, C., & Burgess, S. (2005). The effects of a mother’s return to work decision on child development in the UK. The Economic Journal, 115, F48–F80.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gustafsson, S., & Stafford, F. (1992). Child care subsidies and labor supply in Sweden. Journal of Human Resources, 27, 204–230.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Haan, P., & Wrohlich, K. (2007). Optimal taxation: The design of child-related cash- and in-kind benefits. Forthcoming German Economic Review.

  • Håkonsen, L. (2003). Child care subsidies and economic efficiency. Working Paper no. 17/2003, Telemark Research Institute.

  • Hotz, V. J., & Scholz, J. K. (2003). The earned income tax credit. In R. Moffitt (Ed.), Means-tested transfer programs in the United States (pp. 141–198). Chicago, London: The University of Chicago Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ilmakunnas, S., & Pudney, S. (1990). A model of female labour supply in the presence of hours restrictions. Journal of Public Economics, 41, 183–210.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Immonen, R., Kanbur, R., Keane, M., & Tuomala, M. (1998). Tagging and taxing: The optimal use of categorical and income information in designing tax/transfer schemes. Economica, 65, 179–192.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jaumotte, F. (2003). Labour Force participation of women: Empirical evidence on the role of policy and other determinants in OECD countries. OECD Economic Studies, No. 37, 2003/2.

  • Kalb, G. (2009). Children, labour supply and childcare: Challenges for empirical analysis. Forthcoming in Australian Economic Review.

  • Kalb, G., & Lee, W.-S. (2007). The effect of an alternative childcare subsidy on labour supply: A policy simulation. Australian Journal of Labour Economics, 10, 39–57.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kalb, G., & Lee, W.-S. (2008). Childcare use and parents’ labour supply in Australia. Australian Economic Papers, 47, 272–295.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kalb, G., & Thoresen, T. O. (2007). The case for labour supply incentives: A comparison of family policies in Australia and Norway. Melbourne Institute of Applied Economic and Social Research Working Paper No. 27/07, University of Melbourne.

  • Kalb, G., & Thoresen, T. O. (2009). Behavioural microsimulation: Labour supply and childcare use responses in Australia and Norway. In A. Harding, P. Williamson, & A. Zaidi (Eds.), New frontiers in microsimulation modelling. Surrey: Ashgate.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kaplow, L. (2007). Optimal income transfers. International Tax and Public Finance, 14, 295–325.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kapteyn, A., Kooreman, P., & van Soest, A. (1990). Quantity rationing and concavity in a flexible household labor supply model. The Review of Economics and Statistics, 72, 55–62.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kornstad, T., & Thoresen, T. O. (2004). Means-testing the child benefit. The Review of Income and Wealth, 50, 29–49.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kornstad, T., & Thoresen, T. O. (2006). Effects of family policy reforms in Norway: Results from a joint labour supply and childcare choice microsimulation analysis. Fiscal Studies, 27, 339–371.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kornstad, T., & Thoresen, T. O. (2007). A discrete choice model for labor supply and child care. Journal of Population Economics, 20, 781–804.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mehlum, H., Moene, K., & Torvik, R. (2006). Institutions and the resource curse. The Economic Journal, 116, 1–20.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Michalopoulos, C., & Robins, P. K. (2000). Employment and child care choices in Canada and the United States. Canadian Journal of Economics, 33, 435–470.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • OECD. (2006a). OECD factbook 2006—economic, environmental and social statistics. Paris: OECD.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • OECD. (2006b). OECD employment outlook. Paris: Boosting Jobs and Incomes.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Powell, L. M. (2002). Joint labor supply and childcare choice decisions of married mothers. The Journal of Human Resources, 37, 106–128.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ribar, D. C. (1995). A structural model of child care and the labor supply of married women. Journal of Labor Economics, 13, 558–597.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rosen, S. (1996). Public employment and the welfare state in Sweden. Journal of Economic Literature, 34, 729–740.

    Google Scholar 

  • Saez, E. (2002). Optimal income transfer programs: Intensive versus extensive labor supply responses. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 117, 1039–1073.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Statistics Norway. (2007a). Births http://www.ssb.no/english/subjects/02/02/10/fodte_en/.

  • Statistics Norway. (2007b). Day-care centres http://www.ssb.no/.

  • Van Soest, A. (1995). Structural models of family labor supply: A discrete choice approach. Journal of Human Resources, 30, 63–88.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Walker, J. (1996). Funding child rearing: Child allowance and parental leave. The Future of Children, 6, 122–136.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgments

This paper was written when the second author visited the Department of Economics and the Melbourne Institute of Applied Economic and Social Research at the University of Melbourne. Both institutions are gratefully acknowledged for their hospitality. A previous version of this paper was presented at the Australian Labour Market Research Workshop, 8-9 February 2007, and at the International Microsimulation Conference, 20–22 August 2007. We thank John Creedy, John K. Dagsvik, Prem Thapa and two anonymous referees for their comments on earlier versions of this paper and Tom Kornstad for assisting with the simulations for Norway. The first author also acknowledges the financial support of the Australian Research Council, which funded this research through a Discovery Project Grant (# DP0770567).

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Guyonne Kalb.

Appendices

Appendix 1

1.1 The Norwegian behavioral simulation model

The behavioral microsimulation model assumes that Norwegian families make choices among finite sets of job and care alternatives B and S, for which utility is defined as:

$$ U(C_{kr} ,H_{k} ,Q_{r} ,k,r) = \nu (C_{kr} ,H_{k} ,Q_{r} ) + \varepsilon^{*} (C_{kr} ,H_{k} ,Q_{r} ,k,r)\quad k \in B,\;r \in S, $$
(3)

where C kr is consumption/disposable income corresponding to job k and childcare arrangement r, H k is annual hours of work in job k for the mother, Q r is the quality of care alternative r, and ε *(C kr , H k , k, r) is a stochastic error term, which is allowed to vary both across combinations of care and job alternatives and across individuals, for instance accounting for unobserved care quality characteristics. The error terms are assumed to be both independent of observed characteristics and of each other, and distributed according to the extreme value distribution.Footnote 28 ν(..) is the deterministic component of the utility function while ε*(..) is the random component. The family’s budget constraint is determined as described in Eq. (1) in Sect. 4.1.

The sets of job and care alternatives, B and S, are represented by a common choice set D = D(HwM), which denotes the number of alternatives that the families face for working hours and hours of care H. That is, a fixed link between hours of work and hours of care is assumed, except for home-working mothers who may use non-parental care alternatives, although at this stage this is suppressed in the notation. It can be useful to think of the alternatives within D as packages: for working hours/hours of care H, families observe a number of job opportunities for the mother with wage rate w and other job attributes, and a number of care alternatives with fees M and care attributes, such as quality of care characteristics. Neglecting differences in wages and care prices across different choices for notational simplicity, it follows from the standard discrete choice model for utility maximizing behavior that the probability of choosing a job within D can be written as:

$$ \varphi_{H} = {\frac{{{ \exp }\left( {v(H,w,M)\theta_{H} } \right)}}{{\sum\nolimits_{x} {{ \exp }\left( {v(x,w,M)\theta_{x} } \right)} }}}, $$
(4)

where \( \theta_{H} \) represents the number of combinations within D and v(H, w, M) represents the utility of choosing a care/work combination with hours H.

Equation (4) shows that the choice model is analogous to a multinomial logit model, where the representative utility terms are weighted with the number of opportunities (\( \theta_{H} \)) at that utility, see also Dagsvik and Strøm (2006). However, as these opportunity densities are not observed, the empirical strategy implies estimating parameters reflecting differences in the number of opportunities across different choices along with parameters of the utility function.

In Kornstad and Thoresen (2007) the choice setting is further simplified by addressing choices between three types of care and five categories of working hours/hours of care. Let m symbolize the three modes of care: care at centers (m = 1); care by other paid providers (m = 2); and own/parental care (m = 3). Jobs are divided into groups according to working hours. The model distinguishes non-participation (j = 1); three levels of part-time work, corresponding to 1–16 h per week (j = 2), 17–24 h per week (j = 3) and 25–32 h per week (j = 4); and full-time work at over 32 h per week (j = 5). Then P hjm defines the probability that household h chooses a job with hours of work in group j and a childcare arrangement in mode m:

$$ P_{hjm} = {\frac{{{ \exp }\left( {\nu \left( {\tilde{C}_{hjm} ,\tilde{H}_{j} ,X_{h} } \right) + { \log }\left( {{{n_{jm} } \mathord{\left/ {\vphantom {{n_{jm} } n}} \right. \kern-\nulldelimiterspace} n}} \right)} \right)}}{{{ \exp }\left( {\nu \left( {\tilde{C}_{h13} ,\tilde{H}_{1} ,X_{h} } \right) + { \log }n_{13} } \right) + \sum\nolimits_{i = 1}^{5} {\sum\nolimits_{{l \in \Upomega_{h} }} {{ \exp }\left( {\nu \left( {\tilde{C}_{hil} ,\tilde{H}_{i} ,X_{h} } \right) + { \log }n_{il} } \right)} } }}}, $$
(5)

where jm = 13 represents the home care (no market work) alternative, and

$$ \Upomega_{h} = \left\{ {\begin{array}{*{20}c} { ( 1 )\quad } \hfill & {{\text{if}}\,{\text{household}}\,h\,{\text{is}}\,{\text{constrained}}\,{\text{in}}\,{\text{the}}\,{\text{market}}\,{\text{for}}\,{\text{care}}\,{\text{at}}\,{\text{centers}}} \hfill \\ { ( 1 , 2 )\quad } \hfill & {\text{otherwise}} \hfill \\ \end{array} } \right. . $$
(6)

\( \tilde{H}_{j} \) is the median working time in hours of work group j, \( \tilde{C}_{jm} \) is consumption corresponding to working time \( \tilde{H}_{j} \) and X h is a taste-modifying variable. The key notion of (latent) differences in choice sets is captured by \( \Upomega_{h} \), stating some households have more limited choices, as center-based care is not available to them, and by the choice opportunities n jm , which indicate that the number of opportunities in each care and work category may vary compared to the baseline (n). An unobserved individual effect (random effect) is introduced in the representation of wages.

The deterministic part of preferences is represented by a “Box-Cox” type utility function:

$$ v\left( {\tilde{H}_{j} ,\tilde{C}_{hjm} } \right) \equiv \gamma_{0} {\frac{{\tilde{C}_{hjm}^{{\alpha_{1} }} - 1}}{{\alpha_{1} }}} + {\frac{{\left( {1 - {\frac{{\tilde{H}_{j} }}{T}}} \right)^{{\alpha_{2} }} - 1}}{{\alpha_{2} }}}X_{h} \beta , $$
(7)

where T = 8760 is the total number of annual hours, γ 0 , α 1, α 2 and β are parameters, and X h is the number of children below 19 years of age. The utility function is quasi-concave if α 1 < 1 and α 2 < 1. If α 1 → 0 and α 2 → 0, the utility function converges to a log-linear function.

Appendix 2

2.1 The Australian behavioral simulation model

The behavioral microsimulation model assumes that Australian families make choices among a finite set of hours worked, for which utility is defined as:

$$ U(C_{{h_{1} h_{2} }} ,h_{1} ,h_{2} ) = \nu (C_{{h_{1} h_{2} }} ,h_{1}, h_{2} ) + \varepsilon^{*} (h_{1} ,h_{2} )\quad {\text{with}}\,h_{1} \in \{ 0,h_{11} , \ldots ,h_{1n} \} ,h_{2} \in \{ 0,h_{21} , \ldots ,h_{2m} \} ,$$
(8)

where \( C_{{h_{1} h_{2} }} \) is consumption/disposable income (exclusive of childcare expenditure) corresponding to the male partner working h 1 hours and the female partner working h 2 hours and \( \varepsilon^{*} \left( {h_{1} ,h_{2} } \right) \) is a stochastic error term, which is allowed to vary both across combinations of hours of work of both partners and across individuals. The error terms are assumed to be independent of observed characteristics and of each other, and are distributed according to the extreme value distribution.Footnote 29 ν(..) is the deterministic component of the utility function while ε*(..) is the random component. The family’s budget constraint is determined as described in Eq. (2) in Sect. 4.1. Childcare is only included through the budget constraint.

It follows from the standard discrete choice model for utility maximizing behavior that the probability of choosing labor supply h 1 and h 2 can be written as:

$$ P_{{h_{1} h_{2} }} = {\frac{{{ \exp }\left( {v(C_{{h_{1} h_{2} }} ,h_{1} ,h_{2} )} \right)}}{{\sum\nolimits_{i = 0}^{n} {\sum\nolimits_{j = 0}^{m} {{ \exp }\left( {v(C_{{h_{1i} h_{2j} }} ,h_{1i} ,h_{2j} )} \right)} } }}} .$$
(9)

The deterministic part of preferences is represented by a quadratic utility function:

$$ \begin{aligned} \nu (C_{{h_{1} h_{2} }} ,h_{1} ,h_{2} ) = & \beta_{C} (C_{{h_{1} h_{2} }} - \gamma_{1} - \gamma_{2} ) + \beta_{1} h_{1} + \beta_{2} h_{2} + \alpha_{CC} (C_{{h_{1} h_{2} }} - \gamma_{1} - \gamma_{2} )^{2} + \alpha_{11} h_{1}^{2} + \alpha_{22} h_{2}^{2} + \\ & \alpha_{C1} (C_{{h_{1} h_{2} }} - \gamma_{1} - \gamma_{2} )h_{1} + \alpha_{C2} (C_{{h_{1} h_{2} }} - \gamma_{1} - \gamma_{2} )h_{2} + \alpha_{12} h_{1} h_{2}, \\ \end{aligned}$$
(10)

where the αs and βs are preference parameters and γ1 and γ2 are the fixed cost of working parameters to be estimated (where the indices 1 and 2 denote the husband and wife, respectively). The fixed cost is zero when the relevant person is not working. Observed heterogeneity can be included by allowing β1, β2, β C , γ1 and γ2 to depend on personal and household characteristics. Unobserved heterogeneity can be added to β1, β2, β C , and γ2, in the form of a normally distributed error term with zero mean and unknown variance. The model is estimated using simulated maximum likelihood. In estimation, the unobserved heterogeneity parameters were found to be insignificant and were dropped.

Probability distributions of labor supply for Australia are obtained using a user-specified number of random draws (100 in our case) rather than use Eq. 9 since this allows us to calibrate to observed hours. The deterministic component of utility, \( \nu (C_{{h_{1} h_{2} }} ,h_{1} ,h_{2} ) \), is obtained using the parameter estimates of the quadratic preference function. To generate the random component of utility, a draw is taken from the distribution of the error term for each hours level (an Extreme Value Type I distribution). The utility-maximizing hours level is found by adding the two components of utility for each hours level and choosing the hours with the highest utility. Draws from the error terms are taken conditionally on the observed labor supply; that is, they are taken in such a way that the optimal pre-reform labor supply is equal to the actually observed labor supply. As a result, the post-reform labor supply outcome is computed conditional on the observed pre-reform labor supply. Using the repeated draws, an empirical probability distribution for the hours of work can be constructed at the individual level and aggregated up to the population level. The probability distribution can then be used to simulate expected labor supply responses or changes in expenditure at the individual level which can then again be aggregated up to the population level.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Kalb, G., Thoresen, T.O. A comparison of family policy designs of Australia and Norway using microsimulation models. Rev Econ Household 8, 255–287 (2010). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11150-009-9076-3

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11150-009-9076-3

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation