Skip to main content
Log in

Imagined futures: fictional expectations in the economy

  • Published:
Theory and Society Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Starting from the assumption that decision situations in economic contexts are characterized by fundamental uncertainty, this article argues that the decision-making of intentionally rational actors is anchored in fictions. “Fictionality” in economic action is the inhabitation in the mind of an imagined future state of the world and the beliefs in causal mechanisms leading to this future state. Actors are motivated in their actions by the imagined future and organize their activities based on these mental representations. Since these representations are not confined to empirical reality, fictional expectations are also a source of creativity in the economy. Fictionality opens up a way to an understanding of the microfoundations of the dynamics of the economy. The article develops the notion of fictional expectations. It discusses the role of fictional expectations for the dynamics of the economy and addresses the question of how fictional expectations motivate action. The last part relates the notion of fiction to calculation and social macrostructures, especially institutions and cultural frames. The conclusion hints at the research program developing from the concept of fictional expectations.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Institutional subscriptions

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. This is not to deny the crucial role of routine behavior also in economic contexts (Camic 1986; Tappenbeck 1999, p. 48). The discussion here, however, refers only to a type of action in which actors are reflexive in the sense that they make decisions based on a deliberate consideration of alternatives, weighted against each other with regard to the desirability of their expected outcomes.

  2. Though fictional expectations do exist in all spheres of social life, I would hypothesize that they are more volatile in economic contexts of capitalist societies, because behavior in this sphere is less normatively regulated. This contingency of expectations is a foundation for the innovativeness of capitalist economies but is also a cause of its restlessness and susceptibility to crises stemming from rapid fluxes in expectations.

  3. In part, this is a problem of lack of thoroughness of economic analysis (Hellwig 1998, p. 719ff.). However, the problem cannot be reduced to superficiality of analysis. In practical terms, actors are simply overburdened and therefore cannot take all relevant information into account (Elster 2009). And with regard to novelty, the necessary information for optimizing decisions is simply not available at the time of decision making (Dequech 2003).

  4. Structuralist theories in economic sociology are closely related to economics if they consider networks and technologies to be the basis for the possibility of rational calculation (Callon 1998; Callon and Munesia 2005).

  5. According to Neil Fligstein (2001, p. 112), the identities of actors—that is, their interpretation of the structures of the world—are not fixed but emerge in the process of social interaction. Sabel and Zeitlin (1997, p. 15) argue that actors define “themselves strategically in the very act of constituting their context” because context is not objectively given but established through the definition of the situation carried out by the actors who are acting in these structures. The economics of conventions (Favereau and Lazega 2002) assumes the simultaneous presence of different conventions, making it necessary for actors to decide which convention holds in a specific situation, a decision that takes place in the action process and is potentially conflictual.

  6. Script following and imagination can also take place in situations with certainty and risk. Traditional action (Weber [1922] 1978) or wishful thinking would be examples. Given the assumption of intentional rationality these cases are not further explored here.

  7. In discussions of the financial crisis the term “fictional” is often used to describe fraudulent misrepresentations of economic facts. It is important to note that this is not how the term is used here.

  8. Because of this, literary texts wear their fictionality on their sleeve, while non-literary fictions hide it. As Wolfgang Iser (1993, pp. 12–13) emphasizes: “In the self-disclosure of its fictionality, an important feature of the fictional text comes to the fore: it turns the whole of the world organized in the text into an ‘as-if’ construction”.

  9. Fictionality, moreover, allows the attribution of qualities to goods that exist only as imaginaries. This is of crucial importance in understanding the sources of consumer demand, especially in economies that are saturated in functional terms. Examples of where this aspect of imaginaries can be studied particularly well are the valuation of antiques, art, wine, and so on. This aspect of fictionality is not discussed in this article. See, however, Beckert (2011).

  10. With hindsight, such point predictions mostly turn out to be wrong. However, based on the theoretical considerations developed here, it would be a categorical mistake to mock such forecasts for being wrong. They are necessarily wrong because the future cannot be foreseen. The much more interesting perspective is to analyze the functions of such forecasts (and other forms of fictional expectations) for structuring action in the present.

  11. As Volkmann (2001, p. 15) elaborates with reference to Wolfgang Iser, the act of fictionalizing converts the diffuseness of the imaginary into a gestalt. Fictionalizing “provides the imaginary with a determinacy that it would otherwise not possess” (ibid.).

  12. Research on narrative representations is also important in historiography (Anderson 1983). Since this research refers to the past it is not considered here. Our interest here lies in stories used to depict future events imaginatively.

  13. That expectations under conditions of uncertainty are fictions also finds confirmation in the status of the ratings of rating agencies. After ratings had proved to be wrong in the financial crisis of 2008, rating agencies stressed in their defense that their ratings are nothing but “opinions”. While this was an excuse to avoid legal liability, it also confirms the argument developed here: assessments of the future in highly complex conditions are no more than “pretensions”.

  14. The influence of fictional depictions of future states on investments is not limited to financial markets; it is a much wider phenomenon. It shows itself, for instance, in the bequest of wealth (Beckert 2008), the buying of life insurance (Zelizer 1979, p. 595f.), the purchase of lottery tickets (Beckert and Lutter 2009), or investments in education motivated by imaginaries of intergenerational upward mobility, supported by collective narratives such as the “American dream”.

  15. See also Zbaracki (2004, p. 17) who shows, based on ethnographic work in a large industrial firm, that price-setting practices make use of economic price theory. But rather than determining prices, the theory has influence because it is used to legitimate the position advocated by a group of managers in the negotiations. “Price theory may serve as a rational myth” used by actors to orient themselves in a complex situation.

  16. Psychological theories (Beach and Mitchell 1987) distinguish between several mental “images” through which knowledge is represented: The self-image, consisting of personal beliefs and values; the trajectory-image, depicting a desirable future; the action-image, portraying the sequences of actions needed to achieve the desirable future; and the projected-image, which depicts the anticipated results of the action.

  17. For investigations in economic sociology on the role of emotions see Bandelj (2009), Barbalet (1998), Beckert (2006), Berezin (2005), DiMaggio (2002), and Pixley (2004).

  18. This is also supported by findings from neuroscience that show that the brain regions activated when imagining pleasurable events are the same as the ones activated when actually experiencing these events (Costa et al. 2010; Speer et al. 2009).

  19. Again, there seems to be a parallel to fictional literature that can also produce “quasi emotions” (Walton 1990, p. 37) in the reader who empathizes with the fate of the characters.

References

  • Akerlof, G. A., & Shiller, R. (2009). Animal spirits. How human psychology drives the economy, and why it matters for global capitalism. Princeton: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Allais, M. (1953). Le comportement de l’homme rationnel devant le risque: critique des postulats et axiomes de l’école Américaine. Econometrica, 21, 503–546.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Anderson, B. (1983). Imagined communities: reflections on the origin and spread of nationalism. London: Verso.

    Google Scholar 

  • Augier, M., & Kreiner, K. (2000). Rationality, imagination and intelligence: some boundaries in human decision-making. Industrial and Corporate Change, 9, 659–681.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bacharach, M., & Gambetta, D. (2001). Trust in society. In K. S. Cook (Ed.), Trust in society (pp. 148–184). New York: Russel Sage.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bandelj, N. (2009). Emotions in economic action and interaction. Theory and Society, 38, 347–366.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Barbalet, J. (1998). Emotion, social theory, and social structure: a macrosociological approach. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

  • Barbalet, J. (2010). Action theoretic foundations of economic sociology. Kölner Zeitschrift für Soziologie und Sozialpsychologie. Sonderband, 49, 143–157.

    Google Scholar 

  • Beach, L. R., & Mitchell, T. R. (1987). Image theory: Principles goals, and plans in decision making. In Acta Psychologica 66.

  • Beckert, J. (1996). What is sociological about economic sociology? Uncertainty and the embeddedness of economic action. Theory and Society, 25, 803–840.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Beckert, J. (2002). Beyond the market. The social foundations of economic efficiency. Princeton: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Beckert, J. (2003). Economic sociology and embeddedness. How shall we conceptualize economic action? Journal of Economic Issues, 37, 769–787.

    Google Scholar 

  • Beckert, J. (2005). Trust and the performative construction of markets. Köln: Max-Planck-Institut für Gesellschaftsforschung. MPIfG Discussion Paper 05/8.

    Google Scholar 

  • Beckert, J. (2006). Was tun? Die emotionale Konstruktion von Zuversicht bei Entscheidungen unter Ungewissheit. In A. Scherzberg (Ed.), Kluges Entscheiden. Disziplinäre Grundlagen und interdisziplinäre Verknüpfungen (pp. 123–141). Tübingen: Mohr Siebeck.

    Google Scholar 

  • Beckert, J. (2008). Inherited wealth. Princeton: Princeton University Press.

  • Beckert, J. (2011). The transcending power of goods. In J. Beckert & P. Aspers (Eds.), The worth of goods (pp. 106–128). Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Beckert, J. (2013). Capitalism as a system of fictional expectations. Toward a sociological microfoundation of political economy. Politics and Society (forthcoming).

  • Beckert, J., & Lutter, M. (2009). The inequality of fair play. Lottery gambling and social stratification in Germany. European Sociological Review, 25, 475–488.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Berezin, M. (2005). Emotions and the economy. In N. J. Smelser & R. Swedberg (Eds.), Handbook of economic sociology (pp. 9–127). New York: Russell Sage.

    Google Scholar 

  • Berger, P. L., & Luckmann, T. (1966). The social construction of reality: A treatise in the sociology of knowledge. Garden City: Anchor Books.

    Google Scholar 

  • Boulding, K. E. (1956). The image. Ann Arbor: The University of Michigan Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bronk, R. (2009). The romantic economist. Imagination in economics. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Brown, J. S., et al. (2005). Storytelling in organizations. Burlington: Elsevier Butterworth-Heinemann.

    Google Scholar 

  • Buchanan, J., & Vanberg, V. ([1984] 2008). The market as a creative process. In D. Hausmann (Ed.), The philosophy of economics (pp. 379–398). Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

  • Bunia, R. (2010). Was ist Fiktion? Kunstforum, 202, 46–53.

    Google Scholar 

  • Burgdorf, A. (2011). Virtualität und Fiktionalität—Überlegungen zur Finanzwelt als “Vorstellungsraum”. In C. Künzel & D. Hempel (Eds.), Finanzen und Fiktionen (pp. 107–118). Frankfurt/M: Campus Verlag.

    Google Scholar 

  • Callon, M. (Ed.). (1998). The laws of the markets. Oxford: Blackwell Publishers.

    Google Scholar 

  • Callon, M., & Munesia, F. (2005). Economic markets as calculative collective devices. Organization Studies, 26, 229–1250.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Camerer, C. F., Loewenstein, G., & Rabin, M. (Eds.). (2003). Advances in behavioral economics. Princeton: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Camic, C. (1986). The matter of habit. The American Journal of Sociology, 91, 1039–1087.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Castoriadis, C. (1998). The imaginary institution of society. Cambridge: MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Coleman, J. S. (1990). Foundations of social theory. Cambridge: Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Coleridge, S. T. (1817). Biographia Literaria. <http://www.gutenberg.org/cache/epub/6081/pg6081.html>.

  • Costa, V. D., et al. (2010). Emotional imagery: assessing pleasure and arousal in the brain’s reward circuitry. Human Brain Mapping, 31, 1446–1457.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Czarniawska, B. (1997). Narrating the organisation. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Dequech, D. (2003). Conventional and unconventional behavior under uncertainty. Journal of Post Keynesian Economics, 26, 145–168.

    Google Scholar 

  • Dequech, D. (2006). The new institutional economics and the behaviour under uncertainty. Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, 59, 109–131.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dewey, J. (1957). Human nature and conduct. An introduction to social psychology. New York: The Modern Library.

    Google Scholar 

  • Dewey, J. ([1938] 1998). The pattern of inquiry the essential John Dewey. Bloomington: Indiana University Press, 169–179.

  • Diaz-Bone, R., & Krell, G. (Eds.). (2009). Diskurs und Ökonomie. Wiesbaden: VS Verlag für Sozialwissenschaften.

    Google Scholar 

  • DiMaggio, P. (2002). Endogenizing “animal spirits”: toward a sociology of collective response to uncertainty and risk. In M. F. Guillén et al. (Eds.), The new economic sociology. Developments in an emerging field (pp. 79–100). New York: Russell Sage.

    Google Scholar 

  • DiMaggio, P., & Powell, W. (1983). The iron cage revisited: institutional isomorphism and collective rationality in organizational fields. American Sociological Review, 48, 147–160.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dobbin, F. (2001). How institutional economics is killing microeconomics. Economic Sociology Listserve.

  • Dobbin, F. (2004). The sociological view of the economy. In F. Dobbin (Ed.), The new economic sociology. A reader (pp. 1–46). Princeton: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Elster, J. (2009). Excessive ambitions. Capitalism and Society, 4, 1–30.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Esposito, E. (2007). Die Fiktion der wahrscheinlichen Realität. Frankfurt a.M: Suhrkamp.

    Google Scholar 

  • Favereau, O., & Lazega, E. (2002). Conventions and structures in economic organization. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.

    Google Scholar 

  • Fligstein, N. (2001). Social skill and the theory of fields. Sociological Theory, 19, 105–125.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Foucault, M. (1970). The order of things: An archeology of the human sciences. New York: Vintage Books.

    Google Scholar 

  • Friese, H. (2001). Imagination: History of the concept international encyclopedia of the social and behavioral sciences (pp. 7197–7201). Oxford: Elsevier Publishers.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Garfinkel, H. (1967). Studies in ethnomethodology. Cambridge: Polity Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gold News (2011). <http://goldnews.bullionvault.com/gold_price_111020117>.

  • Granovetter, M. (1985). Economic action and social structure: the problem of embeddedness. American Journal of Sociology, 91, 481–510.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Granovetter, M. (2005). The impact of social structure on economic outcomes. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 19, 33–50.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Güth, W., & Kliemt, H. (2010). (Un)Eingeschränkt rational entscheiden in Geschäft und Moral. In Berlin Brandenburgische Akademie der Wissenschaften (Ed.), Preis der Berlin-Brandenburgischen Akademie der Wissenschaften gestiftet von der Commerzbank Stiftung. Preisverleihung am 19. Oktober 2009: Weyma Lübbe. Berlin: BBAW.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hellwig, M. (1998). Discussion on international contagion: what is it and what can be done against it? Swiss Journal of Economics and Statistics, 134, 715–739.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hellwig, M. (1999). Zur “volkswirtschaftlichen Verantwortung” der Banken. In F. Jaeger (Ed.), Die volkswirtschaftliche Verantwortung der Banken. Rüegger: Chur.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hellwig, M. (2008). Systemic risk in the financial sector: An analysis of the subprime-mortgage financial crisis (Vol. 157). Bonn: Max Planck Institute for Research on Collective Goods. Preprints of the Max Planck Institute for Research on Collective Goods Bonn 2008/43.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hirschman, A. (1986). Rival views of market society. New York: Viking.

    Google Scholar 

  • Holmes, D. R. (2009). Economy of words. Cultural Anthropology, 24, 381–419.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Iser, W. (1993). The fictive and the imaginary: Charting literary anthropology. Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Joas, H. (1996). The creativity of action. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Karpik, L. (2010). Valuing the unique. The economics of singularities. Princeton: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Keynes, J. M. ([1936] 1964). The general theory of employment, interest, and money. London: MacMillan.

  • Keynes, J. M. ([1937] 1973). The general theory of employment. In: The collected writings of J.M. Keynes. London: Macmillan, 109–123.

  • Knight, F. H. ([1921] 1985). Risk, uncertainty, and profit. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

  • Koselleck, R. (1988). Vergangene Zukunft: Zur Semantik geschichtlicher Zeiten. Frankfurt/M: Suhrkamp Verlag.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kraemer, K. (2010). Propheten der Finanzmärkte. Zur Rolle charismatischer Ideen im Börsengeschehen. Berliner Journal für Soziologie, 20, 179–201.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Künzel, C., & Hempel, D. (2011). Finanzen und Fiktionen. Frankfurt/M: Campus Verlag.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lucas, R. (1972). Expectations and the neutrality of money. Journal of Economic Theory, 4, 103–124.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • MacKenzie, D., & Millo, Y. (2003). Constructing a market, performing theory: the historical sociology of a financial derivatives exchange. The American Journal of Sociology, 109, 107–145.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mahony, J. (2000). Path dependence in historical sociology. Theory and Society, 29, 507–548.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • March, J. G. (1995). The future, disposable organizations and the rigidities of imagination. Organization, 2, 427–440.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Marx, K. ([1846] 1998). The German ideology. Oxford: Blackwell.

  • McCloskey, D. (1985). The rhetoric of economics. Madison: The University of Wisconsin Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • McCloskey, D. (1990a). If you’re so smart. The narrative of economic expertise. Chicago: The University of Chicago Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • McCloskey, D. (1990b). Storytelling in economics. In D. Lavoie (Ed.), Economics and hermeneutics. New York: Routledge.

    Google Scholar 

  • Merton, R. (1957). Social theory and social structure. Glencoe: The Free Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mische, A. (2009). Projects and possibilities: Researching futures in action. Sociological Forum, 24, 694–704.

    Google Scholar 

  • Miyazaki, H. (2003). The temporalities of the market. American Anthropologist, 105, 255–265.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Möllering, G. (2006). Trust: reason, routine, reflexivity. Oxford: Elsevier.

    Google Scholar 

  • Morris, P. E., & Hampson, P. (1983). Imagery and consciousness. London: Academic.

    Google Scholar 

  • Münnich, S. (2011). Interest-seeking as sense-making: ideas and business interests in the new deal. European Journal of Sociology, 52, 277–311.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Muth, J. F. (1961). Rational expectations and the theory of price movements. Econometrica, 29, 315–335.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mützel, S. (2010). Koordinierung von Märkten durch narrativen Wettbewerb. Kölner Zeitschrift für Soziologie und Sozialpsychologie. Sonderband, 49, 87–106.

  • Nelson, S., & Katzenstein, P. J. (2010). Uncertainty and risk and the crisis of 2008. Ithaca: Cornell University.

    Google Scholar 

  • Nye, D. E. (2004). Technological prediction. In M. Sturken, D. Thomas, & S. J. Ball-Rokeach (Eds.), Technological visions (pp. 159–185). Philadelphia: Temple University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Orléan, A. (2005) The self-referential hypothesis in finance. Paris.

  • Orléan, A. (2008). Knowledge in finance: objective value versus convention. Paris.

  • Orléan, A. (2011). L’Empire de la Valeur. Paris: Editions du Seuil.

    Google Scholar 

  • Parsons, T. (1951). The social system. London: Routledge.

    Google Scholar 

  • Pascal, B. ([1672] 1958). Pensées. New York, NY: E. P. Dutton & Co., Inc.

  • Patalano, R. (2003). Beyond rationality: Images as guide-lines to choice. Torino: University of Torino. Vol. 05/2003.

  • Piotti, G. (2009). German companies engaging in China. Decision-making processes at home and management practices in Chinese subsidiaries. Köln: Max-Planck-Institut für Gesellschaftsforschung. MPIfG Working Paper 09/14.

    Google Scholar 

  • Pixley, J. (2004). Emotions in finance: Distrust and uncertainty in global markets. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Putnam, R. A. (2006). Democracy and value inquiry. In J. R. Shook & J. Margolis (Eds.), A companion to pragmatism (pp. 278–289). Malden: Blackwell Publishing.

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Pylyshyn, Z. W. (2003). Seeing and visualizing: It’s not what you think. Cambridge: MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Riles, A. (2010). Collateral expertise. Current Anthropology, 51, 1–25.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Roeckelein, J. E. (2004). Imagery in psychology: A reference guide. Westport: Praeger Publishers.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sabel, C. F., & Zeitlin, J. (1997). Stories, strategies, structures: Rethinking historical alternatives to mass production. In C. F. Sabel & J. Zeitlin (Eds.), World of possibilities. Flexibility and mass production in western industrialization (pp. 1–33). Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Salmon, C. (2007). Storytelling. La machine à fabriquer des histoires et à formater les esprits. Paris: La Découverte.

    Google Scholar 

  • Schumpeter, J. (1912). Theorie der wirtschaftlichen Entwicklung. Berlin: Duncker & Humblot.

    Google Scholar 

  • Schütz, A. (2003). Das Problem der Personalität in der Sozialwelt. Bruchstücke. In R. Grathoff, H.-G. Soeffner, & I. Srubar (Eds.), Alfred Schütz Werkausgabe: Theorie der Lebenswelt 1. Die pragmatische Schichtung der Lebenswelt (pp. 91–177). Konstanz: UVK Verlagsgesellschaft mbH.

    Google Scholar 

  • Searle, J. (1975). The logical status of fictional discourse. New Literary History, 6, 319–332.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Shackle, G. L. S. (1961). Decision, order and time in human affairs. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Shackle, G. L. S. (1964). General thought-schemes and the economist. Woolwich: Woolwich Polycentric Press. Woolwich Economic Paper 2.

    Google Scholar 

  • Shackle, G. L. S. (1979). Imagination and the nature of choice. Edinburgh: Edinburgh University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Shiller, R. J. (2000). Irrational exuberance. Princeton: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Simon, H. (1957). Models of man. New York: Wiley.

    Google Scholar 

  • Soros, G. (1998). The crisis of global capitalism: Open society endangered. New York: PublicAffairs.

    Google Scholar 

  • Speer, N., et al. (2009). Reading stories activates neural representations of visual and motor experiences. Psychological Science, 20, 989–999.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Stark, D. (2009). The sense of dissonance: Accounts of worth in economic life. Princeton: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Storper, M., & Salais, R. (1997). Worlds of production. Cambridge: Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sturken, M., & Thomas, D. (2004). Introduction. Technological visions and the rhetoric of the new. In M. Sturken, D. Thomas, & S. J. Ball-Rokeach (Eds.), Technological visions (pp. 3–18). Philadelphia: Temple University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Swedberg, R. (2008). The sociological study of hope and the economy: Introductory remarks. Ithaca: Cornell University.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tappenbeck, I. (1999). Phantasie und Gesellschaft. Zur soziologischen Relevanz der Einbildungskraft. Würzburg: Königshausen und Neumann.

    Google Scholar 

  • Vaihinger, H. ([1911] 2007) Die Philosophie des Als Ob. Saarbrücken: VDM Verlag.

  • van Lente, H., & Rip, A. (1998). Expectations in technological developments: An example of prospective structures to be filled in by agency. In C. Disco & B. van der Meulen (Eds.), Getting new technologies together. Studies in making sociotechnical order (pp. 203–229). Berlin: de Gruyter.

    Google Scholar 

  • Volkmann, C. (2001). Organization theory and literary theory: Strange encounters. Exeter: School of Business & Economics. Vol. 03/01.

  • Walton, K. (1990). Mimesis as make believe: On the foundations of the representational arts. Cambridge: Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Weber, M. ([1920] 1988). Die Wirtschaftsethik der Weltreligionen. In M. Weber (Ed.), Gesammelte Aufsätze zur Religionssoziologie I. Tübingen: J.C.B. Mohr/Siebeck UTB, 237–573.

  • Weber, M. ([1922] 1978). Economy and society. Berkeley: University of California Press.

  • White, H. (1992). Identity and control. A structural theory of social action. Princeton: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Whitford, J. (2002). Pragmatism and the untenable dualism of means and ends: why rational choice theory does not deserve paradigmatic privilege. Theory and Society, 31, 325–363.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Zbaracki, M. J. (2004). Pricing structure and structuring price. Philadelphia: University of Pennsylvania.

    Google Scholar 

  • Zelizer, V. (1979). Morals and markets: The development of life insurance in the United States. New York: Columbia University Press.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgments

I would like to thank the two anonymous Theory and Society reviewers for their very helpful comments. For comments on earlier versions of this article I would like to thank David Dequech, Christoph Deutschmann, Arne Dreßler, Martin Hellwig, Sebastian Kohl, Sophie Mützel, and Werner Rammert.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Jens Beckert.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Beckert, J. Imagined futures: fictional expectations in the economy. Theor Soc 42, 219–240 (2013). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11186-013-9191-2

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11186-013-9191-2

Keywords

Navigation