Growth of government and the politics of fiscal policy

https://doi.org/10.1016/S0954-349X(02)00007-3Get rights and content

Abstract

US government expenditures increased rapidly during the post-war period, then slowed in the 1980s and began falling in 1992. To examine the dynamics of the growth and subsequent reduction in government spending, we present a general equilibrium growth model in which politicians chose government spending to maximize support by their constituents. That is, output and government spending are endogenous and jointly determined. The model predicts that government expenditures will initially mimic Wagner's law—the tendency for government spending to increase with GDP—but eventually diverge from output due to the growth of the welfare state. After government expenditures become large, we identify an endogenous threshold on the economy's growth path where it is optimal for politicians to shrink the welfare state, cut taxes, and stimulate output growth. We show that the policies chosen by politicians are Pareto suboptimal and cause endogenous cycles in output. Such cycles are of several types, and we characterize when the equilibrium growth path will result in a reduction in the size of the welfare state, as well as when the welfare state cycles between small and large.

Introduction

Between 1929 and 2000 US real GDP grew at an average rate of 3.4% a year. During the same time period, real government outlays (federal, state and local) grew at an average of 3.2% a year. Writing in 1893, Adolph Wagner posited that increased political pressures would accompany the development of modern industrial societies, giving rise to a continual expansion of the public sector. When government spending grows faster than output, ‘Wagner's law’ is said to hold. Empirical tests of Wagner's law for developed countries affirm its existence.1 Modern explanations for this finding range from extensions of the franchise which reduced the income of the median voter and increased transfers (Meltzer and Richard, 1981, Husted and Kenny, 1997) and enfranchised women (Lott and Kenny, 1999), to legislative self-oversight (Miller and Moe, 1983) and increasing centralization (Borcherding, 1985), to more extensive government monitoring required in an increasingly complex economy (Chapell and Keech, 1985) and a complicated tax structure (Becker and Mulligan, 1998), to the role of government agencies and size of bureaucracy (Wilson, 1989), to an aging population which increased transfers (Azariadis and Lambertini, 1997).2 The raison d’être of this paper is that the sources of government growth cannot be understood without examining the motivations of those setting policy. Further, policy determination must account for the interdependence between fiscal policy and output growth.

Conducting empirical tests for the period 1929–2000, we show in Section 2 that Wagner's law does not hold for the US. Fig. 1 informally demonstrates this by plotting aggregate real government expenditures—not including defense expenditures—as a percentage of real GDP.3 The figure partitions the data into four distinct regions. Though the data are noisy before WWII, Wagner's law appears to hold from 1945 to 1975. This relationship starts to breakdown after 1975 as government spending slowed markedly while output growth accelerated, invalidating the presumed co-movement between them. More starkly, US aggregate government expenditures began to fall in 1992, with this decline continuing through the present, while output growth during the 1990s was extraordinarily high.

Taking the trend depicted in Fig. 1 as a point of departure, this paper constructs a political theory of the composition of government expenditures within a neoclassical growth model to explain the pattern of aggregate government expenditures. The theory shows that over subperiods, Wagner's law holds as the growth of the ‘welfare state’ exceeds output growth.4 We demonstrate that after government expenditures become a large proportion of the economy, a threshold emerges at which politicians optimally reduce the size of the welfare state—at least temporarily—in order to maintain positive output growth. The model thus predicts an endogenous switch in the time trend of government expenditures, just as US data show. The catalyzing factor driving these results is the choice by politicians of both the level and composition of government expenditures which is made to maximize support from their constituents. When politicians set policy, we show that the size of the welfare state oscillates. We characterize the sources and types of oscillations, and show that after the welfare state shrinks, there are strong incentives for its subsequent growth.

Comparing the equilibrium dynamics induced by politically motivated policy-setting to Pareto optimal policies and constant policies, we show that political policies not only are Pareto-suboptimal, but result in distinctly different dynamic paths for the economy. Indeed, Pareto optimal policies produce endogenous growth in which the economy never reaches a steady state, while politically motivated policies and constant policies lead to steady states in per capita income. Perhaps most interestingly, political incentives cause the equilibrium path of the economy to exhibit cycles. Output oscillations arise in an economy that would otherwise have a monotone growth path, and are the direct result of politically motivated policy-setting.

The paper is structured as follows. Section 2 discusses the results of cointegration tests of real US government expenditures and GDP. These tests reject Wagner's law which motivates the model of policy-setting in a dynamic economy presented in Section 3. In Section 3 we derive politically-motivated policy choices and characterizes both the aggregate impact of such policies and the size of the welfare state. Section 4 draws implications from the analysis and concludes.

Section snippets

Motivation

This section tests whether Wagner's law is borne out in the US using annual data from 1929 to 2000. We include this test to motivate a theoretical model that explains and (predicts) not only the secular growth of government, but also downturns, and cycles.5

Politicians and policy

Because politicians determine government expenditures, fiscal flows reflect their objectives. In particular, we model politicians as choosing a set of fiscal policies to maximize the support of their constituents.14 One way that politicians maintain constituent support is to raise voters’ incomes through enacted policies. There is robust

The dynamics of politically motivated policies

In this section, we characterize the dynamics of an economy in which politicians set policy. The aggregate implications of such policies are compared to constrained Pareto optimal policies as well as outcomes with constant policies. In order to keep the dynamics tractable, we consider an economy in which savings is a fixed proportion of income, as in Solow (1956).

The capital market equilibrium condition is given byKt+1=sȲt+(1−δ)Ktwhere s∈(0,1) is the savings rate, and Y is income net of taxes

Discussion and conclusion

The implications of the model in this paper taken as a whole demonstrate that policies that are optimal from politicians’ point of view may be detrimental to the economy. These findings are consistent with the intuition that political incentives produce suboptimal policies, but the dynamics of this suboptimality that we find—the existence of thresholds and cycles—is indicative of the extent to which government policies affect aggregate economic dynamics. This is especially true since cyclic

Acknowledgements

We thank Helge Berger, Tom Borcherding and Arthur Denzau, two anonymous referees, as well as participants as the 1997 Midwest Macro and the 1998 Public Choice conferences for useful comments on this paper which was originally circulated under the title ‘Wagner's law, Fiscal Illusion, and The Politics of Fiscal Policy.’ Chetan Ghate thanks the Chapman Fund at Colorado College for support.

References (69)

  • J. Ashworth

    Spurious in Mexico: a comment on Wagner's law

    Public Finance/Finances Publiques

    (1994)
  • Azariadis, C., Lambertini, L., 1997. The Fiscal Politics of Big Governments. UCLA Working...
  • J. Barro Robert

    Government spending in a simple model of endogenous growth

    Journal of Political Economy

    (1990)
  • R.F. Baumgartner et al.

    Agendas and Instability in American Politics

    (1993)
  • N. Beck

    The Fed and the political business cycle

    Contemporary Policy Issues

    (1992)
  • Becker, G.S., Mulligan, C.B., 1998. Deadweight Costs and the Size of Government. NBER Working Paper...
  • T. Besley et al.

    Sources of inefficiency in a representative democracy: a dynamic analysis

    American Economic Review

    (1998)
  • M. Bohl

    Some international evidence on Wagner's law

    Public Finance

    (1996)
  • J.M. Buchanan et al.

    Democracy in Deficit: The Political Legacy of Lord Keynes

    (1977)
  • J.M. Buchanan

    Toward analysis of closed behavioral systems

  • H. Chapell et al.

    A new view of political accountability for economic performance

    American Political Science Review

    (1985)
  • L.S. Davidson et al.

    Testing the satisficing version of the political business cycle: 1905-1984

    Public Choice

    (1992)
  • A.T. Denzau et al.

    Legislators and interest groups: how unorganized interests get represented

    American Political Science Review

    (1986)
  • A. Dixit et al.

    Redistributive politics and economic efficiency

    American Political Science Review

    (1995)
  • R.F. Engle et al.

    Cointegration and error correction: representation, estimation, and testing

    Econometrica

    (1987)
  • B.S. Frey et al.

    Towards a mathematical model of government behavior

    Zeitschrift fur Nationalokonomie

    (1968)
  • M.P. Fiorina

    Retrospective Voting in American National Elections

    (1981)
  • N. Gemell

    Wagner's law, relative prices, and the size of the public sector

    The Manchester School

    (1990)
  • G.M. Grossman et al.

    Intergenerational redistribution with short-lived governments

    Economic Journal

    (1998)
  • Hayakawa, T., Zak, P.J., 2002. Debt, Death and Taxes, International Tax and Public Finance, 9 (2),...
  • B. Hayo

    No further evidence on Wagner's law for Mexico

    Public Finance/Finances Publiques

    (1994)
  • Henrekson, M., 1990. An Economic Analysis of Swedish Government Expenditure. Vasastadens Bokbinderi...
  • M. Henrekson

    Wagner's law: a spurious relationship

    Public Finance

    (1993)
  • C.M. Holsey et al.

    Why does government's share of national income grow? an assessment of the recent literature on the US experience

  • Cited by (25)

    • Testing threshold cointegration in Wagner's Law: The role of military spending

      2016, Economic Modelling
      Citation Excerpt :

      Few studies analyse very long time spans and generally reject WL. Henrekson (1993) and Bohl (1996) find no support for WL in Sweden from 1861 to 1990 or in the United Kingdom from 1870 to 1995, respectively; Ghate and Zak (2002) do not find any empirical evidence in the United States from 1929 to 2000; Durevall and Henrekson (2011) find direct evidence in favour of WL only for Sweden and the United Kingdom for a time period from around 1860 to 1970. There are, however, shorter time spans during which WL holds.

    • The welfare state, thresholds, and economic growth

      2005, Economic Modelling
      Citation Excerpt :

      This implies that a structural break in χ—say from χL to χH—induces a structural break in θ from Eq. (10) in period t. This paper undertakes an empirical test of the model of economic growth and the welfare state developed by Ghate and Zak (2002). By using a Hamilton regime switching model on an exhaustive list of welfare state economies, our main finding is that structural breaks in the growth rate of several welfare state economies can be attributed to a structural break in the trend growth of the welfare state variable.

    • Wagner on government spending and national income: A new look at an old relationship

      2019, Journal of Policy Modeling
      Citation Excerpt :

      If the law is strongly supported, then government spending or budget size increases at a more rapid rate than economic growth, consequently government is likely to be forced to quit a flexible fiscal policy or to borrow excessively (Funashima & Hiraga, 2017). Previous studies on the Wagner Law can be classified into three groups: first, studies finding support for Wagner’s Law (e.g., Ahsan, Kwan, & Sahni, 1996; Akitoby, Clements, Gupta, & Inchauste, 2006; Bairam, 1992; Kolluri, Panik, & Wahab, 2000; Lin, 1995; Mohammadi, Cak, & Cak, 2008; Murthy, 1993; Nagarajan & Spears, 1990; Narayan, Nielsen, & Smyth, 2008; Oxley, 1994; Ram, 1992; Zaghini & Lamartina, 2008; Ono, 2014; Barra, Bimonte, & Spennati, 2015), second, studies finding qualified support for Wagner’s Law, i.e., those studies which include additional variables and some especial types of expenditure (e.g., Arpaia & Turrini, 2008; Bairam, 1995; Biswal, Dhawan, & Lee, 1999; Bohl, 1996; Chang, 2002; Chow, Cotsomitis, & Kwan, 2002; Courakis, Moura-Roque, & Tridimas, 1993; Olekalns, 1999; Payne & Ewing, 1996; Magazzino, 2012), and third, studies not finding support for Wagner’s Law (e.g., Burney, 2002; Chletsos & Kollias, 1997; Ghate & Zak, 2002; Hayo, 1994; Halicioglu, 2003; Henrekson, 1993; Huang, 2006; Katrakilidis and Tsaliki, 2009; Kolluri & Wahab, 2007; Narayan et al., 2008; Shelton, 2007; Wahab, 2004; Ziramba, 2008; Durevall & Henrekson, 2011; Moore, 2016). Thus, over the past three decades, numerous studies focus on several countries and time periods by applying the concepts of cointegration (linear and nonlinear) and causality.

    • Government spending and its components in Italy, 1862–2009: Drivers and policy implications

      2017, Journal of Policy Modeling
      Citation Excerpt :

      Henrekson (1993) and Bohl (1996) find no support for WL in Sweden from 1861 to 1990 and in the UK from 1870 to 1995. Ghate and Zak (2002) do not find any empirical evidence in the USA from 1929 to 2000. Durevall and Henrekson (2011) find that in both the UK and Sweden WL does not hold in the long run (i.e., in the years 1800–2006 for Sweden and 1830–2006 for the UK); there are, however, two shorter time spans during which WL holds: approximately 1860–1913 and 1920–1975 for both countries.

    View all citing articles on Scopus
    View full text