Optimal lending contracts with long run borrowing constraints

https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jedc.2013.01.003Get rights and content

Abstract

This paper discusses two variations to the optimal lending contract under asymmetric information studied in Clementi and Hopenhayn (2006). One variation assumes that the entrepreneur is less patient than the bank, and the other assumes the bank has limited commitment. The qualitative properties of the two modified contracts are very similar. In particular, both variations lead to borrowing constraints that are always binding such that the firm is financially constrained throughout its life cycle and subject to a positive probability of being liquidated eventually.

Introduction

A considerable body of empirical evidence suggests that many firms are constrained in their borrowing and borrowing constraints can be important determinants of firm dynamics.1 Recent attempts to analyze, theoretically, the impact of borrowing constraints on firm dynamics, such as Quadrini (2004), Albuquerque and Hopenhayn (2004) and Clementi and Hopenhayn (2006), have used the optimal contract design framework—where borrowing constraints arise as a feature of an optimal long-term lending contract subject to market failures such as asymmetric information or limited contract enforceability. This approach has been very successful in generating short-to-medium-run implications of borrowing constraints. For example, the optimal lending contract under asymmetric information studied in Clementi and Hopenhayn (2006) (hereafter, CH) implies that smaller firms are more financially constrained, grow faster, but have higher probability of being liquidated. These features are consistent with the qualitative properties of firm growth and survival documented in the empirical literature.2

An important feature of the aforementioned contracting models is that borrowing constraints are transient phenomena in all these models: the firm ceases to be borrowing constrained in finite periods and hence there is no firm growth or exit driven by borrowing constraints in the long run. For instance, in CH, the evolution of equity values of the firm (the state variable of the recursive contract) has two absorbing states: either the firm is liquidated, or it grows in finite periods to the point where it reaches its unconstrained efficient size and will never be liquidated. This seems counterfactual: borrowing constraints as well as the possibility of exit are likely to remain in the long term, as a firm grows larger and older.3

This paper considers two variations of the CH contract—each relaxing one assumption in CH, and both variations lead to borrowing constraints that are always binding during the firm's life cycle. One variation assumes that the entrepreneur has a lower discount factor than the bank, or in other words, the entrepreneur is more impatient than the bank. The assumption of having a lender that is more patient than a borrower has been adopted in many studies, for examples, see Carlstrom and Fuerst (1997), Monge-Naranjo (2009) and DeMarzo and Fishman (2007). It is consistent with an important implication of general equilibrium models with incomplete financial market (e.g., see Huggett, 1993, Aiyagari, 1994)—the equilibrium interest rate (which reflects the discounting by the lender) is lower than the time preference rate of the agent. The other variation relaxes the assumption that the bank has full commitment. Although full commitment on the part of the bank (the principal) is a standard assumption in the optimal contracting literature, frequent bank failures, as observed in the recent financial crisis, suggest that it is not realistic to assume banks are able to keep promises under all circumstances.4 So in the second variation we assume, in a similar form as the limited commitment assumption on the agent's side that has been extensively studied in the literature, that the bank has limited commitment: the bank can renege on the contract if the expected discounted flows of payments to himself implied by the contract fall below a critical value which represents the value of some outside option for the bank.

The two modified optimal lending contracts are carefully characterized. In comparison to the CH contract, both variations lead to borrowing constraints that are always binding such that the firm is financially constrained throughout its life cycle and subject to a positive probability of being liquidated eventually. The key result underlying such difference is that either variation leads to an upper bound on the optimal value entitlement to the firm such that the equity value of the firm cannot grow to the unconstrained level. The term ‘equity’ represents the firm's claim to future cash flows that the contract will deliver, and it grows as the firm makes repayments to the bank, or in other words, as the firm puts deposits in the bank. In the impatient entrepreneur case, as the firm discounts future cash flows more heavily, it is not optimal for the firm to accumulate deposits at the bank, by sacrificing current consumption (dividends), to a level that would allow the firm to be borrowing unconstrained. In the case of the bank having limited commitment, the firm, fearing that the bank may renege on the contract, also does not want to deposit too much at the bank.

Considering the similarities in the properties of the two contracts, we conduct a numerical comparison to see whether the two variations are structurally identical. The numerical results show that there are some structural differences in the computed value functions and policy functions, but the differences are modest compared with the similarities. In particular, the two contracts imply roughly the same evolution dynamics of equity values for the firm. The numerical exercise hints that a quantitative exercise is unlikely to reject one model and not the other.5

This paper contributes to the literature on dynamic contracting in several aspects. First, it formally discusses the implications of different discount rates for the lender and borrower in the context of a dynamic lending contract with private information. In the dynamic contracting literature, different discounting by the principal and the agent with the agent being more impatient is first considered by Williamson (1998) and Aiyagari and Williamson, 1999, Aiyagari and Williamson, 2000 in the context of dynamic risk sharing with privately observed endowments. This assumption, as formally established in Aiyagari and Williamson (1999), leads to a non-degenerate limiting distribution of expected utilities for the agent. In the dynamic lending literature, DeMarzo and Fishman (2007) and Monge-Naranjo (2009) consider the same assumption as ours in their contracting problems, where the former study an optimal long-term financial contract in the presence of agency problems and the latter studies a continuous time version of the contracting problem with limited commitment on the firm's side studied in Albuquerque and Hopenhayn (2004). In both studies this assumption also serves to avoid uninteresting degeneracies. Here, the properties of the optimal lending contract with impatient entrepreneur implies that an aggregation of firms financed by this type of contract would yield a non-degenerate stationary distribution of firm sizes (equity values), with borrowing constraints binding for all firms and continually driving firm growth and exit.6 On the contrary, if firms are financed by the CH contract, a degenerate firm size distribution would result with all firms operating at the unconstrained efficient size. So our result is consistent with previous studies regarding the role of impatient agent. It again demonstrates the robustness of this assumption as a device to avoid degeneracies in dynamic contracting problems.

Second, this paper is one of the very few studies that address the implications of limited commitment on the part of the principal for optimal contract design. In the dynamic contract literature, most studies assume that the agent may or may not fully commit, but the principal has full commitment in the sense that it can fully honors its contracts under all circumstances.7 The only exception by far is Phelan (1995) which considers an optimal risk sharing contract in a repeated unobserved endowment economy. In the model, the principal is allowed to walk away from the contract at some cost. This can be viewed as a form of limited commitment for the principal, although Phelan (1995) does not interpret it this way. It is shown there this assumption leads to an upper bound on the expected utilities of the agent. Here, in a dynamic lending context with private information, we show that the limited commitment assumption for the bank works in a similar way—imposing an upper bound on the value entitlements to the firm. And we go one step further to show that this assumption changes the behavior of the contract in a fundamental way, which leads to interesting changes in the implied firm dynamics. In particular, it provides a different way to avoid the degeneracy problem in dynamic contracting.

Our characterization reveals that the limited commitment assumption for the bank implies a positive lower bound on the expected net cash flow to the bank in every period. Such lower bound can be interpreted as a limited liability constraint for the bank, in the same spirit as the limited liability constraint CH assumes for the firm—a net cash flow bounded below by zero to the firm in every period. So the limited commitment assumption may correspond to some appropriately specified limited liability constraint for the bank. This provides some further justification for the empirical relevance of limited commitment on the principal's side in a contracting problem, as all corporations enjoy the privilege of limited liability, including banks and insurance companies.

Finally, very few studies in the contracting literature have considered both asymmetric information and limited contract commitment—the two most common sources of frictions, although the implications of each have been extensively studied. The findings of this paper suggest that it is important to explore the implications of a combination of these two, not only because adding one to the other can bring non-trivial changes in the behavior of the contract, but also because the role of each can be better clarified in the same contracting environment.

The remainder of the paper is organized as follows. Section 2 describes the contracting environment. Section 3 characterizes the optimal lending contracts under each variation. Section 4 presents a numerical comparison between the two contracts. Section 5 gives some concluding remarks. All proofs for the lemmas and propositions are provided in the Technical appendix.

Section snippets

The environment

We consider a more general version of the contracting problem studied in CH. Here is a brief description of the contracting environment. Time is discrete, and the time horizon is infinite. At time 0 the entrepreneur (firm) has a project which requires a fixed initial investment I0>0 and per-period investments of working capital. Once in operation, the project is subject to revenue shocks θt in each period, where θt{H,L} with prob{θ=H}=p. If θt=H, the project produces revenues R(kt), where kt

Properties of the optimal contract with limited commitment of the bank

In this section, we characterize the optimal lending contract under the assumption that δe=δ, and B̲>B˜.9 Clearly under this assumption the CH contract does not satisfy the limited commitment constraint of the bank: when the firm's equity value reaches V˜pR(k)/(1δ), the value of the contract to the bank B˜ is

Properties of the optimal contract with impatient entrepreneur

In this section, we assume that B̲B˜ such that the limited commitment constraint of the bank is never binding, and the entrepreneur is more impatient than the bank, i.e., δe<δ. Then constraints (5), (6) slip away from the contracting problem defined in (P1) and (P2), and the upper bound V¯ can be set to V˜IEpR(k)/(1δe), where ‘IE’ stands for ‘impatient entrepreneur’.

Assumption 1 implies that S<V˜IE+B˜V˜IE+B(V˜IE), ensuring that the scrap value S strictly less than the total value of the

A comparison between limited commitment and impatient entrepreneur

From the discussions in 3 Properties of the optimal contract with limited commitment of the bank, 4 Properties of the optimal contract with impatient entrepreneur, we see that the contract with limited commitment of the bank and the contract with impatient entrepreneur share very similar properties. In comparison to the original CH contract, both modifications lead to a downward shift in the value functions; the firm is financially constrained throughout its life-cycle and has a positive

Concluding remarks

The CH model provides a useful framework for analyzing the impact of endogenous borrowing constraints on firm dynamics. While the original version of the model implies a transient nature of borrowing constraints, it can be adapted in relatively straightforward ways to alter this implication. This paper illustrates two different ways of doing this—assuming impatient entrepreneur or limited commitment for the bank, and draws out their implications for the optimal lending contract and the implied

Acknowledgments

I would like to thank Dean Corbae, Ian King, Chris Edmond, Lawrence Uren and two anonymous referees for their valuable comments. All remaining errors are my own.

References (30)

  • A. Atkeson et al.

    On efficient distribution with private information

    Review of Economic Studies

    (1992)
  • Banerjee, A., Duflo, E., 2004. Do firms want to borrow more? Testing credit constraints using a directed lending...
  • C.T. Carlstrom et al.

    Agency costs, net worth, and business fluctuationsa computable general equilibrium analysis

    The American Economic Review

    (1997)
  • G.L. Clementi et al.

    A theory of financing constraints and firm dynamics

    The Quarterly Journal of Economics

    (2006)
  • T. Cooley et al.

    Aggregate consequences of limited contract enforceability

    The Journal of Political Economy

    (2004)
  • Cited by (4)

    • The Economics of Entrepreneurship: Second Edition

      2018, The Economics of Entrepreneurship: Second Edition
    View full text