International trade, income distribution and welfare

https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jinteco.2017.10.002Get rights and content

Abstract

This paper studies the relationship between income distribution and international integration in a canonical trade setting with one change. In the standard model prices are solely a function of (constant) marginal costs and (constant) elasticities, implying that information on individual incomes are of no value to a firm. To allow a more realistic role for consumer level information, a firm's strategy space is expanded to include non-linear prices. Now profit maximizing firms use information on income distribution to design a product for each income class and set prices to induce each group to optimally select the appropriate option. Equilibrium involves designs below the first best for low income groups and above the first best for high income groups – welfare differences are more exaggerated than income differences. When countries with differing income distributions integrate this has implications for the size of these distortions, influencing the gains from trade both within and across countries. These implications are quantified and shown to be potentially significant factors affecting welfare outcomes from integration – with the consequences more pronounced at lower trade costs. The structure of trade and expenditure patterns that emerge also match a range of empirical findings. These results are driven by firm strategy based on income difference alone as preferences are assumed to be identical and homothetic across countries, placing the distribution of income at the center of the analysis.

Introduction

Models of international trade have traditionally used richness on the supply side to gain insight into why countries trade and the likely implications of integration. Any role for consumer heterogeneity is usually suppressed by adopting preferences that are both identical and homothetic. While analytically convenient, these assumptions (coupled with linear pricing) lead models of international trade to effectively ignore some of the most pronounced differences across individuals, regions and countries: income and spending patterns.

To date all efforts to gain insight into the consequences of this variation have started by relaxing the assumption of homotheticity, freeing up expenditure shares to depend not just on relative prices but also income levels. In contrast, this paper maintains the assumption of homothetic preferences and focuses on an alternative possibility – firms themselves might be interested in income differences, and may try to exploit this information to raise profits. That is, firms may try to discriminate across the different income groups.

To isolate the main implications of this behavior, we adopt the preference and technology structure of Krugman (1980). With homothetic preferences at its heart, this shuts down the mechanisms exploited by the previous literature.1 Furthermore, its single sector structure means that expenditure shares don’t vary with income. Nevertheless, differences in income across consumers translate into different consumer level demand functions. What we explore is the possibility that a firm might find a way to use this information to their advantage. Another benefit of this framework is that we have a very well understood benchmark for thinking about welfare – as set out in Arkolakis et al. (2012). Can we offer anything new in a setting where welfare outcomes are remarkably robust to variation in assumptions on market structure and firm heterogeneity? Despite all this structure intended to suppress any role for consumer heterogeneity and deliver broad welfare results, we show that nevertheless the gains from trade can vary across income groups within a country.

The key feature that drives this result is that we allow firms to not only recognize that consumers have different incomes but also be sophisticated enough to exploit this knowledge. The way firm set prices in Krugman (1980) lacks this level of sophistication. In particular firms are assumed to use linear prices, implying they are only interested in the curvature of the residual demand function when formulating their optimal strategies. Moreover, with CES preferences the elasticity of residual demand is constant and the same for all consumers. The combination of these two assumptions has relatively extreme implications for how firms respond as their information set is enriched. For example, if a firm is suddenly able to observe the income levels of each consumer, the best they can do under linear pricing is implement third degree price discrimination. However, with the elasticity of demand independent of income and the same for all consumers, a firm will not change their behavior, continuing to charge the same price per unit to all types. Contrary to what might be imagined, this additional consumer level information is then essentially of no value to a firm.

To incorporate a more realistic role for how this information is utilized, we expand a firm's strategy space to include non-linear prices. We follow the typical approach and assume that a firm knows the distribution of income but not an individual consumer's income. More formally this is a setting where a firm implements second degree price discrimination (SDPD). If a firm optimally chooses to exploit this consumer heterogeneity, it does so through the design of a menu of options (product line or “versioning”) offered to a consumer.2

A particularly neat illustration of a product line is the iPad range. The initial offerings only had one dimension of variation, the quantity of gigabytes (GB): 16 GB, 32 GB and 64 GB. For the first two sizes the prices are $499 and $599.3 If we use these prices to linearly project the price of a 64 GB machine we arrive at $399 + $6.25(64) = $799, which is $100 more than the actual price of $699.4 What's behind this pricing behavior – differences in cost, elasticity or something else? Industry sources confirm that the marginal cost of a GB is constant, so costs can’t explain this variation. Additionally, the prices imply that the elasticity of demand is increasing in memory size, contrary to the typical assumption.5 Using the implied elasticity from the 16 GB machine suggests that the 64 GB iPad would be priced over $1100. Evidently a simple mark-up formula isn’t employed, leaving scope for more sophisticated pricing strategies underlying product menus and their design. Moreover, the widespread use of product lines raises a broader question about their welfare implications, not only for a single product but also at an aggregate level.6 A natural way to capture the broader welfare consequences of SDPD is through a general equilibrium framework – the approach adopted in this paper.

An important characteristic of SDPD is that firm behavior and the resulting monopolistically competitive equilibrium is not just a function of the curvature of the demand functions but also their position. Specifically, the profit maximizing menu trades off the desire to extract rents from an income group (by offering a design close to the first best) against the cost that this provides an enhanced outside option for another income group/s. This trade-off is resolved by the relative size and frequency of income groups. As a consequence the distribution of income is a fundamental determinant of the design of the equilibrium product line.

A feature of this equilibrium is that product design is distorted relative to the first best. In general, products designed for low income types are below the first best, while the products targeted to the high income groups are above the first best.7 It then follows that welfare differences are more exaggerated than income differences.

The critical role of the distribution of income in this outcome immediately implies that the integration of two countries with different income distributions alters product line design and consequently welfare. Insight into the implications are clearest when countries can be ranked in terms of income distribution. In particular, if a country's income distribution dominates the global distribution then the gains from free trade will be larger than predicted by the sufficient statistic measure developed by Arkolakis et al. (2012) (henceforth ACR).8 Moreover, these gains are disproportionately concentrated at the bottom end of the income distribution. In this case, trade reduces the distortions from SDPD and the benefits are felt across the entire distribution of income. The opposite occurs in a country whose income distribution is dominated by the global distribution, as trade adds to the distortions from SDPD. Since these distortions are not captured by the standard model of international trade they represent a new dimension of welfare analysis.

Further insight follows from decomposing the gains from trade into those derived from additional varieties and those associated with the design of the menu of choices. Critically, these two components respond differentially to the level of trade costs. In particular, when trade barriers are relatively high, incremental liberalization is primarily about reducing the costs of serving a market and has little impact on menu design. Thus, for high trade barriers the gains from marginal liberalization follow a pattern familiar from the standard model and consistent with ACR. However, once trade barriers become sufficiently low, the potential for international arbitrage triggers a process of convergence in product design across countries. Since not all types in all countries gain from design convergence, there is potential for an incremental process of trade liberalization to stall – at the margin the negative effects for product design in one country can outweigh further savings from lower trade costs.

To examine the role of this mechanism, the model is quantified on the same data utilized by Costinot and Rodriguez-Clare (2014) (hereafter CRC). In common with CRC, the SDPD model has a component of welfare determined by the domestic expenditure share and the trade elasticity. In addition, this measure is multiplied by an adjustment factor that depends on product design. While decreases in domestic expenditure share raise welfare, changes in product design can be an offsetting force. To determine design changes, the equilibrium designs are derived for each income group in each country based on the observed national income distribution. The counter factual considered is complete integration – designs based on the global income distribution. The ratio of the design changes for each income group generates an adjustment factor that either magnifies the ARC gains or diminishes them. Since the domestic expenditure share associated with free trade is not readily calculated, the metric adopted is to ask what change in the domestic expenditure share is required to ensure every income group gains from integration. That is, what percentage change in domestic expenditure share is required to offset any negative design changes?

This exercise reveals stark differences across countries. In particular, only 5 countries have all income groups benefit unambiguously from design changes induced by integration. In contrast, the remaining 28 countries all have at least one income group that is adversely affected by the negative consequences of menu redesign. These changes are especially daunting in low income countries. For 12 countries, the change in the domestic expenditure share needed to offset these design changes exceeds 10 percentage points – requiring a larger decline in the domestic share than observed for any of these countries between 1995 and 2008. Consequently, in these countries it seems likely that there is at least one income group that would prefer the initial trade equilibrium to full integration. These results suggest that if the negative consequences of standardizing global product lines are disproportionately associated with future liberalization, then a number of countries may resist efforts to fully integrate markets through reductions in trade barriers and/or harmonization of standards/regulations.

This paper is related to the literature on international trade that incorporate non-homothetic preferences. Simonovska (2015) shares a focus on price discrimination. She is interested in understanding how prices vary with per capita income across countries in a setting of third degree price discrimination, with no discrimination within countries. However, she doesn’t consider the welfare implications of international integration and quality also doesn’t vary by destination. Tarasov, 2012, Fajgelbaum et al., 2011 and Choi et al. (2009) develop models that examine quality choice by firms when higher income consumers purchase higher quality products. However, these models don’t allow firms to exploit the underlying heterogeneity in the population through the design of a menu of choices. Instead they constrain a firm to produce a good with a single quality level and then leverage this feature through the location choices of firms that produce different qualities. The multi-sector analysis demonstrates that a model with homothetic preferences and SDPD is capable of generating a non-linear Engel curve – the very feature that motivates the use of non-homothetic preferences.9 The key difference is whether distortions arise. In models that utilize non-homotheticities, equilibrium doesn’t necessarily involve inefficiencies Fajgelbaum and Khandelwal, 2015, Markusen, 2013, Fieler, 2011 and Choi et al. (2009)) while the equilibrium associated with SDPD is inefficient. Hence, understanding the source of the variation in expenditure patterns has welfare implications. While I have emphasized differences with the literature based on non-homethetic preferences, there is also scope for these two approaches to be integrated. The adoption of homothetic preferences in the current paper serves to highlight the independent role of discriminatory practices by firms in shaping outcomes and welfare but these practices are also consistent with richer demand structures.

The remainder of the paper is broken into three sections. Section 2 constructs a general equilibrium monopolistically competitive model of SDPD with two income types. This framework facilitates comparisons with both the previous trade literature based on general equilibrium models with linear pricing and also the partial equilibrium monopoly literature that analyzes SDPD. In particular, it derives the shadow linear prices underlying SDPD and the associated measure of real income that enable non-linear prices to be analyzed in a general equilibrium setting. Section 3 considers integration between countries with different income distributions, and examines the consequences of different levels of trade costs. The final section quantifies the welfare effects of integration in a world where firms implicitly discriminate through product lines.

Section snippets

Model

The main elements of the model are familiar from Krugman (1980): one factor (inelastically supplied), monopolistic competition between a set of symmetric firms with a constant marginal cost (and unit labor requirement), w, and a firm level fixed cost, wF. There is a single sector where consumers have the same CES preferences over products:10

Free trade in the standard model

As a benchmark consider the standard model without trade costs where technology and preferences are as described above but firms are constrained to use linear prices. Since welfare of an income group is proportional to their income share we only need to consider aggregate demand for a variety and the number of varieties (which are a function of the relevant endowment, ng=LgσF; where Lg is the size of the labor endowment of the integrated countries). Consequently, for a country with an endowment

Quantifying the gains from integration

The key insight of Proposition 3 is that trade barriers can be partitioned into two sets. High trade barriers that allow firms to segment markets internationally with design based on national income distributions. At these high levels, marginal changes in trade barriers do not change relative design – any gains from trade reflect the mechanisms summarized by ACR. However, at low trade barriers complete segmentation isn’t possible – changes in trade barriers continue to generate ACR style gains

Conclusion

This paper considers the implications of allowing firms to be sophisticated enough to design product lines. Such a level of sophistication makes them interested in consumer level information, and the distribution of income in particular. Enriching firm behavior in this way results in a tractable model and provides a link between the distribution of income and the gains from trade.

This link arises as firms implicitly discriminate between the various income classes, which in equilibrium results

References (35)

  • G.S. Crawford et al.

    Monopoly quality degradation and regulation in cable television

    J. Law Econ.

    (2007)
  • A. Eizenberg

    Upstream innovation and product variety in the US home pc market

    Rev. Econ. Stud.

    (2014)
  • P. Fajgelbaum et al.

    Income distribution, product quality, and international trade

    J. Polit. Econ.

    (2011)
  • P.D. Fajgelbaum et al.

    Measuring the unequal gains from trade

    Q. J. Econ.

    (2015)
  • A.C. Fieler

    Nonhomotheticity and bilateral trade: evidence and a quantitative explanation

    Econometrica

    (2011)
  • I. Hendel et al.

    Intertemporal price discrimination in storable goods markets

    Am. Econ. Rev.

    (2013)
  • P. Krugman

    Scale economies, product differentiation, and the pattern of trade

    Am. Econ. Rev.

    (1980)
  • Cited by (22)

    • An inquiry into the nexus between energy poverty and income inequality in the light of global evidence

      2021, Energy Economics
      Citation Excerpt :

      Meanwhile, Perera and Lee (2013) did not find evidence of the Kuznets Curve in Asian countries over the period 1985–2009, while Yang and Greaney (2017) showed an S-shaped relationship between income inequality and income level in China, Japan, South Korea, and the US. The recent literature shows evidence going beyond income levels, and there is some endeavour to explain the dynamics of income inequality from other angles, with other determinants such as financial development (Jauch and Watzka, 2016; Zhang and Ben Naceur, 2019), human capital (Lee and Lee, 2018), economic integration (Cabral et al., 2016; McCalman, 2018), or industrialisation (Mehic, 2018). For instance, Altunbaş and Thornton (2019) argued that financial development is an important driver of income inequality, which decreases income inequality in upper-middle-income economies but increases income inequality in low- and high-income economies.

    • The Kuznets curve for export diversification and income inequality: Evidence from a global sample

      2020, Economic Analysis and Policy
      Citation Excerpt :

      The important role of income inequality for socio-economic developments in the long run has been extensively considered in the literature (Adam et al., 2015; Korpi and Palme, 1998; Persson and Tabellini, 1994; Suresh Babu et al., 2016; Vanegas, 2014; Zhang and Ben Naceur, 2019). In the context of globalization, there is a vast amount of literature on the influences of trade liberalization on income in general (for instance, recent studies include Le and Chang, 2013; Le et al., 2016a,c; Le, 2017; Le and Tran-Nam, 2018) and on income inequality in particular (see, for example, Kanbur, 2015; Antràs et al., 2017; Bergh and Nilsson, 2010; Meschi and Vivarelli, 2009; McCalman, 2018; Yang and Greaney, 2017). Some of these studies documented that increased trade openness leads to rising income inequality, for example, Kanbur (2015) for both developed and developing countries, and Bergh and Nilsson (2010) for 80 countries over the 1970–2005 period.

    • Specializations, financial constraints, and income distribution

      2018, International Review of Economics and Finance
    View all citing articles on Scopus

    I would like to thank Andres Rodriguez-Clare, along with two anonymous referees for their valuable comments and suggestions. The paper also benefited from numerous seminars and presentations. Financial support from Peter B. Kenen Fellowship at Princeton University and the Australian Research Council, grant DP-140101128, is gratefully acknowledged.

    View full text