Robust monetary policy with imperfect knowledge

https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jmoneco.2007.06.005Get rights and content

Abstract

We examine the performance and robustness properties of monetary policy rules in an estimated macroeconomic model in which the economy undergoes structural change and where private agents and the central bank possess imperfect knowledge about the true structure of the economy. Policymakers follow an interest rate rule aiming to maintain price stability and to minimize fluctuations of unemployment around its natural rate but are uncertain about the economy's natural rates of interest and unemployment and how private agents form expectations. In particular, we consider two models of expectations formation: rational expectations (RE) and learning. We show that in this environment the ability to stabilize the real side of the economy is significantly reduced relative to an economy under RE with perfect knowledge. Furthermore, policies that would be optimal under perfect knowledge can perform very poorly if knowledge is imperfect. Efficient policies that take account of private learning and misperceptions of natural rates call for greater policy inertia, a more aggressive response to inflation, and a smaller response to the perceived unemployment gap than would be optimal if everyone had perfect knowledge of the economy. We show that such policies are quite robust to potential misspecification of private sector learning and the magnitude of variation in natural rates.

Introduction

To paraphrase Clausewitz, monetary policy is conducted in a fog of uncertainty. Our understanding of many key features of the macroeconomic landscape remains imperfect, and the landscape itself evolves over time. As emphasized by McCallum (1988) and Taylor (1993), a crucial requirement for a monetary policy rule is that its good performance be robust to various forms of model misspecification. In this view, it is not enough for a monetary policy rule to be optimal in one specific model, but instead it must be “stress tested” in a variety of alternative model environments before one can conclude with any confidence that the policy is likely to perform well in practice.1 In this paper, we examine the performance and robustness of monetary policy rules in the context of fundamental uncertainty related to the nature of expectations formation and structural change in the economy. Our goal is to identify characteristics of policy rules that are robust to these types of imperfect knowledge, as well as to identify those that are not.

The first form of uncertainty facing the policymaker that we consider relates to the way in which agents form expectations. There is a growing literature that analyzes a variety of alternative models of expectations formation. The key conclusion we take from our reading of this literature is that there is a great deal of uncertainty regarding exactly how private expectations are formed. In particular, the standard assumption of rational expectations (RE) may be overly restrictive for monetary policy analysis, especially in the context of an economy undergoing structural change. But, the available evidence does not yet provide unequivocal support for any other single model of expectations formation. Therefore, fundamental uncertainty about the nature of expectations formation appears to be an unavoidable aspect of the policy environment facing central banks face today.

In this paper, we consider two popular alternative models of private expectations formation. Our approach can easily be extended to incorporate other alternative models of expectations as well, but for reasons of tractability, we leave this for future research. One model is RE, which assumes that private agents know all the parameters of the model and form expectations accordingly. This, of course, is the model used in much of the recent monetary policy rule literature. The second model is perpetual learning, where it is assumed that agents do not know the true parameters of the model, but instead continuously reestimate a forecasting model (see Sargent, 1999, Evans and Honkapohja, 2001 for expositions of this model). This form of learning represents a relatively modest, and arguably realistic, deviation from RE. An advantage of the perpetual learning framework is that it allows varying degrees of deviations in expectations formation relative to the RE benchmark, which are characterized by variation in a single model parameter. As shown in Orphanides and Williams, 2005a, Orphanides and Williams, 2005b, Orphanides and Williams, 2005c), perpetual learning on the part of economic agents introduces an additional layer of interaction between monetary policy, expectations, and economic outcomes.

The second source of uncertainty that we consider is unobserved structural change, which we represent in the form of low-frequency variation in the natural rates of unemployment and interest. The equilibrium of our model economy is described in terms of deviations from these natural rates. In particular, the inflation rate is in part determined by the unemployment gap, the deviation of the unemployment rate from its natural rate. Similarly, the unemployment rate gap is determined in part by the real interest rate gap, the difference between the real short-term interest rate and the real natural rate of interest. We assume that the central bank does not observe the true values of the natural rates and, indeed, is uncertain about the processes generating the natural rates.

Natural rate uncertainty presents a difficulty for policymakers who follow an interest rate rule with the goal of maintaining price stability and minimizing fluctuations of unemployment around its natural rate. With perfect knowledge of natural rates, the setting of policy would ideally account for the evolution of the economy's natural rates. But, if policymakers do not know the values of the natural rates of interest and unemployment when they make policy decisions, they must either rely on inherently imprecise real-time estimates of these rates for setting the policy instrument, or, alternatively, eschew natural rates altogether and follow a policy rule that does not respond to natural rate estimates.

The evidence suggests there exists considerable uncertainty regarding the natural rates of unemployment and interest and ambiguity about how best to model and estimate natural rates, even with the benefit of hindsight.2,3 Indeed, the measurement of the natural rate of output has been a key issue in U.S. monetary policy debates in both the 1970s and 1990s, and uncertainty about the natural rate of interest has been the topic of increasing discussion. The evidence indicates that substantial misperceptions regarding the economy's natural rates may persist for some time, before their presence is recognized. In the meantime, policy intended to be contractionary may actually inadvertently be overly expansionary, and vice versa. Moreover, in an environment where the private sector is learning, the learning process can interact with the policy errors and feed back to economic outcomes, as pointed out by Orphanides and Williams, 2005a, Orphanides and Williams, 2005b, Orphanides and Williams, 2005c and Gaspar et al. (2006).

We examine the effects and policy implications of imperfect knowledge of expectations formation and unknown time-varying natural rates using a quarterly model of the U.S. economy estimated over 1981–2004. We first consider the performance and robustness characteristics of simple operational monetary policy rules under perfect and imperfect knowledge. We then analyze the characteristics and performance of policy rules optimized taking into account model uncertainty about expectations formation and natural rate uncertainty. We approach this problem of optimal policy under uncertainty from Bayesian and Min–Max perspectives and compare the results.

Our analysis yields several key findings. First, the scope for stabilization of the real economy in our model with imperfect knowledge is significantly reduced relative to the economy under perfect knowledge (where private agents and the central bank are assumed to know all features of the model). Second, monetary policies that would be optimal under perfect knowledge can perform very poorly when knowledge is imperfect. Third, the optimal Bayesian policy under uncertainty performs very well across all of our model specifications and is therefore highly robust to the types of model uncertainty that we examine here. This policy features greater policy inertia, a larger response to inflation, and a smaller response to the perceived unemployment gap than would be optimal under perfect knowledge.

The remainder of the paper is organized as follows. Section 2 discusses the problems for monetary policy caused by natural rate mismeasurement. Section 3 briefly describes the estimated macro model. Section 4 describes the class of monetary policy rules that we study. Section 5 presents the models of expectations formation and natural rate estimation. Section 6 provides details on the simulation method. Section 7 analyzes monetary policy under different models of expectations formation, but assuming constant natural rates. Section 8 explores the joint effects of alternative models of expectations and time-varying natural rates. Section 9 examines the optimal Bayesian and Min–Max policies. Section 10 concludes.

Section snippets

Natural rates, misperceptions, and policy errors

We start our analysis with an illustration of some of the difficulties presented by the evolution of the economy's natural rates. To highlight the role of natural rate misperceptions and the role of policy in propagating them in the economy, consider a generalization of the simple policy rule proposed by Taylor (1993). Let it denote the short-term interest rate employed as the policy instrument, (the federal funds rate in the Unites States), πt the rate of inflation, and ut the rate of

An estimated model of the U.S. economy

We examine the interaction of natural rate misperceptions, learning, and expectations for the design of robust monetary policy rules using a simple quarterly model motivated by the recent literature on micro-founded models incorporating some inertia in inflation and output (see Woodford, 2003, for a fuller discussion). The specification of the model is closely related to that in Giannoni and Woodford (2005), Smets (2003), and others. The key difference is that instead of the output gap concept

Monetary policy

We evaluate the performance of monetary policies rules using a loss equal to the weighted sum of the unconditional variances of the inflation rate, the unemployment gap, and the change in the nominal federal funds rate:L=Var(π-π*)+λVar(u-u*)+νVar(Δ(i)),where Var(x) denotes the unconditional variance of variable x.11

Expectations

We consider two methods by which private agents form expectations: RE and learning. Under RE, private agents know all features of the model, including the realized values of the natural rates. Under learning, we assume that private agents form expectations using an estimated forecasting model, and that the central bank forms estimates of the natural rates of interest and unemployment using simple time-series methods. Specifically, following Orphanides and Williams (2005c), we posit that private

Simulation method

As noted above, we measure the performance of alternative policies rules based on the central bank loss equal to the weighted sum of unconditional variances of inflation, the unemployment gap, and the change in the funds rate. In the case of RE with constant and known natural rates, we compute the unconditional variances numerically as described in Levin et al. (1999). In all other cases, we compute approximations of the unconditional moments using stochastic simulations of the model.

Monetary policy and learning

We first consider the design of optimal monetary policy in the presence of learning by private agents but assuming that natural rates are constant and known by the policymaker. In this way we can more easily identify the private sector effects of learning in isolation. In the next section, we analyze the case of private learning with time varying natural rates that are unobserved by the policymaker.

Interaction of learning and time-varying natural rates

Having examined some of the policy implications of perpetual learning under the maintained assumption that natural rates are known and constant, we now turn our attention to the more general case that acknowledges the possible presence of time variation in the natural rates of interest and unemployment. In terms of the model, we add innovations to the natural rate equations, introduce the central bank's real-time updating problem and keep track of the way in which policymaker estimates of the

Robust policy

A striking feature of the results from the generalized policy rule is that the optimal coefficients of the rule do not appear to be very sensitive to the rates of learning that we consider or the magnitude of variation in natural rates, as long as both elements are present. In all cases, the optimal coefficient on the lagged funds rate is near one. The coefficients on inflation and the unemployment gap vary, but are generally of approximately the same size. And the coefficient on the change in

Conclusion

In an environment of imperfect knowledge regarding the potential for structural change in the economy and the formation of expectations, the scope for stabilization of the real side of our economy may be significantly reduced relative to an economy under RE with perfect knowledge. Policies that appear to be optimal under perfect knowledge can perform very poorly if they are implemented in such an environment. In our model economy, the presence of imperfect knowledge tends to raise the

References (47)

  • A. Orphanides et al.

    The decline of activist stabilization policy: natural rate misperceptions, learning, and expectations

    Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control

    (2005)
  • A. Orphanides et al.

    Errors in the measurement of the output gap and the design of monetary policy

    Journal of Economics and Business

    (2000)
  • F. Smets

    Maintaining price stability: how long is the medium term?

    Journal of Monetary Economics

    (2003)
  • J.B. Taylor

    Discretion versus policy rules in practice

    Carnegie–Rochester Conference Series on Public Policy

    (1993)
  • J.B. Taylor

    The robustness and efficiency of monetary policy rules as guidelines for interest rate setting by the European Central Bank

    Journal of Monetary Economics

    (1999)
  • Cogley, T., Sargent, T., 2001. Evolving post-world war II US inflation dynamics. In: NBER Macroeconomics...
  • Collard, F., Dellas, H., 2004. The great inflation of the 1970s. European Central Bank Working Paper 336,...
  • Congressional Budget Office, 2001. CBO's Method for Estimating Potential Output: An Update. Government Printing Office,...
  • Congressional Budget Office, 2002. The Budget and Economic Outlook: An Update. Government Printing Office, Washington...
  • Croushore, D., 1993. Introducing: the survey of professional forecasters. Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia Business...
  • G. Evans et al.

    Learning and Expectations in Macroeconomics

    (2001)
  • M. Friedman

    The role of monetary policy

    American Economic Review

    (1968)
  • V. Gaspar et al.

    Monetary policy, price stability and output gap stabilisation

    International Finance

    (2002)
  • Cited by (0)

    We would like to thank Jim Bullard, Stephen Cecchetti, Alex Cukierman, Stephen Durlauf, Vitor Gaspar, Stefano Eusepi, Bruce McGough, Ricardo Reis, and participants at numerous presentations for useful discussions and comments. The opinions expressed are those of the authors and do not necessarily reflect views of the Central Bank of Cyprus or the management of the Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco.

    View full text