Elsevier

Marine Policy

Volume 93, July 2018, Pages 1-8
Marine Policy

Paying the price to solve fisheries conflicts in Brazil's Marine Protected Areas

https://doi.org/10.1016/j.marpol.2018.03.016Get rights and content

Highlights

  • Conflicts with users, mostly fishers, hamper MPA long-term success.

  • Economic compensatory tools could be designed to compensate fishers for losing their free access.

  • Tourists may be willing to compensate fishers to safeguard important areas.

  • The success of MPAs may lay on accommodating different users’ expectations.

Abstract

Ecosystems services (ES) provide food and recreation to humans, but are fast being degraded. Marine Protected Areas (MPAs) have been proposed as a way to protect some of these ES, but decisions regarding what gets protection and what gets consumed can be a source of conflicts. One such example is the Fernando de Noronha MPA (Brazil), where there is a conflict between shark-directed tourism and fishers who would like to access the no-take part of the MPA during part of the year. A contingent valuation method (Willingness to Pay) was used to ascertain if tourists would accept compensating fishers for not disturbing the sharks during a specific period of the year, by adding a symbolic increase in the taxes they already pay to either visit the island or to visit the no-take part of the MPA. Tourists were open to this alternative (67–71%), regardless of the fee being paid. However, there was a slight tendency to reject the fee when the tourists saw sharks during their stay, suggesting that a closer contact with these animals triggered a less sympathetic attitude towards fishers, probably because they start seeing fishers as wrongdoers, even if this is the worst choice for conservation. Although such a hypothetical payment was easily accepted by the majority of the tourists and could represent an affordable solution to conflicts, convincing those who reject such social compensation, especially if based on an irrational choice, would be an important step for sharks and for the MPA as a whole.

Introduction

All over the world, tropical areas are increasingly being used for their ecosystem services (ESs) [1], sometimes to the point of exhaustion or for conflicting and unsustainable uses [2]. One way to protect ESs is through the establishment of protected areas [3]. There are multiple categories of protected areas, some are very restrictive, where only research is allowed, and others are lax enough to allow the sustainable exploitation of their resources [4]. Such variation in the degree of protection can be found in terrestrial and marine environments.

The establishment of Marine Protected Areas (MPAs) is still occurring at a relatively slow pace in relation to its terrestrial counterpart. At the Seventh Conference of the Parties (COP 7) in 2004, governments agreed to protect 10% of the marine habitats by 2012 [5]. In October 2013, IUCN estimated the actual rate only approached three percent and that it was likely the world would reach the initial goal only after postponing the deadline to 2020.1 Assuring a certain degree of protection is essential to the continuing provisioning of the marine ESs that people depend upon [6].

MPAs protect ecosystems that provide direct and indirect ESs [7], depending on the degree and effectiveness of protection of these areas. Among the human activities that make use of ecosystem services, two are particularly important and related in the tropics: ecotourism [8] and fisheries [9]. Tropical MPAs, when in a good conservation state, can be a more reliable provider of fish than unprotected neighboring areas, working as a source to the latter through the spillover effect [10]. Resident, migratory and even species with sensitive life history aspects (e.g., long lifespan, late maturity, few offspring), such as sharks, can benefit from such areas [11]. Abundant fish attracts the attention of fishers and recreational divers alike.

Shark diving tourism is a profitable business, annually generating over USD 314 million, an ever-growing figure [12]. Tropical fisheries, on the other hand, are in some places the only source of food and cash for vulnerable poor communities [13]. Both activities have in common that they rely on having access to plenty of fish in the long-term, even if the species are not the same. Shark diving tourism is taken as a non-consumptive ES, where its occurrence is less likely to affect the abundance and diversity of fish. Fishing, on the other hand, consumes the resources it depends upon, and even if not focused on sharks, could disrupt the trophic chain, depending on how it is done and on how much fish biomass is removed from an area [14]. Additionally, there is always the chance of incidental catch, when non-target species are caught, sometimes at considerable numbers [15]. Therefore, the sustainable maintenance of livelihoods through fisheries and of shark diving tourism demands the establishment of a middle ground in the use of ecosystems. The lack of an agreement between different uses can lead to conflicts, which ultimately can threaten the already insufficient conservation endeavors [16].

The establishment of protected areas may alter land-use rights, by exclusion, restriction or even by passing these rights to others [17], such as to a local or an external elite [18]. It can also result in the criminalization of natives for their original practices [19]. Conflicts between users and MPAs can jeopardize their effectiveness to the point of making some MPAs less successful than the unprotected areas that surround them [20]. This would be the case when fishers or other users specifically target the MPA to make a political point, for disagreeing with their presence or with the way they were arbitrarily established.

In Brazil, the first protected areas followed the American style of native dispossession to protect an area from any human use, other than contemplation [21]. However, from the late 1980s on, natives and locals saw an opportunity to ally nature protection to land-rights by creating new categories of protection that allowed human presence [22], [23]. Whereas some of these areas have been successful, others face difficulties either because of market pressure on their natural resources that encourage people to break the rules or because of difficulties stemming from arrangements made in the past that cannot be supported by current legislation.

In this study, an economic tool was used to propose alternatives to social conflicts regarding the use of ecosystem services by small-scale fisheries and shark diving tourism. The case study was in the MPA of Fernando de Noronha (Brazil), the main shark diving tourism destination on the south Atlantic coast, which also hosts a traditional community of small-scale fishers. According to some stakeholders (some managers at the time of the study, for instance), fisheries threaten shark diving tourism by interfering with the trophic chain or with shark behavior; whereas fishers feel they have lost their traditional rights, and are forced to give way to tourism interests. Although this MPA was first designed to accommodate local fishers’ interests, legislation changes, tourism growth, and mismanagement created a conflict that could threat the current MPA status [20]. Therefore here it was assessed if tourists were willing to compensate fishers for their economic losses due to restrictive access to fishing grounds in order to not disturb sharks. The findings of this study look into alternative economic ways to solve or ameliorate conflicts that arise when certain ES are used by one activity and restricted to others due to a protected area. Solving conflicts is an important step to assure the effectiveness of protected areas [24], through improved compliance [25].

Section snippets

Fernando de Noronha, conflicts from an MPA

Fernando de Noronha is a 26 km2 MPA, located 345 km off the South Atlantic coast of Brazil (3°51'13.71" S, 32°25'25.63" W), which is zoned into two management categories: a no-take zone that encompasses 70% of the MPA, where visitation is limited and only allowed under a fee, and a sustainable use zone, where fishing, diving and tourism are allowed (Fig. 1). In 2014 and 2015, the number of people who entered the no-take zone was 63,896 and 76,472, respectively. These figures, together with the

Results

The average number of entrance tickets to the no-take area sold to Brazilian and foreign tourists in 2014 and 2015 reached slightly over 70,000 people per year, with a monthly peak in October of over 6700. Brazilians made up more than 80% of the tourists, meaning that the total revenue generated by tourists visiting the park only from entrance tickets was about BRL 7.5 million year1 (for other sources of revenue generated by ecotourism, such as accommodation, please check [27]). Scuba diving

Discussion

Despite high expectations placed on MPAs, in many instances they have not been able to stop deterioration of marine environments, sometimes due to exclusion of important, but overlooked stakeholders, who are often artisanal fishers [24]. By carefully considering the aspirations and expectations of fishers part of the secret to long-term success of MPAs may be unlocked [35], especially in those where conflicts between users and managers lead to non-compliance behavior [25]. Here a conflict

Conclusions

The suggested conflict between shark diving tourism and small-scale fisheries studied here requires the investigation of alternative scenarios that could lead to a healthy continuity of both activities. Having tourists compensate fishers for not interfering with the more vulnerable shark habitats (mating and nursing grounds) is an alternative that faces little opposition and recommends a small rise in fees already paid by the visitors. The next step for managers to adopt would be to actually

Acknowledgements

We would like to thank all participating tourists for sharing their time with us. We are also very thankful to the managers of the airport of Fernando de Noronha and to the managers of Fernando de Noronha MPA, who kindly provided the data on the number of tourists and scuba divers. Special thanks to Felipe Cruz, Thayná Melo and Júlio Rosa from ICMBio and to Ali Ger, Ludmila Damásio, Vinícius Fonseca, Júlia Tovar Verba, and Liana Mendes for their help in the fieldwork. We thank the advisory and

Role of the funding source

This work was supported by LACEEP (Latin American and Caribbean Environmental Economics Program) (Grant 192/2015), whose advisors also provided comments on the design, development and writing of the manuscript.

CNPq played no role in the study.

References (53)

  • I. Logar et al.

    Respondent uncertainty in contingent valuation of preventing beach erosion: an analysis with a polychotomous choice question

    J. Environ. Manag.

    (2012)
  • A. Begossi et al.

    Compensation for environmental services from artisanal fisheries in SE Brazil: policy and technical strategies

    Ecol. Econ.

    (2011)
  • T.W. Blaine et al.

    An assessment of household willingness to pay for curbside recycling: a comparison of payment card and referendum approaches

    J. Environ. Manag.

    (2005)
  • H. Nixon et al.

    Financing electronic waste recycling Californian households' willingness to pay advanced recycling fees

    J. Environ. Manag.

    (2007)
  • J.A. Puppim de Oliveira

    Governmental responses to tourism development: three Brazilian case studies

    Tour. Manag.

    (2003)
  • D.A. Schkade et al.

    How people respond to contingent valuation questions: a verbal protocol analysis of willingness to pay for an environmental regulation

    J. Environ. Econ. Manag.

    (1994)
  • H. Li et al.

    Public support for reducing US reliance on fossil fuels: investigating household willingness-to-pay for energy research and development

    Ecol. Econ.

    (2009)
  • B.D. Solomon et al.

    Valuing climate protection through willingness to pay for biomass ethanol

    Ecol. Econ.

    (2009)
  • F. Reed Johnson et al.

    Constructing experimental designs for discrete-choice experiments: report of the ISPOR conjoint analysis experimental design good research practices task force

    Value Health

    (2013)
  • B. Fisher et al.

    Poverty and biodiversity: measuring the overlap of human poverty and the biodiversity hotspots

    Ecol. Econ.

    (2007)
  • T. Agardy et al.

    Mind the gap: addressing the shortcomings of marine protected areas through large scale marine spatial planning

    Mar. Policy

    (2011)
  • K.S. Bawa et al.

    Beyond paradise: meeting the challenges in tropical biology in the 21st century

    Biotropica

    (2004)
  • M. Rao et al.

    Wild-meat use, food security, livelihoods, and conservation

    Conserv. Biol.

    (2002)
  • W.M. Adams et al.

    People, parks and poverty: political ecology and biodiversity conservation

    Conserv. Soc.

    (2007)
  • EUROPARC et al.

    Guidelines for Protected Area Management Categories: Interpretation and Application of the Protected Area Management Categories in Europe

    (2000)
  • L. Coad, N.D. Burgess, B. Bomhard, C. Besançon, Progress towards the convention on biological diversity´s 2012 and 2012...
  • Cited by (0)

    View full text