Hostname: page-component-76fb5796d-zzh7m Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-04-28T16:28:46.278Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Systemic Politics and the Origins of Great Power Conflict

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  01 February 2008

BEAR F. BRAUMOELLER*
Affiliation:
The Ohio State University
*
Bear F. Braumoeller is Assistant Professor, The Ohio State University, 2168 Derby Hall, 154 North Oval Mall, Columbus, Ohio 43210-1373 (braumoeller.1@polisci.osu.edu).

Abstract

Systemic theories of international politics rarely predict conflict short of cataclysmic systemic wars, and dyadic theories of conflict lack systemic perspective. This article attempts to bridge the gap by introducing a two-step theory of conflict among Great Powers. In the first stage, states engage in a dynamic, ongoing process of managing the international system, which inevitably produces tensions among them. In the second stage, relative levels of security-related activity determine how and when those tensions erupt into disputes. A test of the theory on Great Power conflicts from the nineteenth century supports the argument and, moreover, favors the deterrence model over the spiral model as a proximate explanation of conflict in the second stage.

Type
Research Article
Copyright
Copyright © American Political Science Association 2008

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

REFERENCES

Achen, Christopher H. 2002. Toward a New Political Methodology: Microfoundations and ART.” Annual Review of Political Science 5, 423–50.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Achen, Christopher H. and Snidal, Duncan. 1989. “Rational Deterrence Theory and Comparative Case Studies.World Politics 41 (2): 144–69.Google Scholar
Alvarez, R. Michael and Glasgow, Garrett. 1999. “Two-Stage Estimation of Nonrecursive Choice Models.Political Analysis 8 (Spring): 147–65.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Attfield, C. L. R, Demery, D., and Duck, N. W.. 1991. Rational Expectations in Economics. Cambridge, MA: Blackwell.Google Scholar
Axelrod, Robert. 1984. The Evolution of Cooperation. New York: Basic Books.Google Scholar
Beck, Nathaniel, King, Gary, and Zeng, Langche. 2004. “Theory and Evidence in International Conflict: A Response to de Marchi, Gelpi, and Grynaviski.” American Political Science Review 98 (June), 379–89.Google Scholar
Benoit, Kenneth and Laver, Michael. 2007. “Estimating party policy positions: Comparing expert surveys and hand-coded content analysis.Electoral Studies 26 (March): 90107.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Brainard, William C. 1967. “Uncertainty and the Effectiveness of Policy.” The American Economic Review 57 (June), 411–25.Google Scholar
Braumoeller, Bear. 2008a forthcoming. “Systemic Politics and the Origins of Great Power Rivalry.” Columbus: The Ohio State University.Google Scholar
Braumoeller, Bear. 2008b forthcoming. “Understanding System Dynamics: Simple Models of Complexity.” In Systems Theories of World Politics, ed. Albert, Mathias, Cederman, Lars-Erik, and Wendt, Alexander. Bielefeld, Germany: Institut für Weltgesellschaft.Google Scholar
Brown, Courtney. 1993. “Nonlinear Transformation in a Landslide: Johnson and Goldwater in 1964.American Journal of Political Science 37 (April), 582609.Google Scholar
Budge, Ian. 2001. “Validating Party Policy Placements.British Journal of Political Science 31 (January), 210–23.Google Scholar
Bueno de Mesquita, Bruce. 1998. “The End of the Cold War: Predicting an Emergent Property.Journal of Conflict Resolution 42 (April), 131–55.Google Scholar
Bueno de Mesquita, Bruce, and Lalman, David. 1988. “Empirical Support for Systemic and Dyadic Explanations of International Conflict.World Politics 41 (October): 120.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bull, Hedley. 1977. The Anarchical Society. New York: Columbia University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Buzan, Barry, Jones, Charles, and Little, Richard. 1993. The Logic of Anarchy: Neorealism to Structural Realism. New York: Columbia University Press.Google Scholar
Cameron, A. Colin, and Trivedi, Pravin K.. 2005. Microeconometrics: Methods and Applications. Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Clarke, Kevin A. 2005. “The Phantom Menace: Omitted Variable Bias in Econometric Research.Conflict Management and Peace Science 22 (Winter), 341–52.Google Scholar
Clausewitz, Carl von. 1976. On War. Princeton: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Clements, Michael P., and Hendry, David F.. 1998. Forecasting Economic Time Series. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Croco, Sarah E., and Teo, Tze Kwang. 2005. “Assessing the Dyadic Approach to Interstate Conflict Processes: A.k.a. “Dangerous” Dyad-Years.Conflict Management and Peace Science 22 (Spring): 518.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
de Marchi, Scott, Gelpi, Christopher, and Grynaviski, Jeffrey D.. 2004. “Untangling Neural Nets.American Political Science Review 98 (June): 371–78.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Diehl, Paul F., and Crescenzi, Mark J. C.. 1998. “Reconfiguring the Arms Race-War Debate.Journal of Peace Research 35 (January): 111–18.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Durr, Robert H. 1992. “An Essay on Cointegration and Error Correction Models.Political Analysis 4, 185228.Google Scholar
Fearon, James D. 1994. “Signaling versus the Balance of Power and Interests: An Empirical Test of a Crisis Bargaining Model.Journal of Conflict Resolution 38 (Summer), 236–69.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fearon, James D. 1995. “Rationalist Explanations for War.International Organization 49 (3), 319414.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fischer, Fritz. 1967. Germany's Aims in the First World War. New York: Norton.Google Scholar
Freeman, John R., Williams, John T., and Lin, Tse-min. 1989. “Vector Autoregression and the Study of Politics.American Journal of Political Science 33 (October), 842–77.Google Scholar
Gilpin, Robert. 1981. War and Change in World Politics. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Goldstein, Joshua S., and Freeman, John R.. 1991. “U.S.-Soviet-Chinese Relations: Routine, Reciprocity, or Rational Expectations?American Political Science Review 85 (March): 1735.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gulick, Edward Vose. 1955. Europe's Classical Balance of Power. New York: Norton.Google Scholar
Herwig, Holger H. 2002. “Germany and the ‘Short War’ Illusion: Toward a New Interpretation?Journal of Military History 66 (July), 681–93.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Huntington, Samuel P. 1958. “Arms Races: Prerequisites and Results.Public Policy 8, 4183.Google Scholar
Huth, Paul and Russett, Bruce. 1993. “General Deterrence Between Enduring Rivals: Testing Three Competing Models.American Political Science Review 87 (March): 6173.Google Scholar
Imbens, Guido W., and Rosenbaum, Paul R.. 2005. “Robust, accurate confidence intervals with a weak instrument: quarter of birth and education.Journal of the Royal Statistical Society A 168 (1), 109–26.Google Scholar
Jervis, Robert. 1976. Perception and Misperception in International Politics. Princeton: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Jervis, Robert. 1997. System Effects: Complexity in Political and Social Life. Princeton: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Johnston, John. 1984. Econometric Methods. New York: McGraw-Hill.Google Scholar
Kaplan, Morton. 1957. System and Process in International Politics. New York: Wiley.Google Scholar
Kissinger, Henry. 1994. Diplomacy. New York: Simon and Schuster.Google Scholar
Kydd, Andrew. 2005. Trust and Mistrust in International Relations. Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Lawler, Edward J., Ford, Rebecca S., and Blegen, Mary A.. 1988. “Coercive Capability in Conflict: A Test of Bilateral Deterrence versus Conflict Spiral Theory.Social Psychology Quarterly 51 (June): 93107.Google Scholar
Levy, Jack S. 1988. “Review article: When do deterrent threats work?British Journal of Political Science 18 (October), 485512.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lewis, Jeffrey B., and Poole, Keith T.. 2004. “Measuring Bias and Uncertainty in Ideal Point Estimates via the Parametric Bootstrap.Political Analysis 12 (Spring), 105–27.Google Scholar
Martin, Andrew D., and Quinn, Kevin M.. 2002. “Dynamic Ideal Point Estimation via Markov Chain Monte Carlo for the U.S. Supreme Court, 1953-1999.Political Analysis 10 (Spring), 134–53.Google Scholar
Mearsheimer, John J. 2001. The Tragedy of Great Power Politics. New York: Norton.Google Scholar
Mombauer, Annika. 2002. The Origins of the First World War: Controversies and Consensus. London: Longman.Google Scholar
Morgan, Patrick M. 2003. Deterrence Now. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Most, Benjamin and Starr, Harvey. 1989. Inquiry, Logic, and International Politics. Columbia: University of South Carolina Press.Google Scholar
Murray, Michael P. 2006. “Avoiding Invalid Instruments and Coping with Weak Instruments.Journal of Economic Perspectives 20 (Fall), 111–32.Google Scholar
Organski, A. F. K., and Kugler, Jacek. 1980. The War Ledger. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Persson, Torsten, and Tabellini, Guido. 2002. Political Economics: Explaining Economic Policy. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.Google Scholar
Pollins, Brian M., and Schweller, Randall L.. 1999. “Linking the Levels: The Long Wave and Shifts in U.S. Foreign Policy, 1790–1993.American Journal of Political Science 43 (April): 431–64.Google Scholar
Rivers, Douglas, and Vuong, Quang H.. 1988. “Limited Information Estimators and Exogeneity Tests for Simultaneous Probit Models.Journal of Econometrics 39 (November): 347–66.Google Scholar
Sargent, Thomas J. 1978. “Estimation of Dynamic Labor Demand Schedules under Rational Expectations.The Journal of Political Economy 86 (December), 1009–44.Google Scholar
Schroeder, Paul W. 1994. The Transformation of European Politics. Oxford: Clarendon Press.Google Scholar
Signorino, Curtis S., and Ritter, Jeffrey M.. 1999. “Tau-b or Not Tau-b: Measuring the Similarity of Foreign Policy Positions.International Studies Quarterly 43 (March): 115–44.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Startz, Richard. 2003. “Partial Adjustment as Optimal Response in a Dynamic Brainard Model.” Manuscript, University of Washington.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Thompson, William R. 1986. “Polarity, the Long Cycle, and Global Power Warfare.Journal of Conflict Resolution 30 (December), 587615.Google Scholar
Waltz, Kenneth N. 1979. Theory of International Politics. New York: Random House.Google Scholar
Wendt, Alexander. 1999. Social Theory of International Politics. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar