Hostname: page-component-76fb5796d-skm99 Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-04-25T13:46:02.665Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Hierarchy under anarchy: informal empire and the East German state

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  22 May 2009

Alexander Wendt
Affiliation:
Associate Professor of Political Science at Yale University, New Haven, Connecticut.
Daniel Friedheim
Affiliation:
Visiting Assistant Professor of Political Science at Dartmouth College, Hanover, New Hampshire.
Get access

Abstract

Contemporary international politics embody a tension between formal equality and de facto inequality. States recognize each other as sovereign equals, yet the strong still push around the weak. Among the structures that reflect this tension are informal empires. The dominant assumptions in mainstream international relations theory, materialism and rationalism, privilege the formal equality of states in informal empires a priori: materialism by assuming that authority relations cannot exist between sovereign states; rationalism by assuming that states are sovereign over their own interests. A constructivist approach allows one to explore the hypothesis that transnational authority structures construct state identities and interests. An empirical analysis of the Soviet-East German relationship supports this hypothesis, which raises questions about the emerging study of international governance.

Type
Articles
Copyright
Copyright © The IO Foundation 1995

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

1. On spheres of influence, see especially Keal, Paul, Unspoken Rules and Superpower Dominance (New York: St. Martin's, 1983)CrossRefGoogle Scholar; and Triska, Jan, ed., Dominant Powers and Subordinate States (Durham, N.C.: Duke University Press, 1986)Google Scholar. On intervention, see, for example, Vincent, John, Nonintervention and International Order (Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press, 1974)Google Scholar; and Little, Richard, “Revisiting Intervention: A Survey of Recent Developments,” Review of International Studies 13 (01 1987), pp. 4960CrossRefGoogle Scholar. And on great power management, see Klein, Robert, Sovereign Equality Among States (Toronto: University of Toronto Press, 1974)Google Scholar; and Clark, Ian, The Hierarchy of States (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1989)CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

2. As Waltz puts it, the “state defines for itself how it will cope with its internal and external problems, including whether or not to seek assistance from others and in doing so to limit its freedom by making commitments to them.” See Waltz, Kenneth, Theory of International Politics (Boston: Addison-Wesley, 1979), p. 96Google Scholar.

3. Waltz, Kenneth, Man, the State, and War (New York: Columbia University Press, 1959)Google Scholar.

4. For further development of this map, see Wendt, Alexander, Social Theory of International Politics (Cambridge: Cambridge University PressCrossRefGoogle Scholar, forthcoming), chap. 1. A related version is presented in Jepperson, Ronald, Wendt, Alexander, and Katzenstein, Peter, “Norms, Identity, and Culture in National Security,” in Katzenstein, Peter, ed., Culture and Security (New York: Columbia University PressGoogle Scholar, forthcoming).

5. For a constructivist critique of materialism in social theory that still acknowledges an important role for material forces, see Porpora, Douglas, “Cultural Rules and Material Relations,” Sociological Theory 11 (07 1993), pp. 212–29CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

6. Wendt, Alexander, “Anarchy is What States Make of It: The Social Construction of Power Politics,” International Organization 46 (Spring 1992), pp. 391425CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

7. For an example of such reasoning, see Mearsheimer, John, “The False Promise of Institutionalism,” International Security 19 (Winter 1994/1995), pp. 549CrossRefGoogle Scholar. For a response, see Wendt, Alexander, “Constructing International Politics,” International Security 20 (Summer 1995), pp. 7181CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

8. For an example of previous studies using dependency theory, see Zimmerman, William, “Dependency Theory and the Soviet-East European Hierarchical Regional System,” Slavic Review 37 (12 1978), pp. 604–23CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

9. For neorealist assumptions of sovereignty, see Waltz, , Theory of International Politics, pp. 9596Google Scholar; and Mearsheimer, , “The False Promise of Institutionalism,” p. 11Google Scholar.

10. The reason for this neglect may lie in the “production of like units” argument, which makes processes of identity and interest formation uninteresting. For other individualist interpretations of neorealism, see Ashley, Richard K., “The Poverty of Neorealism,” International Organization 38 (Spring 1984), pp. 225–86CrossRefGoogle Scholar; and Wendt, Alexander, “The Agent-Structure Problem in International Relations Theory,” International Organization 41 (Summer 1987), pp. 335–70CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

11. For a good overview of principal-agent models see Moe, Terry, “The New Economics of Organization,” American Journal of Political Science 28 (11 1984), pp. 739–77CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

12. See, respectively, for example, Ashley, Richard, “The Geopolitics of Geopolitical Space,” Alternatives 12 (10 1987), pp. 403–34CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Cox, Robert, “Gramsci, Hegemony, and International Relations,” Millennium 12 (Summer 1983), pp. 162–75CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Runyan, Anne Sisson and Peterson, V. Spike, “The Radical Future of Realism: Feminist Subversions of IR Theory,” Alternatives 16 (Winter 1991), pp. 67106CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Meyer, John, “The World Polity and the Authority of the Nation-State,” in Bergesen, Albert, ed., Studies of the Modern World System (New York: Academic Press, 1980), pp. 109–37Google Scholar; and Bull, Hedley, The Anarchical Society (New York: Columbia University Press, 1977)CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

13. Our goal here is to clarify how informal empires are structured and work rather than to specify the conditions under which their parties will engage in particular behaviors; we are thus interested in “how” rather than “why” questions. On this distinction see Cross, Charles, “Explanation and the Theory of Questions,” Erkenntnis 34 (03 1991), pp. 237–60CrossRefGoogle Scholar. For an earlier version of our substantive argument see Wendt, Alexander and Barnett, Michael, “Dependent State Formation and Third World Militarization,” Review of International Studies 19 (10 1993), pp. 321–47CrossRefGoogle Scholar. Scholarship on informal empire is divided between that which focuses on political authority and that more concerned with economic control. Much of the latter has roots in an article by Gallagher, John and Robinson, Ronald, “The Imperialism of Free Trade,” Economic History Review 6 (02 1953), pp. 115CrossRefGoogle Scholar. For a sampling of recent work along these lines, see Mommsen, Wolfgang and Osterhammel, Jiirgen, eds., Imperialism and After (London: Allen and Unwin, 1986)Google Scholar. Our concern is with structures of political authority, which may or may not be tied to structures of economic dominance.

14. See Waltz, , Theory of International Politics, pp. 114–16Google Scholar.

15. On anarchy-hierarchy as a continuum, see Milner, Helen, “The Assumption of Anarchy in International Relations Theory: A Critique,” Review of International Studies 17 (01 1991), pp. 6785CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Watson, Adam, The Evolution of International Society (London: RKP, 1992), pp. 1316CrossRefGoogle Scholar; and Buzan, Barry and Little, Richard, “The Idea of ‘International System’: Theory Meets History,” International Political Science Review 15 (07 1994), pp. 231–55CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

16. Thus, the phrase “centralized authority,” which regularly appears in international relations scholarship, is not redundant. For a related and more fully developed attempt to break down the anarchy-hierarchy continuum into a two-dimensional space, see Nau, Henry, “Identity and International Politics,” manuscript, Department of Political Science, George Washington University, Washington, D.C., 1994Google Scholar.

17. On this important point, see Rosenau, James, “Capabilities and Control in an Interdependent World,” in The Study of Global Interdependence (London: Frances Pinter, 1980), pp. 3552Google Scholar; and Doyle, Michael, Empires (Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell University Press, 1986), p. 33Google Scholar.

18. On this basis Watson distinguishes between “dominion” and “hegemony” (in which domestic control is and is not exercised, respectively); see his The Evolution of International Society, p. 15. We agree there is a difference but think it more of degree than kind.

19. On military linkages in the U.S. and Soviet cases, see, for example, Rouquie, Alain, The Military and the State in Latin America (Berkeley: University of California Press, 1987)Google Scholar; and Barany, Zoltan, Soldiers and Politics in Eastern Europe, 1945–90: The Case of Hungary (New York: St. Martin's, 1993)CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

20. Doyle, , Empires, pp. 4244Google Scholar.

21. Waltz, , Theory of International Politics, p. 97Google Scholar.

22. On sovereignty as constitutional independence, see James, Alan, Sovereign Statehood (London: Allen and Unwin, 1986)Google Scholar.

23. See Ruggie, John, “Continuity and Transformation in the World Polity: Toward a Neorealist Synthesis,” World Politics 35 (01 1983), pp. 261–85CrossRefGoogle Scholar; and Kratochwil, Friedrich, Rules, Norms, and Decisions (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1989)CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

24. Kocs, Stephen, “Explaining the Strategic Behavior of States: International Law as System Structure,” International Studies Quarterly 38 (12 1994), pp. 535–56CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

25. On the difference this makes to the character of international politics, see Jackson, Robert and Rosberg, Carl, “Why Africa's Weak States Persist: The Empirical and the Juridical in Statehood,” World Politics 35 (10 1982), pp. 124CrossRefGoogle Scholar; and Strang, David, “Anomaly and Commonplace in European Expansion: Realist and Institutionalist Accounts,” International Organization 46 (Spring 1991), pp. 143–62CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

26. For a suggestive conceptualization of sovereignty as a dominance structure, see the discussion of heteronomy in Onuf, Nicholas and Klink, Frank, “Anarchy, Authority, Rule,” International Studies Quarterly 33 (06 1989), pp. 149–74CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

27. The Japanese prewar presence in Manchuria illustrates an informal empire bordering on formal empire. See Duus, Peter, Myers, Ramon, and Peattie, Mark, The Japanese Informal Empire in China, 1895–1937 (Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press, 1989)Google Scholar.

28. On the importance of legitimacy in international politics, see Franck, Thomas, The Power of Legitimacy Among Nations (Oxford: Oxford University Press, 1990)Google Scholar; and Brilmayer, Lea, American Hegemony: Political Morality in a One-Superpower World (New Haven, Conn.: Yale University Press, 1994)Google Scholar. For a specifically constructivist analysis of legitimacy, see Bukovansky, Mlada, “Normative Innovation in the Eighteenth-Century International System,” manuscript, Dartmouth College, Hanover, N.H., 1995Google Scholar.

29. Blau, Peter, “Critical Remarks on Weber's Theory of Authority,” American Political Science Review 57 (06 1963), pp. 305–16CrossRefGoogle Scholar. The quotation is drawn from p. 307.

30. Dahl, Robert, Democracy and Its Critics (New Haven, Conn.: Yale University Press, 1989), p. 42Google Scholar, emphasis original.

31. Lukes, Steven, “Power and Authority,” in his Moral Conflict and Politics (Oxford: Clarendon Press, 1991), p. 95Google Scholar.

32. On the concept of weak states, see Buzan, Barry, People, States, and Fear, 2d ed. (Boulder, Colo.: Lynne Rienner, 1991)Google Scholar.

33. Fave, Richard Delia, “The Dialectics of Legitimation and Counternorms,” Sociological Perspectives 29 (10 1986), pp. 435–60 and p. 441CrossRefGoogle Scholar in particular.

34. On the lobbyist analogy, see Naimark, Norman, “Soviet-GDR Relations: An Historical Overview,” study no. 51, Bundesinstitüt für ostwissenschaftliche und internationale Studien, Cologne, 1989, p. 8Google Scholar.

35. See Herrmann, Richard, “The Empirical Challenge of the Cognitive Revolution,” International Studies Quarterly 32 (06 1988), pp. 188–89CrossRefGoogle Scholar; and more generally, Merelman, Richard, “Domination, Self-Justification, and Self-Doubt: Some Social-Psychological Considerations,” Journal of Politics 48 (05 1986), pp. 276300CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

36. On this problem in imperial formations, see Herrmann, “The Empirical Challenge of the Cognitive Revolution.”

37. Valdez draws a further distinction between “fundamental” and “operative” levels of ideology in Valdez, Jonathan, Internationalism and the Ideology of Soviet Influence in Eastern Europe (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1993), pp. 58Google Scholar. The quotation is drawn from p. 5.

38. See, respectively, Vladimir Lenin in “The Proletarian Revolution and the Renegade Kautsky,” in Selected Works (1918; reprint, New York: International Publishers, 1967), pp. 39–127; and Joseph Stalin, “The International Situation and the Defense of the USSR,” in Works, vol. 10 (1927; Moscow: Foreign Language Publishing House, 1954), pp. 3–62, as quoted in Valdez, ibid., pp. 27–28.

39. This term is Jones's, Robert, The Soviet Concept of “Limited Sovereignty” from Lenin to Gorbachev (New York: St. Martin's, 1989), p. 96Google Scholar.

40. On this effect of dominance structures, see Wolf, Charlotte, “Legitimation of Oppression: Response and Reflexivity,” Symbolic Interaction 9 (Fall 1986), pp. 217–34CrossRefGoogle Scholar; and England, Paula and Browne, Irene, “Internalization and Constraint in Women's Subordination,” in Agger, Ben, ed., Current Perspectives in Social Theory 12 (Greenwich, Conn.: JAI Press, 1992), pp. 97123Google Scholar.

41. For discussion of how subordinate actors may use this fact to “bind” dominant actors, see Wolf, Charlotte, “Dependency-Bond as Construct,” Symbolic Interaction 17 (Winter 1994), pp. 367–93CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

42. Weber, Max, Economy and Society, An Outline of Interpretive Sociology, vol. 2 (Berkeley: University of California Press, 1978), pp. 1070–110Google Scholar.

43. On this possibility, see Wendt, Alexander, “Collective Identity Formation and the International State,” American Political Science Review 88 (06 1994), pp. 384–96CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

44. See Poggi, Gianfranco, “Max Weber's Conceptual Portrait of Feudalism,” British Journal of Sociology 39 (06 1988), pp. 211–27CrossRefGoogle Scholar; and Galtung, Johan, “A Structural Theory of Imperialism,” Journal of Peace Research, vol. 8, no. 2, 1971, pp. 81109CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

45. On this view of sovereignty, see Miller, J. D. B., “Sovereignty as a Source of Vitality for the State,” Review of International Studies 12 (04 1986), pp. 7989CrossRefGoogle Scholar. Compare Delia Fave, “The Dialectics of Legitimation and Counternorms.” On constraint, see Wolf, “Dependency-Bond as Construct.”

46. For a good discussion of role conflict in international relations, see Barnett, Michael, “Institutions, Roles, and Disorder: The Case of the Arab States System,” International Studies Quarterly 37 (09 1993), pp. 271–96CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

47. Onuf, and Klink, , “Anarchy, Authority, Rule,” p. 163Google Scholar.

48. On external versus internal legitimacy, see Zimmerman, William, “Hierarchical Regional Systems and the Politics of System Boundaries,” International Organization 26 (Winter 1972), pp. 1836 and p. 26CrossRefGoogle Scholar in particular.

49. Stalin is quoted in Djilas, Milovan, Conversations with Stalin (New York: Harcourt, Brace, and World, 1962), p. 153Google Scholar. See also Molotov Remembers: Inside Kremlin Politics: Conversations with Felix Chuev, Resis, Albert, ed. (Chicago: Ivan R. Dee, 1993), p. 86Google Scholar.

50. Ackermann, Contrast Anton, “Gibt es einen besonderen deutschen Weg zum Sozialismus?” (Is there a separate German road to socialism?), Einheit 1 (0102, 1946), pp. 2232Google Scholar, with his “Ūber den einzig möglichen Weg zum Sozialismus” (On the only possible road to socialism), Neues Deutschland 24 09 1948, p. 2Google Scholar.

51. Leonhard, Wolfgang, Child of the Revolution (Cologne: Kiepenheuer and Witsch, 1955; London: Link Inks, 1979)Google Scholar, pp. 362–63.

52. Staritz, Dietrich, “Die SED, Stalin, und die Grundung der DDR,” (The SED, Stalin, and the founding of the GDR) Das Parlament 25 01 1991, p. B5Google Scholar.

53. Wettig, Gerhard, “Die Deutschland-Note vom 10. Mäarz 1952 auf der Basis diplomatischer Akten des russischen Auβenministeriums: Die Hypothese des Wiedervereinigungsangebots” (The Germany note of 10 March 1952, based on diplomatic files of the Russian Foreign Ministry), Deutschland Archiv 26 (07 1993), p. 795Google Scholar.

54. Secret opinion survey conducted by Central Committee and government staff from February to March 1953, as quoted in Loth, Wilfried, Statins unbeliebtes Kind (Stalin's unwanted child) (Berlin: Rowohlt, 1994), p. 196Google Scholar.

55. The Soviet secret police agency was the Ministry of State Security (MGB) until 1954, when it was renamed the State Security Committee (KGB).

56. Das Hermstadt Dokument, das Politbüro der SED und die Geschichte des 17 Juni 1953 (The Herrnstadt file: The SED politburo and the history of 17 June 1953), ed. Herrnstadt, Nadia-Stulz (Berlin: Rowohlt, 1990), pp. 5760Google Scholar. The editor is Herrnstadt's daughter.

57. Richter, James, “Re-examining Soviet Policy Towards Germany in 1953,” Europe-Asia Studies 45, no. 4, 1993, pp. 671–96CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

58. Baras, Victor, “Beria's Fall and Ulbricht's Survival,” Soviet Studies 27 (07 1975), pp. 381–95CrossRefGoogle Scholar. This traditional kremlinology-style analysis has stood the test of time—and of recent revelations from East German and Soviet archives.

59. Gromyko, Andrei, Memories (London: Hutchinson, 1989), p. 318Google Scholar.

60. Zubok, Vladislav M., “Khrushchev and the Berlin Crisis,” working paper 6, Cold War International History Project, Wilson Center, Washington, D.C., (hereinafter CWIHP), 05 1993, p. 5Google Scholar.

61. The Soviet Foreign Ministry drafted no proposed treaty until two months after the ultimatum. See ibid., p. 8.

62. Soviet Embassy First Secretary Kazeinov in East Berlin to Soviet Foreign Ministry, 17 October 1960, as quoted in ibid., p. 14.

63. Ulbricht's influence on Soviet policy “actually increased as the stability of the… regime weakened,” concludes Harrison, Hope M., “Ulbricht and the Concrete Rose: New Archival Evidence on the Dynamics of Soviet-East German Relations and the Berlin Crisis,” working paper 5, CWIHP, 05 1993, p. 20Google Scholar.

64. See then-Soviet Embassy translator Kvitzinsky's, YuliVor dem Sturm (Before the storm) (Frankfurt: Siedler, 1993), p. 179Google Scholar.

65. Letter from Walter Ulbricht to Nikita Krushchev, 15 September 1961, as quoted in Harrison, , “Ulbricht and the Concrete Rose,” p. 52Google Scholar.

66. Slusser identifies Ulbricht's hard-line allies in the Soviet Politburo as Mikhail Suslov and Frol Kozlov. See Slusser, RobertThe Berlin Crisis of 1961: Soviet-American Relations & the Struggle for Power in the Kremlin (Baltimore, Md.: Johns Hopkins University, 1973), pp. 355–58, 377–80Google Scholar, and 440–41.

67. Khrushchev, Nikita, Khrushchev Remembers: The Last Testament, ed. Talbott, Strobe (Boston: Little Brown, 1974), pp. 501–9Google Scholar; and also the supplementary volume, The Glasnost Tapes, p. 170.

68. This figure is taken from the “Arbeitsgemeinschaft 13 August” (The 13 August study group), Tagesspiegel (Berlin), 12 08 1994Google Scholar.

69. See Ministerium für Staatssicherheit (Stasi), “Einsatzbereitschaft, ČSSR” (Readiness preparedness, Czechoslovakia), 13 September 1968; and “Verschärfung der Lage in der ČSSR” (Intensification of the situation in Czechoslovakia), 24 January 1969, B31/68, BdL 86/69, Bundesbeauftragte für die Stasi-Unterlagen-Berlin.

70. “Protokoll einer Unterredung zwischen L. I. Breschnew und Erich Honecker” (Minutes of a conversation between L. I. Brezhnev and Erich Honecker), 28 July 1970, JIV 2/2A/3196, Stiftung Archiv der Parteien und Massenorganisationen der DDR (hereinafter SAPMO-Berlin).

71. Ten SED Poliburo members, “Brief an Breschnew” (letter to Brezhnev), 21 January 1971, in ibid.

72. The treaty also pledged “respect for the independence and autonomy of each of the two states in matters concerning their internal competency within their respective borders.” See Moreton, Edwina, East Germany and the Warsaw Alliance (Boulder, Colo.: Westview, 1978), pp. 151 and 191Google Scholar.

73. Payments totaled DM 3.5 billion. See Rehlinger, Ludwig A., Freikauf, Die Geschäfte der DDR mit politisch Verfolgten, 1963–1989 (Ransom: East German dealing in political prisoners, 19631989) (Frankfurt: Ullstein, 1991), p. 247Google Scholar.

74. Meuschel, Sigrid, Legitimation und Parteiherrschaft: zum Paradox von Stabilität und Revolution in der DDR, 1945–1989 (Legitimacy and party rule: On the paradox of East German stability and revolution, 1945–1989) (Frankfurt: Suhrkamp, 1992), pp. 273–91Google Scholar.

75. Speech by Honecker, Erich, Neues deutschland, 26–27 11 1983, p. 3Google Scholar.

76. The quotations are drawn from Asmus, Ronald, “The Dialectics of Detente and Discord: The Moscow-East Berlin-Bonn Triangle,” Orbis (Winter 1985), pp. 754–58Google Scholar.

77. Shevardnadze, Eduard, The Future Belongs to Freedom (London: Sinclair-Stevenson, 1991), pp. xi, xvi, and 121Google Scholar.

78. National Defense Council, “Analyse des Abkommens… ŭber Fragen, die mit der zeitweiligen Stationierung sowjetischer Streitkrafte auf dem Territorium der D.D.R. zusammenhangen” (Analysis of the agreement… on questions having to do with the stationing of Soviet forces on East German territory), 25 November 1988, VA-01/39592, Militarisches Zwischenarchiv Potsdam, pp. 16–27.

79. The ideologist Hager, Kurt is quoted in Neues Deutschland, 10 04 1987, p. 3Google Scholar.

80. Vyacheslav Dashitschev, memo dated April 1989, as reprinted in Der Spiegel 5 February 1990, pp. 50–51.

81. Horn calls himself “the Hungarian Foreign Minister who opened the Iron Curtain.” See Horn, Gyula, Freiheit, die ich meine (Freedom is what I mean) (Hamburg: Hoffmann and Campe, 1991), p. 308ffGoogle Scholar.

82. “Stenografische Niederschrift,” transcript of the Politburo meeting with Gorbachev at Schloβ Niederschönhausen, 7 October 1989, JIV/971, SAPMO-Berlin.

83. On this endgame of informal empire, see Friedheim, Daniel, “Democratic Transition Through Regime Collapse: Elite Legitimacy and the Peaceful East German Revolution,” Ph.D. diss. Yale University, New Haven, Conn., 1995Google Scholar.

84. For a summary of recent findings about the still-mysterious decision to open the wall, see Maximytschew, Igor F. and Hertle, Hans-Hermann, “Die Maueroffnung” (The wall opening) Deutschland Archiv 27 (11 1994), pp. 1137–58Google Scholar.

85. Egon Krenz to Mikhail Gorbachev, 10 November 1989, IV 2/1/704 SAPMO-Berlin, pp. 83–84.

86. See especially Rosenau, James and Czempiel, Ernst-Otto, eds., Governance Without Government (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1992)CrossRefGoogle Scholar; and Young, Oran, International Governance (Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell University Press, 1994)Google Scholar.

87. For an early appreciation of international institutions as “authority” structures see Ruggie, John, “International Regimes, Transactions, and Change: Embedded Liberalism in the Postwar Economic Order,” in Krasner, Stephen, ed., International Regimes (Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell University Press, 1983), p. 196Google Scholar and passim. For a more recent argument, see Wendt, “Collective Identity Formation and the International State.”

88. Lukes, Steven, Power: A Radical View (London: MacMillan, 1974)CrossRefGoogle Scholar.