Hostname: page-component-848d4c4894-p2v8j Total loading time: 0.001 Render date: 2024-05-17T00:59:02.625Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

From London to Bretton Woods; Sources of Change in Bargaining Strategies and Outcomes*

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  07 April 2017

John S. Odell
Affiliation:
International Relations, University of Southern California

Abstract

Our most prominent theories of international bargaining miss elements essential for understanding national bargaining strategies and international outcomes. In particular they lack sufficient mechanisms of change over time. A focused contrast between the London economic and monetary conference of 1933 and the Bretton Woods conference of 1944 suggests three new dynamic hypotheses. (1) Changes, especially extreme ones, in national market conditions are likely to shift the state's bargaining strategy sharply even if its relative international position has not changed. A slump will produce a more exploitative strategy, while a boom will encourage either a passive or an expansive strategy. (2) Painful national experience running contrary to prevailing policy ideas is likely to discredit those ideas among politicians and officials, turn them toward alternative doctrines, and lead to corresponding strategy changes. The ideas most likely to spread politically are ones which had predicted the currrent problem, and those whose advocates mount the most sophisticated publicity campaign. (3) International technical disagreement can pose a decisive impediment to intergovernmental agreement, while in some conditions at least technical convergence facilitates official agreement.

Type
Articles
Copyright
Copyright © Cambridge University Press 1988

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

REFERENCES

Blum, J. (1959) From The Morgenthau Diaries: Years of Crisis, 1928–1938. Boston: Houghton Mifflin.Google Scholar
Clarke, S. (1973) The Reconstruction of the International Monetary System: The Attempts of 1922 and 1933. Princeton Studies in International Finance No. 33. Princeton: Princeton University, November.Google Scholar
Cooper, R. (1986) International cooperation in public health as a prologue to macroeconomic cooperation. Discussion Papers in International Economics, No. 44. Washington Brookings Institution, March.Google Scholar
Divine, R. (1967) Second Chance: The Triumph of Internationalism in America During World War II. New York: Atheneum.Google Scholar
Eckes, A. Jr, (1975) A Search for Solvency. Austin: University of Texas Press.Google Scholar
Eichengreen, B. (1985) International policy coordination in historical perspective: a view from the interwar years. In Buiter, W. and Marston, R. (eds.), International Economic Policy Coordination. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Feis, H. (1966) 1933: Characters in Crisis. Boston: Little, Brown.Google Scholar
Frankel, J. (1984) The Yen/Dollar Agreement: Liberalizing Japanese Capital Markets. Policy Analyses in International Economics, No. 9. Washington: Institute for International Economics.Google Scholar
Frieden, J. (1988) Sectoral conflict and US foreign economic policy, 1914–1940, International Organization, 42, 1, 5990.Google Scholar
Gallarotti, G. M. (1985) Toward a business-cycle model of tariffs, International Organization 39, 1, 155188.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gardner, R. (1956) Sterling–Dollar Diplomacy. Oxford: Clarendon Press.Google Scholar
Ghosh, A. R. and Masson, P. R. (1988) International policy coordination in a world with model uncertainty, IMF Staff Papers, 35, 2, 230258.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Goldstein, J. (1988) Ideas, institutions, and American trade policy, International Organization 42, 1, 179218.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gourevitch, P. (1986) Politics in Hard Times. Ithaca: Cornell University Press.Google Scholar
Haas, E., Williams, M. P., and Babai, D. (1977) Scientists and World Order. Berkeley: University of California Press.Google Scholar
Hall, P. (ed) (forthcoming) The Political Power of Economic Ideas: Keynesianism across Nations. Princeton: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Harrod, R. (1966) The Life of John Maynard Keynes. London: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Haskel, B. (1974) Disparities, strategies, and opportunity costs: the example of the Scandinavian economic market negotiations, International Studies Quarterly 18, 330Google Scholar
Henning, C. R. (1987) Macroeconomic Diplomacy in the 1980s: Domestic Politics and International Conflict among the United States, Japan, and Europe. Atlantic Paper No. 65. London: Croom Helm, for the Atlantic Institute for International Affairs.Google Scholar
Horsefield, J. K. (1969) The International Monetary Fund 1945–1965. Washington: International Monetary Fund.Google Scholar
Ikenberry, G. J. (1987) The spread of norms in the international system. Paper presented at the annual meetings of the American Political Science Association.Google Scholar
Ikenberry, G.J. (1988) Market solutions for state problems: the international and domestic politics of American oil decontrol, International Organization 42, 1, 151178.Google Scholar
International Monetary Fund (1978). The Rise in Protectionism.Google Scholar
Jervis, R. (1976) Perception and Misperception in International Politics. Princeton: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Jervis, R. (1988) Realism, game theory, and cooperation, World Politics 40, 3–4, 317349.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lord, Kahn (1976) Historical Origins of the International Monetary Fund, in Thirlwall, A. P. (ed.), Keynes and International Monetary Relations. New York: St. Martins Press.Google Scholar
Keynes, J. M. (1933) The Means to Prosperity. London: Macmillan.Google Scholar
King, L. R. and Melanson, P. H. (1972). Knowledge and politics: some experiences from the 1960s, Public Policy (Winter), 20, 1, 83102.Google Scholar
Kingdon, J. (1988) Ideas, politics, and public policies. Paper presented at annual meetings of the American Political Science Association.Google Scholar
Krasner, S. (1976) State power and the structure of international trade, World Politics 28, 317347.Google Scholar
Krasner, S. (1978) Defending the National Interest. Princeton: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Kuznets, S. (1966) Modern Economic Growth. New Haven: Yale University Press.Google Scholar
Lake, D. (1988) Power, Protection and Free Trade: International Sources of US Commercial Strategy 1887–1939. Ithaca: Cornell University Press.Google Scholar
Larson, D. (1985) Origins of Containment: A Psychological Explanation. Princeton: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
League of Nations (1944) International Currency Experience: Lessons of the Inter-War Period, Pub. 1944.II.A.4. Princeton: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
League of Nations (1945) Industrialization and Foreign Trade. Princeton: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Marks, S. (forthcoming) Empirical analyses of the determinants of protection: a survey and some new results, in Odell, J. and Willett, T. (eds.) Blending Economic and Political Analysis of International Trade Policies.Google Scholar
McKeown, T. J. (1983) ‘Hegemonic stability theory and 19th century tariff levels in Europe’, International Organization 37, 1, 7392.Google Scholar
Moley, R. (1939) After Seven Years. New York: Harper.Google Scholar
Odell, J. (1982) US International Monetary Policy. Princeton: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Odell, J. (1987) Constraints on international economic bargaining: theorizing via game models and beyond them. Prepared for the annual meetings of the American Political Science Association.Google Scholar
Oliver, R. (1975) International Economic Co-operation and the World Bank. London: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Oye, K. (1985) The sterling-dollar-franc triangle: monetary diplomacy 1929–1937, World Politics, 38, 1, 73199.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Putnam, R. and Bayne, N. (1987) Hanging Together: Cooperation and Conflict in the Seven-Power Summits. London: Sage Publications.Google Scholar
Rose, R. (1987) The political appraisal of employment policies, Journal of Public Policy 7, 3–4, 285306.Google Scholar
Romasco, A. (1983) The Politics of Recovery: Roosevelt's New Deal. New York: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Simon, H. (1987) ‘Rationality in Psychology and Economics’, in Hogarth, R. and Reder, M. (eds.), Rational Choice: The Contrast between Economics and Psychology. Chicago: University of Chicago Press. Also published in Journal of Business 59 (October 1986).Google Scholar
Stein, Herbert (1969) The Fiscal Revolution in America. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
US Bureau of the Census (1966) Long-Term Economic Growth, 1860–1965.Google Scholar
US President (1971) The United States in the Changing World Economy, Report by Peter Peterson, 2 vols.Google Scholar
Walton, R. E. and McKersie, R. B.. (1965) A Behavioral Theory of Labor Negotiations. New York: McGraw-Hill.Google Scholar
Weatherford, M. S. (1988) The interplay of ideology and advice in economic policy making: the case of political business cycles, Journal of Politics, 49, 925952.Google Scholar