Skip to main content
Log in

Political business cycles and macroeconomic credibility: a survey

  • Published:
Public Choice Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

There is clear evidence that government popularity and election performance is affected, in part, by economic performance, suggesting that governments may manipulate the economy to political advantage. Simple models incorporating adaptive expectations which allowed the government to exploit this relationship were developed in the 1970s, but fell out of fashion with the advent of new-classical economics. However, modern theories of the political business cycle, which are closely related to the macroeconomic policy game literature, assume rational expectations, and lead to forms of political business cycle, driven by the existence of uncertainty of one type or another. The international evidence suggests that some aspects of the theories apply, although definitive conclusions are – as we might expect – hard to come by.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

References

  • Agénor, P.-R. and Taylor, M.P. (1992). Testing for credibility effect. IMF Staff Papers 39: 545–571.

    Google Scholar 

  • Aghion, P. and Bolton, P. (1990). Government domestic debt and the risk of default: A politicale-conomic model of the strategic role of debt. In R. Dornbusch and M. Draghi (Eds.), Public debt management: Theory and History. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Alesina, A. (1987). Macroeconomic policy in a two-party system as a repeated game. Quarterly Journal of Economics 102: 651–678.

    Google Scholar 

  • Alesina, A. (1988). Macroeconomics and politics. NBER Macroeconomics Annual. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Alesina, A. (1990). Evaluating rational partisan business cycle theory: A response. Economics and Politics 5: 1–30.

    Google Scholar 

  • Alesina, A., Cohen, G. and Roubini, N. (1992). Macroeconomic policy and elections in OECD democracies. Economics and Politics 4: 1–30.

    Google Scholar 

  • Alesina, A., Cohen, G. and Roubini, N. (1993). Electoral business cycles in industrial democracies. European Journal of Political Economy 9: 1–23.

    Google Scholar 

  • Alesina, A. and Gatti, R. (1995). Independent central banks: Lowinflation at no cost? American Economic Review(Papers and Proceedings) 85: 196–200.

    Google Scholar 

  • Alesina, A. and Perotti, R. (1995). Fiscal adjustment: Fiscal expansions and adjustment in OECD countries. Economic Policy 21: 205–240.

    Google Scholar 

  • Alesina, A. and Rosenthal, H. (1995). Partisan politics, divided governments and the economy. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Alesina, A. and Roubini, N. (1992). Political cycles in OECD democracies. Review of Economic Studies 59: 663–688.

    Google Scholar 

  • Alesina, A. and Sachs, J. (1988). Political parties and the business cycle in the United States 1948–1984. Journal of Money Credit and Banking 20: 63–82.

    Google Scholar 

  • Alesina, A. and Summers, L.H. (1993). Central bank independence and macroeconomic performance: Some comparative evidence. Journal of Money, Credit and Banking 25: 151–162.

    Google Scholar 

  • Alesina, A. and Tabellini, G. (1988). Credibility and politics. European Economic Review 32: 542–550.

    Google Scholar 

  • Alesina, A. and Tabellini, G. (1990). A positive theory of fiscal deficits and government debt. Review of Economic Studies 57: 403–414.

    Google Scholar 

  • Alogoskoufis, G., Lockwood, B. and Philippopoulos, A. (1992). Wage inflation, electoral uncertainty and the exchange rate regime: Theory and U.K. evidence. Economic Journal 102: 1378–1385.

    Google Scholar 

  • Backus, D. and Driffill, J. (1985). Inflation and reputation. American Economic Review 75: 530–538.

    Google Scholar 

  • Balke, N.S. (1991). Partisanship theory, macroeconomics outcomes and endogenous elections. Southern Economic Journal 57: 920–935.

    Google Scholar 

  • Barro, R. (1977). Unanticipated money growth and unemployment in the U.S. American Economic Review 67: 101–115.

    Google Scholar 

  • Barro, R. (1978). Unanticipated money, output and the price level in the U.S. Journal of Political Economy 86: 549–580.

    Google Scholar 

  • Barro, R. and Gordon, D. (1983a). Rules, discretion, and reputation in a model of monetary policy. Journal of Monetary Economics 12: 101–122.

    Google Scholar 

  • Barro, R. and Gordon, D. (1983b). A positive theory of monetary policy in a natural ratemodel. Journal of Political Economy 31: 589–610.

    Google Scholar 

  • Blais, A. and Nadeau, R. (1992). The electoral budget cycle. Public Choice 74: 389–404.

    Google Scholar 

  • Blanchard, O. (1984). The Lucas critique and the Volcker deflation. American Economic Review(Papers and Proceedings), 74: 211–215.

    Google Scholar 

  • Calvert, R. (1985). Robustness of the multidimensional votingmodel: Candidates' motivations, uncertainty and convergence. American Journal of Political Science 29: 69–95.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cargill, T.F. and Hutchison, M.M. (1991). Political business cycles with endogenous election timing: Evidence from Japan. Review of Economics and Statistics 73: 733–739.

    Google Scholar 

  • Chappell, H. and Keech, W. (1988). The unemployment rate consequences of partisan monetary policies. Southern Economic Journal 55: 107–122.

    Google Scholar 

  • Choi, S.W. and Price, S. (1994). Reduced form estimates of short-term and long-term interest rates for the U.K.; MTFS credibility and the Fisher effect. Mimeo. University of Essex.

  • Christensen, M. (1987a). Disinflation, credibility and price inertia: A Danish exposition. Applied Economics 19: 1353–1366.

    Google Scholar 

  • Christensen, M. (1987b). On interest rate determination, testing for policy credibility, and the relevance of the Lucas critique. European Journal of Political Economy 3: 369–388.

    Google Scholar 

  • Chrystal, A. and Alt, J. (1981). Public sector behaviour: The status of the political business cycle. In D. Currie, R. Nobay, and D. Peel (Eds.), Macroeconomic analysis. London: Croom Helm.

    Google Scholar 

  • Chrystal, A. and Peel, D. (1986). What can economics learn from political science, and vice versa? American Economic Review(Papers and Proceedings), 76: 62–64.

    Google Scholar 

  • Clarke, H., Mishler, W. and Whiteley, P. (1990). Recapturing the Falklands: Models of conservative popularity, 1979–83. British Journal of Political Science 20: 63–82.

    Google Scholar 

  • Clarke, H., Mishler, W. and Whiteley, P. (1990). Recapturing the Falklands:Models of conservative popularity, 1979–83. British Journal of Political Science 20: 63–82.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cukierman, A. (1992). Central bank strategy, credibility and independence: Theory and evidence. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cukierman, A., Webb, S.B. and Neypati, B. (1992). Measuring the independence of central banks and its effect on policy outcomes. The World Bank Economic Review 6: 353–398.

    Google Scholar 

  • Davidson, L.S., Fratianni, M. and Von Hagen, J. (1991). Testing the satisficing version of the political business cycle 1905–1984. Public Choice 73: 21–36.

    Google Scholar 

  • De Grauwe, P. (1990). The costs of disinflation and the European Monetary System. Open Economics Review 1: 147–173.

    Google Scholar 

  • Detken, C. and Gärtner, M. (1991a). Governments, trade unions and the macroeconomy: An expository analysis of the political business cycle. Public Choice 73: 37–54.

    Google Scholar 

  • Detken, C. and Gärtner, M. (1991b). Are German unions rocking the economy?: A reappraisal of the supply-side political business cycle. Applied Economics 25: 1345–1353.

    Google Scholar 

  • Downs, A. (1957). An economic theory of democracy. New York: Harper and Row.

    Google Scholar 

  • Driffill, J. (1992). Changes in regime and the term structure: A note. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control 16: 165–174.

    Google Scholar 

  • Eijffinger, S. and Van Keulen, M. (1994). Central bank independence in another eleven countries. CenTER Discussion Paper No. 9494, University of Tilburg.

  • Eijffinger, S., Van Rooij, M. and Schaling, E. (1994). Central bank independence: A panel data approach. CenTER Discussion Paper No. 9493, University of Tilburg.

  • Ellis, C.J. and Toma, M.A. (1993). Credibility and political business cycles. Journal of Macroeconomics 15: 69–89.

    Google Scholar 

  • Feddersen, T. (1992). A voting model implying Duverger's Lawand positive turnout. American Journal of Political Science 26: 982–962.

    Google Scholar 

  • Fischer, S. (1990). Rules versus discretion in monetary policy. In B. Friedman and F. Hahn, Handbook of monetary economics, 2: 1156–1184. Amsterdam: North-Holland.

    Google Scholar 

  • Frey, B.S. (1978). Modern political economy. Oxford: Martin Robertson.

    Google Scholar 

  • Frey, B.S. and Schneider, F. (1978). A model of politico-economic behaviour in the model of the United Kingdom. Economic Journal 88: 243–253.

    Google Scholar 

  • Frey, B.S. and Schneider, F. (1981). A politico-economic model of the United Kingdom: New estimates and predictions. Economic Journal 91: 737–740.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gärtner, M. (1994a). Democracy, elections and macroeconomic policy: Two decades of progress. European Journal of Political Economy 10: 85–109.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gärtner, M. (1994b). The quest for political cycles in OECD economies. European Journal of Political Economy 10: 427–440.

    Google Scholar 

  • Giavazzi, F. and Pagano, M. (1988). The advantage of tying one's hands. European Economic Journal 32: 1055–1082.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ginsburgh, V. and Michel, P. (1983). Random timing of elections and the political business cycle. Public Choice 40: 155–164.

    Google Scholar 

  • Goodhart, C. and Bhansalli, R.J. (1970). Political economy. Political Studies 18: 43–106.

    Google Scholar 

  • Grier, K.B. (1987). Presidential elections and Federal Reserve policy: An empirical test. Southern Economic Journal 54: 475–486.

    Google Scholar 

  • Grilli, V., Masciandro, D. and Tabellini, G. (1991). Political and monetary institutions and public financial policies in the industrial countries. Economic Policy 13: 341–392.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hakes, D.R. (1988). Monetary policy and Presidential elections: A nonpartisan political cycle. Public Choice 57: 175–182.

    Google Scholar 

  • Haldeman, H.R. and DiMona, J. (1978). The ends of power. New York: Times Books.

    Google Scholar 

  • Harrington, J.E. Jr. (1993). Economic policy, economic performance and elections. American Economic Review 83: 27–42.

    Google Scholar 

  • Haynes, S.E. and Stone, J.A. (1989). An integrated test for electoral cycles in the U.S. economy. Review of Economics and Statistics 71: 426–434.

    Google Scholar 

  • Heylen, F. and Van Poeck, A. (1995). Central bank independence: Only part of the inflation story. Mimeo. University of Ghent.

  • Hibbs, D. (1977). Political parties and macroeconomic policy. American Journal of Political Science 57: 1467–1487.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hibbs, D. (1986). Political parties and macroeconomic policies and outcomes in the United States. American Economic Review(Papers and Proceedings), 76: 66–70.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hibbs, D. (1987). The American political economy. Cambridge,MA: Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hibbs, D. (1992). Partisan theory after fifteen years. European Journal of Political Economy 8: 361–373.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kalecki, M. (1943). Political aspects of full employment. Political Quarterly 14: 322–331.

    Google Scholar 

  • Keil, M. (1988). Is the political business cycle really dead? Southern Economic Journal 55: 86–99.

    Google Scholar 

  • King, M. (1995). Credibility and monetary policy: Theory and evidence. Scottish Journal of Political Economy 42: 1–19.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kremers, J. (1990). Gaining policy credibility for a disinflation. IMF Staff papers 37: 116–145.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kydland, F. and Prescott, E. (1977). Rules rather than discretion: The inconsistency of optimal plans. Journal of Political Economy 85: 473–491.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lindbeck, A. (1976). Stabilization policies in open economies with endogenous politicians. American Economic Review(Papers and Proceedings), 66: 1–19.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lockwood, B., Philippopoulos, A. and Snell, A. (1996). Fiscal policy, public debt stabilisation and politics: Theory and U.K. evidence. Economic Journal 106: 894–911.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lucas, R. (1976). Econometric policy evaluation: A critique. In K. Brunner and A. Meltzer (Eds.), The Phillips curve and labour markets, Vol. 1. Carnegie-Rochester Conference Series on Public Policy. Amsterdam: North-Holland.

    Google Scholar 

  • MacRae, C.D. (1977). A political model of the business cycle. Journal of Political Economy 85: 239–264.

    Google Scholar 

  • McCallum, B. (1977). The political business cycle: An empirical test. Southern Economic Journal 43: 504–515.

    Google Scholar 

  • McCallum, B. (1995). Two fallacies concerning central bank independence. American Economic Review(Papers and Proceedings), 85: 207–211.

    Google Scholar 

  • Milesi-Ferretti, G.M. and Spolaore, E. (1994). How cynical can an incumbent be?: Strategic policy in a model of government spending. Journal of Public Economy 55: 121–140.

    Google Scholar 

  • Miller, W.H. and Mackie, W.M. (1973). The electoral cycle and the asymmetry of government and opposition popularity. Political Studies 20: 263–279.

    Google Scholar 

  • Minford, P. and Peel, D. (1982). The political theory of the business cycle. European Economic Review 17: 253–270.

    Google Scholar 

  • Nannestad, P. and Paldam, M. (1994). The V-P function: A survey of the literature on vote and popularity functions after 25 years. Public Choice 79: 213–245.

    Google Scholar 

  • Nordhaus, W.D. (1975). The political business cycle. Review of Economic Studies 42: 169–190.

    Google Scholar 

  • Nordhaus, W.D. (1989). Alternative approaches to the political business cycle. Brookings Papers 20: 1–49.

    Google Scholar 

  • Norpoth, H. (1987). Guns and butter and economic popularity in Britain. American Political Science Review 81: 949–959.

    Google Scholar 

  • Norpoth, H., Lewis-Beck, M. and Lafay, J.-D. (1991). Economics and politics: The calculus of support. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ohlsson, H. and Vredin, A. (1996). Political cycles and cyclical policies. Scandinavian Journal of Economics 98: 203–228.

    Google Scholar 

  • Paldam, M. and Skott, P. (1995). A rational-voter explanation of the cost of ruling. Public Choice 83: 159–172.

    Google Scholar 

  • Persson, T. and Svensson, L. (1989). Why a stubborn conservative would run a deficit: Policy with time-inconsistent preferences. Quarterly Journal of Economics 104: 325–345.

    Google Scholar 

  • Persson, T. and Tabellini, G. (1990). Macroeconomic policy, credibility and politics. Chur, Switzerland: Harwood Academic Publishers.

    Google Scholar 

  • Persson, T. and Tabellini, G. (1993). Designing institutions for monetary stability, 39: 53- 84. Carnegie-Rochester conference series on public policy. Amsterdam: Elsevier Science Publishers.

    Google Scholar 

  • Persson, T. and Tabellini, G. (Eds.) (1994). Monetary and fiscal policy. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Posen, A.S. (1993). Why central bank independence does not cause low inflation. Central Banking 3: 51–63.

    Google Scholar 

  • Powell, R. (1990). Nuclear deterrence theory: The search for credibility. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Price, S. (1996a). Government popularity and the political business cycle. City University Discussion Paper.

  • Price, S. (1996b). The politics of the political business cycle: A comment. British Journal of Political Science, forthcoming.

  • Price, S. and Sanders, D. (1993). Modelling government popularity in post-War Britain. American Journal of Political Science 37: 317–334.

    Google Scholar 

  • Price, S. and Sanders, D. (1994). Economic competence, government popularity and rational expectations. Manchester School 62: 100–112.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rasmussen, E. (1994). Games and information, 2nd ed. Oxford: Basil Blackwell.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rogoff, K. (1985). The optimum degree of commitment to an intermediate monetary target. Quarterly Journal of Economics 100: 1169–1190.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rogoff, K. (1990). Equilibrium political budget cycles. American Economic Review 80: 21–36.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rogoff, K. and Sibert, A. (1988). Elections and macroeconomic policy cycles. Review of Economic Studies 55: 1–16.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sanders, D., March, D. and Ward, H. (1987). Government popularity and the Falklands War. British Journal of Political Science 17: 281–283.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sanders, D. and Price, S. (1995). Party support and economic perceptions in the U.K., 1979- 87: A two-level approach. In D. Broughton, D. Farrell, D. Denver and C. Rallings (Eds.), British elections and parties yearbook 1994. London: Frank Cass.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sanders, D. and Price, S. (1996). Disentangling the relationship between party support and perceived economic competence: Some evidence from the U.K., 1991 to 1995. Economics Department Discussion Paper, City University.

  • Sargent, T.J. and Wallace, N. (1975). Rational expectations, the optimal monetary instrument and the optimal money supply rule. Journal of Political Economy 83: 241–254.

    Google Scholar 

  • Schultz, K.A. (1995). The politics of the political business cycle. British Journal of Political Science 25: 79–99.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sheffrin, S.S. (1989). Evaluating rational partisan business cycle theory. Economics and Politics 1: 239–259.

    Google Scholar 

  • Strotz, R. (1956). Myopia and inconsistency in dynamic optimization. Review of Economic Studies 23: 100–115.

    Google Scholar 

  • Walsh, C.E. (1995a). Optimal contracts for central bankers. American Economic Review 85: 150–167.

    Google Scholar 

  • Walsh, C.E. (1995b). Is New Zealand's Reserve Bank Act of 1989 an optimal central bank contract? Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, forthcoming.

  • Weber, A.A. (1991). Reputation and credibility in the European Monetary System. Economic Policy 6: 57–102.

    Google Scholar 

  • Weber, A.A. (1992). The role of policymakers' reputations in the EMS disinflations: An empirical evaluation. European Economic Review 49: 55–67.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Price, S. Political business cycles and macroeconomic credibility: a survey. Public Choice 92, 407–427 (1997). https://doi.org/10.1023/A:1004937830968

Download citation

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1023/A:1004937830968

Keywords

Navigation