Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

Precautionary Savings in the Great Recession

  • Published:
IMF Economic Review Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Heightened uncertainty since the onset of the Great Recession has materially increased saving rates, contributing to lower consumption and GDP growth. Consistent with a model of precautionary savings in the face of uncertainty, the paper finds for a panel of advanced economies that greater labor income uncertainty is significantly associated with higher household savings. These results are robust to controlling for other determinants of saving rates, including wealth-to-income ratios, the government fiscal balance, demographics, credit conditions, and global growth and financial stress. The estimates imply that at least two-fifths of the sharp increase in household saving rates between 2007 and 2009 can be attributed to the precautionary savings motive.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Figure 1
Figure 2
Figure 3
Figure 4
Figure 5
Figure 6
Figure 7
Figure 8
Figure 9
Figure 10

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. The role of uncertainty was highlighted by Christina Romer (1990) in her analysis of the Great Depression. She found that a high level of stock market volatility in 1929 induced caution in the purchase of consumer durables and, thereby, contributed to the sharp decline in consumption.

  2. Several other papers have analyzed the determinants of saving rates using cross-country panel data, among which Schmidt-Hebbel, Webb, and Corsetti (1992), Edwards (1996), and Masson, Bayoumi, and Samiei (1998).

  3. Alternatively, we could assume that permanent income Y is multiplied by a lognormally distributed mean-one shock ɛ. The model responses to an increase in the variance of ɛ are qualitatively identical to an increase in unemployment u. We thus preferred to use our unemployment specification since the unemployment rate will be used as one of the regressors.

  4. More precisely, β is set to 0.97933 in order for the model to generate an equilibrium wealth-to-income ratio of 2. This is the average ratio of financial net worth to disposable income in our data set between 2005 and 2009.

  5. For an early discussion of the impact of investment risk on saving, see Sandmo (1970). The ambiguous role of investment risk for aggregate saving in general equilibrium is analyzed in Angeletos (2007).

  6. For the United States, the University of Michigan's index of unemployment expectations provides an alternative measure of unemployment prospects. Carroll and Slacalek (2009) estimate a consumption growth equation using as an explanatory variable the fraction of consumers who expect the unemployment rate to decline over the next year minus the fraction who expect it to increase.

  7. To facilitate comparison with the previous regression results, column (1) of Table 2 reports the estimates in column (3) of Table 1.

  8. It is possible that stock market volatility reduces investment and increases unemployment. The impact of stock market volatility may thus be subsumed in other explanatory variables that we use.

  9. For reference as a baseline, the column (1) of Table 3 includes the results of column (2) in Table 2.

  10. We could have alternatively included the house price-to-income ratio rather than its change. However, that measure would be difficult to interpret since it is a ratio of normalized indices. Furthermore, in our sample, saving rates appear to be correlated with the change in the index rather than the level of the index.

  11. Column (1) is again provided as reference for the reader's convenience; it is the same as column (2) in Table 3.

  12. See Carroll, Slacalek, and Sommer (2012) for a recent analysis of the U.S. saving rate using the senior loan officer survey.

  13. To facilitate the comparison, column (1) of Table 5 repeats the results in column (2) of Table 4. All regressions in Table 5 include country fixed effects.

  14. An appreciation of the Swiss franc (relative to the U.S. dollar) is sometimes seen as a “flight to safety.” Such appreciation behaves in a manner similar to a rise in the TED spread.

  15. We only include those countries with sufficiently complete time-series data to generate fitted values for all the years between 2003 and 2009. This reduces the number of countries from 24 in column (2) of Table 4 and column (5) of Table 6 to 14.

  16. Previous studies have tried to control for precautionary motives only using very imperfect measures, such as inflation.

References

  • Angeletos, George-Marios, 2007, “Uninsured Idiosyncratic Investment Risk and Aggregate Saving,” Review of Economic Dynamics, Vol. 1, No. 1, pp. 1–30.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bloom, Nicholas, 2009, “The Impact of Uncertainty Shocks,” Econometrica, Vol. 77, No. 3, pp. 623–85.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bloom, Nicholas, Max Floetotto, Nir Jaimovich, Itay Saporta-Eksten, and Stephen Terry, 2011, “Really Uncertain Business Cycles,” mimeo, available via the internet: http://www.stanford.edu/~nbloom/RUBC_DRAFT.pdf.

  • Caballero, Ricardo J., 1991, “Earnings Uncertainty and Aggregate Wealth Accumulation,” American Economic Review, Vol. 81, pp. 859–871.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cagetti, Marco, 2003, “Wealth Accumulation over the Life Cycle and Precautionary Savings,” Journal of Business and Economic Statistics, Vol. 21, No. 3, pp. 339–53.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Carroll, Christopher D., 1992, “The Buffer-Stock Theory of Saving: Some Macroeconomic Evidence,” Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, Vol. 2, pp. 62–156.

    Google Scholar 

  • Carroll, Christopher D., and Andrew Samwick, 1997, “Buffer Stock Saving and the Life-Cycle Permanent Income Hypothesis,” The Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. 112, pp. 1–55.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Carroll, Christopher D., and Jiri Slacalek, 2009, The American Consumer: Reforming, or Just Resting?, Available via the Internet: www.econ.jhu.edu/people/ccarroll/papers/ReformingOrResting.pdf.

  • Carroll, Christopher D., Jiri Slacalek, and Martin Sommer, 2012, “Dissecting Saving Dynamics: Measuring Credit, Uncertainty, and Wealth Effects,” mimeo, available via the internet: http://www.econ2.jhu.edu/people/ccarroll/papers/cssUSSaving.pdf.

  • Deaton, Angus, 1991, “Saving and Liquidity Constraints,” Econometrica, Vol. 59, pp. 1221–48.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Edwards, Sebastian, 1996, “Why are Latin America's Saving Rates So Low? An International Comparative Analysis,” Journal of Development Economics, Vol. 51, pp. 5–44.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Eichengreen, Barry, and Kevin O'Rourke, 2010, “What Do the New Data Tell Us?,” VoxEU.org. Available via the Internet: www.voxeu.org/index.php?q=node/3421.

  • Engen, Eric M., and Jonathan Gruber, 2001, “Unemployment Insurance and Precautionary Saving,” Journal of Monetary Economics, Vol. 47, pp. 545–79.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Giavazzi, Francesco, and Michael McMahon, 2012, “Policy Uncertainty and Household Savings,” The Review of Economics and Statistics, forthcoming.

  • Gourinchas, Pierre-Olivier, and Jonathan A. Parker, (2002), “Consumption over the Life Cycle,” Econometrica, Vol. 70, No. 1, pp. 47–89.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Leland, Hayne E., 1968, “Saving and Uncertainty: The Precautionary Demand for Saving,” The Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. 82, No. 3, pp. 465–73.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Loayza, Norman, Klaus Schmidt-Hebbel, and Luis Servén, 2000, “What Drives Private Saving Across the World,” The Review of Economics and Statistics, Vol. 82, No. 2, pp. 165–81.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Krugman, Paul, 2011, Are Other Commodities Like Gold?, Available via the Internet: www.krugman.blogs.nytimes.com/2011/09/07/are-other-commodities-like-gold-quick-and-wonkish/.

  • Masson, Paul R., Tamim Bayoumi, and Hossein Samiei, 1998, “International Evidence on the Determinants of Private Saving,” The World Bank Economic Review, Vol. 12, No. 3, pp. 483–501.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Romer, Christina D., 1990, “The Great Crash and the Onset of the Great Depression,” The Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. 105, No. 3, pp. 597–624.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Salant, Stephen W., and Dale W. Henderson, 1978, “Market Anticipations of Government Policies and the Price of Gold,” The Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 86, No. 4, pp. 627–48.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sandmo, Agnar, 1970, “The Effect of Uncertainty on Saving Decisions,” The Review of Economic Studies, Vol. 37, No. 3, pp. 353–60.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Schmidt-Hebbel, Klaus, Steven B. Webb, and Giancarlo Corsetti, 1992, “Household Saving in Developing Countries: First Cross-Country Evidence,” The World Bank Economic Review, Vol. 6, No. 3, pp. 529–47.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Skinner, Jonathan, 1988, “Risky Income, Life Cycle Consumption, and Precautionary Saving,” Journal of Monetary Economics, Vol. 22, pp. 237–55.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Zeldes, Stephen P., 1989, “Optimal Consumption with Stochastic Income: Deviations from Certainty Equivalence,” Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. 104, pp. 275–98.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Authors

Additional information

*Ashoka Mody is Deputy Director in the IMF Research Department. Franziska Ohnsorge, and Damiano Sandri are economists in the IMF European Department. The authors are grateful to Olivier Blanchard, Christopher Carroll, Thomas Harjes, Philip Lane, Jaewoo Lee, Daniel Leigh, Steve Kamin, Martin Weitzmann, and seminar participants at the Deutsche Bundesbank for comments. The paper has greatly benefited from the comments of the editor, Pierre-Olivier Gourinchas, and two anonymous referees. The views expressed herein are those of the authors and do not necessarily represent those of the IMF or IMF policy.

Appendix

Appendix

Tables A1 and A2

Table A1 Data Appendix
Table A2 Data Definitions and Sources

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Mody, A., Ohnsorge, F. & Sandri, D. Precautionary Savings in the Great Recession. IMF Econ Rev 60, 114–138 (2012). https://doi.org/10.1057/imfer.2012.5

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1057/imfer.2012.5

JEL Classifications

Navigation