Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

Is it the “How” or the “When” that Matters in Fiscal Adjustments?

  • Research Article
  • Published:
IMF Economic Review Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Using data from 16 OECD countries from 1981 to 2014 we study the effects on output of fiscal adjustments as a function of the composition of the adjustment—that is, whether the adjustment is mostly based on spending cuts or on tax hikes—and of the state of the business cycle when the adjustment is implemented. We find that both the “how” and the “when” matter, but the heterogeneity related to the composition is more robust across different specifications. Adjustments based upon permanent spending cuts are consistently much less costly than those based upon permanent tax increases. Our results are generally not explained by different reactions of monetary policy. However, when the domestic central bank can set interest rates—that is outside of a currency union—it appears to be able to dampen the recessionary effects of consolidations implemented during a recession.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. They do so using information from quarterly forecasts of fiscal and aggregate variables from the University of Michigan’s RSQE macroeconometric model, the Survey of Professional Forecasters and the forecasts prepared by the staff of the Federal Reserve Board for the meetings of the Federal Open Market Committee.

  2. They also consider a different measure of slack, related to unemployment rather than to output growth as in AG.

  3. Two related papers which use Canadian data (Owyang and others 2013; Ramey and Zubairy 2015) had found higher multipliers in high unemployment states. Revisiting those findings the authors (in work in progress) find that the difference between the US and Canadian results were probably due to the special circumstances of Canada’s entry into WWII, when output responded to the news long before government spending actually rose.

  4. In a simple real business cycle model, such as Baxter and King (1993), the output multiplier of a positive shift in government spending is below one. In New Keynesian models the magnitude of the output multiplier depends on the nature of the shock that takes the economy to the ZLB. Woodford (2011), Eggertsson (2011) and Christiano and other (2011) consider the case in which the economy reaches the ZLB as a result of a “fundamental” shock. In this case the multiplier can be substantially larger than one as temporary government spending is inflationary and stimulates private consumption and investment by decreasing the real interest rate. Mertens and Ravn (2014) consider instead a situation in which the ZLB is reached following a “non-fundamental” confidence shock: they find that the output multiplier during the ZLB period is quite small. The reason is that, in this situation, government spending shocks are deflationary, raising the real interest rate and reducing private consumption and investment. Exploiting regional variation in military buildups Nakamura and Steinsson (2014) estimate an “open economy relative multiplier” of approximately 1.5. They claim their results are in line with New Keynesian models where government spending has a large effect on output, particularly when the economy is in a liquidity trap. Erceg and Lindé (2013) investigate the effects of a spending-based versus labor tax-based fiscal consolidation in a two-country DSGE model. They find that the effects depend on the degree of monetary accommodation. Under an independent monetary policy (no currency union) cuts in government spending are much less costly than tax hikes. Under a currency union the effect is partially reversed. Indeed, their model predicts that when monetary policy provides too little accommodation—given its focus on union wide aggregates—spending-based fiscal consolidations are more costly in terms of output losses in the short run. In the long run, however, spending cuts are still less harmful than tax hikes, because of real exchange rates and price levels adjustments. The adverse impact of spending-based consolidations (in the short run) is exacerbated when monetary policy is constrained at the ZLB.

  5. Note that our sample of 16 OECD countries differs from the sample of 17 OECD countries considered by Devries and others. We have dropped the Netherlands, which is the only country for which the narrative identified fiscal adjustments are significantly correlated with past output growth. This is not surprising given that the budget rules in the Netherlands include the following provision “...The budget can respond to changes in the economy and measures need not be taken immediately if there is a windfall or setback...” (https://www.government.nl/topics/budget-day/contents/budget-rules). That is, the rule prescribes that the government sets fiscal targets at the beginning of its election term and in the following years deviations from these targets are only allowed for cyclical reasons.

  6. The data used in this paper, as well as the codes we wrote, are available on a dedicated space in the IGIER webpage: www.igier.unibocconi.it/fiscalplans.

  7. As a convention, we use the GDP of the previous period because this was the latest estimate for GDP known by policymakers at the time these fiscal measures were announced. Moreover, current GDP may be affected by contemporaneous fiscal shocks. Results (available upon request) are virtually identical when scaling with current GDP.

  8. Tables and figures are obtained using the data described in Appendix 3 and in Sect. 2.1.

  9. Standard New Keynesian models imply that the effects of permanent changes are quite different from those of temporary changes; permanent tax hikes have stronger contractionary effects than transient ones, and permanent spending cuts are much less contractionary than transient ones (see Erceg and Lindé 2013; Alesina and others 2017).

  10. The non-predictability of fiscal corrections on the basis of output growth is documented by Alesina and others (2017) who verify that GDP does not Granger-cause the narrative fiscal consolidations shocks, according to the procedure by Toda and Yamamoto (1995) which shows no Granger causality on a panel VAR with one lag, and 10 percent Granger causality on a panel with two lags.

  11. Credibility of fiscal consolidations is discussed in Lemoine and Lindé (2016) and Corsetti and others (2012).

  12. To obtain values of F(s) for the entire 1981–2014 sample we use data for output growth in the 2 years prior to the starting date of the estimation.

  13. We obtain this share by considering as years of recession those in which the number of months recorded as recessionary by the NBER is higher than 3.

  14. With \(F(s_{i,t})\) we refer to the economic conditions prevailing at the beginning of the period in which the consolidation is implemented, thus reflecting economic growth in the two previous periods. Consistently with the way we constructed our indicator, in Fig. 1 we plot \(F(s_{i,t+1})\) as a measure of the state of the cycle in period t for comparability with actual recessions.

  15. See Sect. 2.2 for details on how we label plans.

  16. At the estimation stage we include announced fiscal shift to be implemented up to two years in the future, that is, we include \(e_{i,t,t+1}^{a}\) and \(e_{i,t,t+2}^{a}\), and we restrict their coefficients to be equal. We impose this restriction to increase statistical power and because the dynamic effect of these shifts will then be captured by \(e_{i,t.-1,t}^{a}\) as well.

  17. Remember that we do not extract exogenous fiscal shocks from the VAR innovations: the components of our exogenous plans are identified outside the VAR using the narrative identification strategy and are included directly into the model.

  18. Early narrative studies consider measures only upon implementation, using \(f_{i,t}=e_{i,t}^{u}+e_{i,t-1,t}^{a}\) and neglecting \(e_{i,t,t+j}^{a}\), as in Guajardo and others (2014) and Romer and Romer (2010).

  19. Alternatively we could have allowed the inter-temporal structure of plans to be country—rather than plan-specific (see Alesina and others 2015). We opted for the latter to impose restrictions in the auxiliary regressions more similar to those in the main system—i.e., coefficients restricted across countries and unrestricted across types of plans.

  20. Given the presence of nonlinearities, impulse responses are constructed using the generalized method proposed by Koop and others (1996). This implies computing

    $$\begin{aligned} I\left( \mathbf {z}_{i,t},n,\delta ,I_{t-1}\right) =E\left( \mathbf {z}_{i,t+n}\mid \mathbf {e}_{i,t}=\delta ,I_{t-1}\right) -E\left( \mathbf {z}_{i,t+n}\mid \mathbf {e}_{i,t}=0,I_{t-1}\right) \end{aligned}$$

    using the following steps: (i) generate a baseline simulation for all variables by solving the full nonlinear system dynamically forward. This requires setting to zero all shocks for a number of periods equal to the horizon up to which impulse responses are computed, (ii) generate an alternative simulation for all variables by considering a particular plan and then solve dynamically forward the model up to the same horizon used in the baseline simulation, (iii) compute impulse responses to fiscal plans as the difference between the simulated values in the two steps above, (iv) compute confidence intervals by bootstrapping. In constructing the bootstrap we have to deal with dependence in the residuals of our system of 48 (3 variables and 16 countries) estimated equations. We do so by constructing a matrix \(34\times 48\) (our sample is 1981–2014 and it contains 34 annual observations) containing all the residuals in our system and by resampling the rows of such matrix.

  21. The intra-temporal structure of these EB shocks is as follows: \(\tau _{0}^{u}=0.34\), \(g_{0}^{u}=0.52\), \(\tau _{0,1}^{a}=-0.04\), \(g_{0,1}^{a}=0.14\), \(\tau _{0,2}^{a}=0.01\), \(g_{0,2}^{a}=0.03\).

  22. The intra-temporal structure of these TB shocks is as follows: \(\tau _{0}^{u}=0.59\), \(g_{0}^{u}=0.16\), \(\tau _{0,1}^{a}=0.11\), \(g_{0,1}^{a}=0.10\), \(\tau _{0,2}^{a}=0.01\), \(g_{0,2}^{a}=0.02\).

  23. All the results we present are obtained using 1000 bootstrap repetitions.

  24. For \(F\left( s\right)\) we report non-cumulated responses.

  25. Appendix 4 reports the multipliers for these alternative specifications.

  26. More precisely, we perform this check starting form the baseline model and interacting the fiscal shocks in the equation for output with a dummy equal to one for observations at the ZLB and another dummy which equals one for observations outside the ZLB. Then, we perform our simulation using the coefficients estimated on the latter. We do not present the IRFs for consolidations at the ZLB as they are unreliable, being estimated on a very limited number of observations.

  27. The multipliers computed under these two specifications are reported in Appendix 4.

  28. We are grateful to one of our referees for having made this point.

  29. See Appendix 4 for the exact multipliers computed under this alternative model.

  30. Allowing for the presence of TB and EB plans would strengthen our point but at the cost of making the algebra more complicated.

  31. This is the specification adopted by Auerbach and Gorodnichenko (2012a) to estimate a regime-dependent impulse response.

References

  • Alesina, Alberto, Carlo Favero, and Francesco Giavazzi. 2015. “The Output Effect of Fiscal Consolidation Plans.” Journal of International Economics 96(S1): S19–S42.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Alesina, Alberto, Omar Barbiero, Carlo Favero, Francesco Giavazzi, and Matteo Paradisi. 2017. “The Effects of Fiscal Consolidations: Theory and Evidence,” Working Paper N. 23385, National Bureau of Economic Research May 2017.

  • AMECO, AMECO-ECFIN Annual Macroeconomic Database. https://data.europa.eu/euodp/data/dataset/ameco (Accessed on 14 July 2016 for “Final consumption expenditure of general government at current prices” and “Price deflator total final consumption expenditure of general government”; on 20 October 2015 for “Gross fixed capital formation at current prices: general government” and “Price deflator gross fixed capital formation: total economy”).

  • Auerbach, Alan J, and Yuriy Gorodnichenko. 2012a. “Fiscal Multipliers in Recession and Expansion.” In Fiscal Policy after the Financial Crisis, ed. Alberto Alesina, and Francesco Giavazzi, 63–98. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Auerbach, Alan J., and Yuriy Gorodnichenko. 2012b. “Measuring the Output Responses to Fiscal Policy.” American Economic Journal: Economic Policy 4(2): 1–27.

    Google Scholar 

  • Baxter, Marianne, and Robert G. King. 1993. “Fiscal Policy in General Equilibrium.” American Economic Review 83(3): 315–34.

    Google Scholar 

  • Blanchard, Olivier J., and Roberto Perotti. 2002. “An Empirical Characterization of the Dynamic Effects of Changes in Government Spending and Taxes on Output.” The Quarterly Journal of Economics 117(4): 1329–1368.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Caggiano, Giovanni, Efrem Castelnuovo, Valentina Colombo, and Gabriela Nodari. 2015. “Estimating Fiscal Multipliers: News From A Non-linear World.” The Economic Journal 125(584): 746–776.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Christiano, Lawrence, Martin Eichenbaum, and Sergio Rebelo. 2011. “When Is the Government Spending Multiplier Large?” Journal of Political Economy 119(1): 78–121.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Corsetti, Giancarlo, André Meier, and Gernot J. Müller. 2012. “Fiscal Stimulus with Spending Reversals.” Review of Economics and Statistics 94(4): 878–895.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • De Cos, Pablo Hernández, and Enrique Moral-Benito. 2016. “On the Predictability of Narrative Fiscal Adjustments.” Economics Letters 143: 69–72.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Devries, Pete, Andrea Pescatori, Daniel Leigh, and Jaime Guajardo. 2011. “A New Action-Based Dataset of Fiscal Consolidation.” IMF Working Paper 11/128, International Monetary Fund June 2011.

  • Eggertsson, Gauti B. 2011. “What Fiscal Policy is Effective at Zero Interest Rates?” In NBER Macroeconomics Annual 2010, vol. 25, ed. Daron Acemoglu, and Michael Woodford, 59–112. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Erceg, Christopher J, and Jesper Lindé. 2013. “Fiscal Consolidation in a Currency Union: Spending Cuts Vs. Tax Hikes.” Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control 37(2): 422–445.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Guajardo, Jaime, Daniel Leigh, and Andrea Pescatori. 2014. “Expansionary Austerity? International Evidence.” Journal of the European Economic Association 12(4): 949–968.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • IMF, World Economic Outlook Database, April 2015. https://www.imf.org/external/pubs/ft/weo/2015/01/weodata/index.aspx (Accessed on 22 September 2015).

  • Jordà, Òscar. 2005. “Estimation and Inference of Impulse Responses by Local Projections.” The American Economic Review 95(1): 161–182.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jordà, Òscar, and Alan M Taylor. 2016. “The Time for Austerity: Estimating the Average Treatment Effect of Fiscal Policy.” The Economic Journal 126(590): 219–255.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Koop, Gary, M.Hashem Pesaran, and Simon M. Potter. 1996. “Impulse Response Analysis in Nonlinear Multivariate Models.” Journal of Econometrics 74(1): 119–147.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Leeper, Eric M., Todd B. Walker, and Shu-Chun Susan Yang. 2008. “Fiscal Foresight: Analytics and Econometrics.” NBER Working Papers 14028, National Bureau of Economic Research, May 2008.

  • Lemoine, Matthieu and Jesper Lindé. 2016. “Fiscal Consolidation Under Imperfect Credibility.” Working Paper Series 322, Sveriges Riksbank (Central Bank of Sweden) May 2016.

  • Mertens, Karel, and Morten O. Ravn. 2014. “Fiscal Policy in an Expectations-Driven Liquidity Trap.” Review of Economic Studies 81(4): 1637–1667.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Miyamoto, Wataru, Thuy Lan Nguyen, and Dmitriy Sergeyev. 2016. “Government Spending Multipliers Under the Zero Lower Bound: Evidence from Japan.” CEPR Discussion Paper No. DP11633, Centre for Economic Policy Research November 2016.

  • Nakamura, Emi, and Jón Steinsson. 2014. “Fiscal Stimulus in a Monetary Union: Evidence from US Regions.” American Economic Review 104(3): 753–792.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • OECD, OECD Economic Outlook No. 88 (Edition 2010/2). OECD Economic Outlook: Statistics and Projections (Database), 2010. 10.1787/data-00533-en (Accessed on 18 July 2016).

  • OECD, “Historical Population Data and Projections (1950–2050),” OECD Statistics (Database), 2015. http://stats.oecd.org/Index.aspx?DataSetCode=POP_PROJ (Accessed on 21 October 2015; for FIN and SWE on 22 February 2016).

  • OECD, “OECD Economic Outlook No. 97 (Edition 2015/1),” OECD Economic Outlook: Statistics and Projections (Database), 2015. 10.1787/data-00759-en (Accessed on 15 September 2015 for “Gross domestic product, volume, market prices” and “Gross domestic product, value, market prices”; on 15 July 2016 for “Govt. final consumption expenditure, volume”; on 24 September 2015 for “Govt. gross fixed capital formation, volume”).

  • OECD, “OECD Economic Outlook No. 98 (Edition 2015/2),” OECD Economic Outlook: Statistics and Projections (Database), 2015. 10.1787/bd810434-en (Accessed on 25 March 2016).

  • Owyang, Michael T., Valerie A. Ramey, and Sarah Zubairy. 2013. “Are Government Spending Multipliers Greater During Periods of Slack? Evidence from Twentieth-Century Historical Data.” The American Economic Review 103(3): 129–134.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ramey, Valerie A. 2011. “Identifying Government Spending Shocks: It’s all in the Timing.” The Quarterly Journal of Economics 126(1): 1–50.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ramey, Valerie A., and Sarah Zubairy. 2015. “Are Government Spending Multipliers State Dependent? Evidence from U.S. and Canadian Historical Data.” Working Paper, University of California, San Diego.

  • Ramey, Valerie A., and Sarah Zubairy. 2017. “Government Spending Multipliers in Good Times and in Bad: Evidence from U.S. Historical Data,” Journal of Political Economy.

  • Romer, Christina D., and David H. Romer. 2010. “The Macroeconomic Effects of Tax Changes: Estimates Based on a New Measure of Fiscal Shocks.” American Economic Review 100(3): 763–801.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Toda, Hiro Y., and Taku Yamamoto. 1995. “Statistical Inference in Vector Autoregressions with Possibly Integrated Processes.” Journal of Econometrics 66(1): 225–250.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Woodford, Michael. 2011. “Simple Analytics of the Government Expenditure Multiplier.” American Economic Journal: Macroeconomics 3(1): 1–35.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Francesco Giavazzi.

Additional information

First presented at the 2016 IMF Annual Research Conference. We thank two anonymous referees, the editor Linda Tesar, and especially our discussant, Chris Erceg, for his very useful comments. We thank Giorgio Saponaro for his excellent research assistantship.

Appendices

Appendix 1: Predictability and Exogeneity

In a dynamic time-series model, estimation and simulation require, respectively, weak and strong exogeneity: these requirements are different from lack of predictability. To illustrate the point consider the following simplified model, which only includes the unanticipated component of fiscal plans:

$$\begin{aligned} \Delta y_{t}&= \beta _{0}+\beta _{1}e_{t}^{u}+\beta _{3}\Delta y_{t-1}+\beta _{4}\Delta \tau _{t-1}+\beta _{5}\Delta g_{t-1}+u_{1t}\\ e_{t}^{u}&= \gamma _{1}\Delta y_{t-1}+\gamma _{2}\Delta \tau _{t-1}+\gamma _{3}\Delta g_{t-1}+u_{2t}\\ \left( \begin{array}{c} u_{1t}\\ u_{2t} \end{array}\right)&\thicksim N\left[ \left( \begin{array}{c} 0\\ 0 \end{array}\right) ,\left( \begin{array}{cc} \sigma _{11} &{} \sigma _{12}\\ \sigma _{12} &{} \sigma _{22} \end{array}\right) \right] \end{aligned}$$

The condition required for \(e_{t}^{u}\) to be weakly exogenous for the estimation of \(\beta _{1}\) is \(\sigma _{12}=0.\) This condition is independent of \(\gamma _{1},\gamma _{2},\gamma _{3}.\) In other words, when weak exogeneity is satisfied, the existence of predictability does not affect the consistency of the estimate of \(\beta _{1}.\) Moreover \(\beta _{1}\) measures, by construction, the impact on \(\Delta y_{t}\) of \(u_{2t},\) i.e., of the part of \(e_{t}^{u}\) that cannot be predicted by \(\Delta y_{t-1}\), \(\Delta \tau _{t-1}\) and \(\Delta g_{t-1}\). In fact, by the partial regression theorem, estimating first \(\overset{\wedge }{u_{2t}}=e_{t}^{u}-\overset{\wedge }{\gamma _{1}}\Delta y_{t-1}+\overset{\wedge }{\gamma _{2}}\Delta \tau _{t-1}+\overset{\wedge }{\gamma _{3}}\Delta g_{t-1}\) and then \(\delta _{1}\), running \(\Delta y_{t}=\delta _{0}+\delta _{1}\overset{\wedge }{u_{2t}}+v_{t}\), gives \(\overset{\wedge }{\beta _{1}}=\overset{\wedge }{\delta _{1}}.\)

Appendix 2: MA’s Versus VAR’s

The VAR model described in the text model (2) is not the way impulse response functions are constructed in the recent empirical literature. In the literature the effect of narratively identified shifts in fiscal variables relies either on estimates of a truncated MA representation or on linear projection methods. The reason for these choices is that in the presence of multiple nonlinearities the MA representation of a VAR is much heavier than in the linear case—which means it could only be estimated imposing restrictions that limit the relevance of such nonlinearities. Consider for instance the following model in which fiscal adjustment plans have heterogenous effects according to the state of the cycle, but the VAR dynamics does not depend on the state of the economy, that is, using the terminology in the text, \(A_{i}^{E}=A_{i}^{R}\). Assume also that TB and EB plans have identical effects.Footnote 30

$$\begin{aligned} \mathbf {z}_{i,t}=A_{1}\mathbf {z}_{i,t-1}+(1-F(s_{i,t}))B_{1}e_{i,t}+F(s_{i,t})B_{2}e_{i,t}+\mathbf {u}_{i,t} \end{aligned}$$
(4)

where \(\mathbf {z}_{i,t}\) is the vector containing output growth and the growth rates of taxes and spending, \(e_{i,t}\) are, as in the main text, the narratively identified fiscal adjustments and \(\mathbf {u}_{i,t}\) unobservable VAR innovations. From this VAR we would derive the following MA truncated representations:

$$\begin{aligned} \mathbf {z}_{i,t}=\underset{j=0}{\overset{k}{\sum }}A_{1}^{j}\left( (1-F(s_{i,t-j}))B_{1}e_{i,t-j}+F(s_{i,t-j})B_{2}e_{i,t-j}\right) +\underset{j=0}{\overset{k}{\sum }}A_{1}^{j}\mathbf {u}_{i,t-j}+A_{1}^{k+1}\mathbf {z}_{i,t-k-1} \end{aligned}$$

Now apply to this framework the linear projection method. This would amount to deriving impulse responses for the relevant component of \(\mathbf {z}_{i,t}\)—say \(\Delta y_{i,t}\)—running the following set of regressionsFootnote 31:

$$\begin{aligned} \Delta y_{i,t+h}=\alpha _{i,h}+(1-F(s_{i,t}))\beta _{h,1}e_{i,t}+F(s_{i,t})\beta _{h,2}e_{i,t}+\Gamma _{h}\mathbf {z}_{i,t}+\epsilon _{i,t} \end{aligned}$$
(5)

Now compare this with the more general case in which the VAR dynamics is also affected by the state of the cycle—that is remove the restriction \(A_{i}^{E}=A_{i}^{R},(i=1,2,3)\):

$$\begin{aligned} \mathbf {z}_{i,t}=(1-F(s_{i,t}))A_{1}\left( L,E\right) \mathbf {z}_{i,t-1}+F(s_{i,t})A_{1}\left( L,R\right) \mathbf {z}_{i,t-1}+(1-F(s_{i,t}))B_{1}e_{i,t}+F(s_{i,t})B_{2}e_{i,t}+\mathbf {u}_{i,t} \end{aligned}$$

In this case the truncated MA representation would be much more complicated than (5), as the response of \(\mathbf {z}_{i,t+h}\) to \(e_{i,t}\) would depend on all states of the economy between t and \(t+h.\) Estimating the correct linear projection would no longer be feasible.

To further illustrate the point observe that the correct linear projection to estimate the effect of \(e_{i,t}\) on \(\Delta y_{i,t+1}\):

$$\begin{aligned} \Delta y_{i,t+1}&= \alpha _{i,1}+(1-F(s_{i,t+1}))F(s_{i,t})\beta _{1,1}e_{i,t}+(1-F(s_{i,t+1}))(1-F(s_{i,t}))\beta _{1,2}e_{i,t}\nonumber \\&+(F(s_{i,t+1}))F(s_{i,t})\beta _{1,3}e_{i,t}+(F(s_{i,t+1}))(1-F(s_{i,t}))\beta _{1,4}e_{i,t}\nonumber \\&+\Gamma _{h}\mathbf {z}_{i,t}+\epsilon _{i,t} \end{aligned}$$
(6)

is in general different from:

$$\begin{aligned} \Delta y_{i,t+1}=\alpha _{i,h}+(1-F(s_{i,t}))\beta _{1,1}e_{i,t}+F(s_{i,t})\beta _{1,2}e_{i,t}+\Gamma _{h}\mathbf {z}_{i,t}+\epsilon _{i,t} \end{aligned}$$
(7)

Note, in closing, that the cases in which the two representations coincide are very specific. Indeed, when (6) is the data generating process and (7) is estimated, the implied assumption is that the states \(F(s_{i,t+1})=1\) and \(F(s_{i,t+1})=0\) are observationally equivalent.

Summing up: if the data are generated by (6) the VAR representation is much more parsimonious than the linear projection which becomes practically not feasible unless very strong restrictions are imposed on the empirical model.

Table 12 Data sources

Appendix 3: Data Sources

See Table 12.

\(\mathbf {gdpv,}\) \(\mathbf {gdp}\)::

OECD Economic Outlook n.97; for Ireland, IMF WEO April 2015;

\(\mathbf {cgv}\)::

OECD Economic Outlook n.97; for Ireland we used data from AMECO (final consumption expenditure of general government at current prices deflated in 2012 prices with the correspondent deflator series in the AMECO dataset—price deflator total final consumption expenditure of general government);

\(\mathbf {igv}\)::

OECD Economic Outlook n.97; for Austria missing data in the period 1978–1994; for Ireland, Italy, Portugal, Spain, we used data from AMECO (gross fixed capital formation at current prices: general government, deflated with correspondent deflator series in AMECO dataset—price deflator gross fixed capital formation: total economy); note that for Portugal and Ireland series are, respectively, in 2011 and 2012 prices;

\(\mathbf {yrg}\)::

OECD Economic Outlook n.98; for Australia in the period 1978–1988 and Ireland before 1990, Economic Outlook n.88;

\(\mathbf {sspg}\)::

OECD Economic Outlook n.98; for Australia in the period 1978–1988 and Ireland before 1990, Economic Outlook n.88;

\(\mathbf {oco}\)::

OECD Economic Outlook n.98; for Australia in the period 1978–1988 and Ireland before 1990, Economic Outlook n.88;

\(\mathbf {popt}\)::

OECD Historical Population Data and Projections (1950–2050).

The variables we use in the analysis are constructed as follows:

  • GDP deflator

    $$\begin{aligned} pgdp_{i,t}=\frac{gdp_{i,t}}{gdpv_{i,t}} \end{aligned}$$
  • Real per capita GDP growth

    $$\begin{aligned} {\Delta }y_{i,t}=100*\left[ \log \left( \frac{gdpv_{i,t}}{gdpv_{i,t-1}}\right) -\log \left( \frac{popt_{i,t}}{popt_{i,t-1}}\right) \right] \end{aligned}$$
  • Percentage Change of Government Spending (as fraction of GDP)

    $$\begin{aligned} {\Delta }g_{i,t}=100*\left[ \frac{\left( igv_{i,t}+cgv_{i,t}\right) +\frac{oco_{i,t}+sspg_{i,t}}{pgdp_{i,t}}}{gdpv_{i,t}}-\frac{\left( igv_{i,t-1}+cgv_{i,t-1}\right) +\frac{oco_{i,t-1}+sspg_{i,t-1}}{pgdp_{i,t-1}}}{gdpv_{i,t-1}}\right] \end{aligned}$$
  • Percentage Change of Government Revenues (as fraction of GDP)

    $$\begin{aligned} {\Delta }\tau _{i,t}=100*\left[ \frac{\frac{yrg_{i,t}}{pgdp_{i,t}}}{gdpv_{i,t}}-\frac{\frac{yrg_{i,t-1}}{pgdp_{i,t-1}}}{gdpv_{i,t-1}}\right] \end{aligned}$$

Appendix 4: Multipliers in the Alternative Specifications

See Tables 13, 14, 15.

Table 13 Output multipliers in the alternative specifications
Table 14 Output multipliers controlling for monetary policy and excluding zero lower bound observations
Table 15 Output multipliers under alternative specification of F(s)
Fig. 1
figure 1

Evolution of \(F\left( s\right)\) and Recessions. Note. The graph shows the evolution of F(s) for the countries in our sample and years of recession (years of negative growth per capita, shaded areas), 1981–2013

Fig. 2
figure 2

Impulse responses from the model with heterogeneities between EB and TB plans and across states of the cycle. Note. The graph shows the response of VAR variables and F(s) to a deficit reduction plan of 1 percent of GDP. IRFs for tax-based shock starting in recession labeled with stars, for tax-based shock starting in expansion labeled with squares, for expenditure-based shock starting in recession labeled with circles and expenditure-based shock starting from expansion labeled with triangles. Dashed lines and shaded areas are for bootstrapped (1000 repetitions) 90 percent confidence intervals

Fig. 3
figure 3

Impulse responses from the model with heterogeneity only across states of the cycle. Note. The graph shows the response of VAR variables and F(s) to a deficit reduction plan of 1 percent of GDP. IRFs for a plan starting in expansion labeled with circles, for a plan starting in recession labeled with triangles. Dashed lines and shaded areas are for bootstrapped (1000 repetitions) 90 percent confidence intervals

Fig. 4
figure 4

Impulse responses from the model with heterogeneity only between EB and TB plans. Note. The graph shows the response of VAR variables to a deficit reduction plan of 1 percent of GDP. IRFs for tax-based shock labeled with circles, for expenditure-based shock labeled with triangles. Dashed lines and shaded areas are for bootstrapped (1000 repetitions) 90 percent confidence intervals

Fig. 5
figure 5

Impulse responses from the model with heterogeneities between EB and TB plans and across states of the cycle, controlling for monetary policy. a Constrained Monetary Policy. b Unconstrained Monetary Policy. Note. The graph shows the response of VAR variables and F(s) to a deficit reduction plan of 1 percent of GDP in euro area countries—under a common monetary policy—panel (a), and in the other countries—where monetary policy is free to adjust—panel (b). IRFs for tax-based shock starting in recession labeled with stars, for tax-based shock starting in expansion labeled with squares, for expenditure-based shock starting in recession labeled with circles and expenditure-based shock starting from expansion labeled with triangles. Dashed lines and shaded areas are for bootstrapped (1000 repetitions) 90 percent confidence intervals

Fig. 6
figure 6

Impulse responses from the model with heterogeneities between EB and TB plans and across states of the cycle, excluding episodes at the ZLB. Note. The graph shows the response of VAR variables and F(s) to a deficit reduction plan of 1 percent of GDP, from a model where we exclude episodes at the ZLB. IRFs for tax-based shock starting in recession labeled with stars, for tax-based shock starting in expansion labeled with squares, for expenditure-based shock starting in recession labeled with circles and expenditure-based shock starting from expansion labeled with triangles. Dashed lines and shaded areas are for bootstrapped (1000 repetitions) 90 percent confidence intervals

Fig. 7
figure 7

Impulse responses from the model with heterogeneities between EB and TB plans and across states of the cycle, alternative specification of \(F\left( s\right)\). Note. The graph shows the response of VAR variables to a deficit reduction plan of 1 percent of GDP, from a model where we use an alternative specification of F(s) depending on current output growth. IRFs for tax-based shock starting in recession labeled with stars, for tax-based shock starting in expansion labeled with squares, for expenditure-based shock starting in recession labeled with circles and expenditure-based shock starting from expansion labeled with triangles. Dashed lines and shaded areas are for bootstrapped (1000 repetitions) 90 percent confidence intervals. The cycle indicator is held fixed throughout the simulation horizon

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Alesina, A., Azzalini, G., Favero, C. et al. Is it the “How” or the “When” that Matters in Fiscal Adjustments?. IMF Econ Rev 66, 144–188 (2018). https://doi.org/10.1057/s41308-017-0047-z

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1057/s41308-017-0047-z

JEL Classification

Navigation