Skip to main content
Log in

Regulatory changes to bank liability structures: implications for deposit insurance design

  • Original Article
  • Published:
Journal of Banking Regulation Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

“Tiered” depositor (or deposit insurer) preference as exists in Australia and has been recently introduced in the EU and UK calls into question the merits of ex ante fees for explicit, limited deposit insurance under such arrangements. This paper illustrates how, under such arrangements, the “fair price” of deposit insurance and risks to the deposit insurer are reduced to near zero unless virtually all bank non-equity funding is insured deposits. It is also argued that other regulatory changes affecting bank liability structures and resolution arrangements reinforce that effect, while introduction of “resolution funds” calls into question the rationale for a separate deposit insurance fund. While increased use of collateralised financing complicates resolution arrangements and raises other risks for financial stability, its impact on a “fair price” for deposit insurance under tiered preference is minimal.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. EC [4] states that EU591.9 billion (4.6% of EU 2-12 GDP) of government capital support was provided between October 2008 and December 2012.

  2. Birchler [7] notes that “[m]any aspects of deposit priority rules, in particular their joint effects with deposit insurance, may need further investigation”.

  3. While some commentators suggest collateralisation reduces the quantity of bank assets available to meet depositor claims, this argument neglects the fact that deposit or other non-collateralised financing should also be correspondingly lower.

  4. They also can be interpreted as implying a form of depositor preference over any AT1 and Tier 2 forms of debt financing, even if no general depositor preference applies.

  5. Chan-Lau and Oura [9] find that in their analysis “[t]he cost of preferred deposits, declines to only a few basis points above risk-free rate even without the support from a deposit guarantee scheme …as long as the share of preferred deposits remains below 60% of total liabilities.” IADI [2] advocate that a substantial proportion by value of deposits should be uninsured. Cannas et al. [10] estimate the share of covered to total deposits for the EU in 2013 to be just under 50%.

  6. Reuters [11] report that Fitch Ratings, for example, noted that the introduction of depositor preference in Europe could increase the effective asset encumbrance ratio, from the perspective of unsecured creditors, from 28 to 72% with significant implications for recovery rates in the case of insolvency.

  7. Schich et al. [12] note from a study of European banks that “Implicit guarantees persist, however, and their value continues to be significant” despite some decline in the last few years associated with developments in bank regulation and resolution arrangements.

  8. Demirgüç-Kunt et al. [14] note that 88% of the countries in their survey with explicit deposit insurance schemes use ex ante funding.

  9. See for example IMF [18,19,20].

  10. Data provided by IADI from its 2014 survey. Very few EU countries at that time had depositor preference. The figures are also affected by multiple deposit insurance agencies reporting from some jurisdictions.

  11. One country which has explicitly eschewed this route is New Zealand, whose Open Bank Resolution approach involves bail-in, by way of haircut, applied pro rata to all unsecured bank creditors including depositors.

  12. Many commentators have expressed concerns that depositor preference will increase incentives of less preferred stakeholders to “run”.

  13. In practice, there will be other liabilities in insolvency such as unpaid employee entitlements, tax liabilities which, depending upon national legislation, may rank ahead of insured deposits or the insurer in liquidation. So also will collateralised claims.

  14. The FSB [21] identifies four categories: general depositor preference; national depositor preference; eligible depositor preference (preference to categories of deposit eligible for deposit insurance, even if above the maximum cap); insured depositor preference. This ignores “tiered” preference arrangements.

  15. This includes deposits in overseas branches which would have otherwise been eligible.

  16. The unification of member country national deposit insurance schemes into a unified EU scheme is under discussion at the time of writing.

  17. China has local depositor preference and announced in December 2014 the forthcoming introduction of a deposit insurance scheme, but details on preference status of the insurer are not readily available.

  18. The number and size of losses from bank failures impacting on the FDIC fund suggest that even though the FDIC has preference (since 1993) over other (non-depositor) creditors, an important determinant may be the proportion of insured deposits to bank liabilities. At the aggregate level, at the end of 2017, insured deposits at FDIC insured banks were 53% of total deposits and 46% of total liabilities (FDIC [26]. O’Keefe and Ufier [27], however, report that the proportion of deposits insured decreases with size and was 74% for banks with assets between $1 and $10 billion and 97% for the small sample of failed banks between 1984 and 2016 with assets under $1 billion for which data was available. Over the period 1990-2017 (excluding 2007-2010, when the figure was $4.4 billion) the average size of failed institutions was $270 million).

  19. Even though national deposit insurers may not use such explicit option pricing models in determining premiums, risk-based pricing approaches typically reflect similar considerations and, in principle, aim to (a) achieve appropriate compensation for the insurance scheme (or taxpayers) for the value of insurance provided and (b) reduce the incidence of moral hazard.

  20. While they did not explicitly consider non-depositor creditors, in the absence of depositor preference, their analysis can be interpreted to include other creditors with uninsured depositors.

  21. In this experiment, Laeven infers that uninsured debt is treated as equivalent to equity which would understate the reduction in the value of deposit insurance since the implied bankruptcy level of assets (and strike price of the put option used in calculating the insurance premium value) is lower than is actually the case.

  22. For ease of exposition, it is assumed that the deposit insurer inherits the priority status of insured depositors.

  23. It is not identical since the point of bankruptcy differs. The tiered depositor preference result is the same for cases a, b and c because the proportion of insured depositors is held constant.

  24. Alternatively, statutory bail-in powers over bank debt funding may be available to the resolution agency without any contractual provisions being included.

  25. A number of other concerns for deposit insurers if bail-in does occur are addressed in IADI [42] including use of agency funds in an inefficient resolution process and dealing with and disposing of any resulting equity stake.

  26. Merton [28] addressed a similar issue in the context of assessing the value to a bank from the introduction of explicit deposit insurance covering all non-equity (deposit) liabilities. He argued that the value of insurance to the bank is determined by the reduction in the interest rate risk premium it must pay to raise funds. Any underpricing of insurance relative to its “fair value” conditional on the existence of the insurance scheme is an additional benefit to the bank.

  27. It might be argued that recent global regulatory developments, such as increased capital requirements have reduced the value of implicit guarantees. And while they arguably have, it would appear that implicit guarantees remain of value. Schich et al. [12] estimate that significant funding cost advantages of around 132 basis points existed in Europe in 2014 as measured by the effect of credit rating uplifts for banks associated with perceived sovereign support.

References

  1. Nolte, J.P., and I.Z. Khan. 2017. Deposit Insurance Systems: Addressing emerging challenges in Funding, Investment, Risk-based Contributions & Stress Testing. Washington, DC: World Bank.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  2. IADI. 2014. IADI Core Principles for Effective Deposit Insurance Systems. http://www.iadi.org/en/assets/File/Core%20Principles/cprevised2014nov.pdf. Accessed 22 Jan 2019.

  3. Bennett, R.L., and H. Unal. 2015. Understanding the components of bank failure resolution costs. Financial Markets, Institutions & Instruments 24 (5): 349–389.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  4. EC, State aid. 2013. Commission’s new on-line state aid benchmarking tool shows less aid to banks. In Press release IP-13-1301, ed. E. Commission. Brussels: European Commission

  5. Philippon, T., and A. Salord. 2017. Bail-Ins and Bank Resolution in Europe. Geneva Reports on the World Economy Special Report, vol. 4. New York: New York University.

    Google Scholar 

  6. FDIC. 2000. Depositor Priority and rights of set-off (netting). https://www.fdic.gov/deposit/deposits/international/guidance/depositorypriority.pdf. Accessed 22 Jan 2019.

  7. Birchler, U.W. 2000. Bankruptcy priority for bank deposits: A contract theoretic explanation. The Review of Financial Studies 13 (3): 813–840.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  8. Danisewicz, P., et al. 2017. Debt priority structure, market discipline, and bank conduct. The Review of Financial Studies. https://doi.org/10.1093/rfs/hhx111.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  9. Chan-Lau, J.A. and H. Oura, 2016. Bail-In Power, Depositor Preference, and Asset Encumbrance: The End of Cheap Senior Unsecured Debt? A Structural Pricing Perspective. Available at SSRN: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2785992 or http://dx.doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.2785992.

  10. Cannas, G., et al. 2014. Updated estimates of EU eligible and covered deposits. In European Commission Joint Research Centre Technical Report. Institute for the Protection and Security of the Citizen, 1–32.

  11. Reuters, Fitch. 2013. Bank Depositor Preference Still Key Subordination Risk. https://www.reuters.com/article/fitch-bank-depositor-preference-still-ke/fitch-bank-depositor-preference-still-key-subordination-risk-idUSFit65964420130529. Accessed 22 Jan 2019.

  12. Schich, S., M. Bijlsma, and R. Mocking. 2014. Improving the monitoring of the value of implicit guarantees for bank debt. OECD Journal: Financial Market Trends 2014 (1): 7–37.

    Google Scholar 

  13. IADI. 2017. IADI publishes results of its survey on deposit insurance and financial safety net frameworks. https://www.iadi.org/en/assets/File/Press%20Releases/IADI_Annual_Survey_2016_Press_Release.pdf. Accessed 22 Jan 2019.

  14. Demirgüç-Kunt, A., E. Kane, and L. Laeven. 2015. Deposit insurance around the world: A comprehensive analysis and database. Journal of financial stability 20: 155–183.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  15. Demirgüç-Kunt, A., E.J. Kane, and L. Laeven. 2016. Deposit Insurance Design and Implementation: Policy Lessons from Research and Practice. Washington, DC: The World Bank.

    Google Scholar 

  16. IMF. 2016. Financial Sector Assessment Program: European Union. Deposit Insurance, Technical Note, IMF Country Report No. 13/66.

  17. FSB. 2012. TheMatic Review on Deposit Insurance Systems. Financial Stability Board: Basel.

    Google Scholar 

  18. IMF. 2012. Brazil: Financial System Stability Assessment. IMF Country Report No 12/206. IMF.

  19. IMF. 2014. Canada Financial Sector Stability Assessment. IMF Country Report No 14/29.

  20. IMF. 2017. Japan: Financial System Stability Assessment. IMF Staff Country Reports 17/244.

  21. FSB. 2011. Effective Resolution of Systemically Important Financial Institutions—Recommendations and Timelines. Basel: Financial Stability Board

  22. UK Government. 2013. Financial Services (Banking Reform) Act 2013. London: UK Government.

  23. EC. 2014. Bank recovery and resolution—Directive 2014/59/EU. E. Commission.

  24. Hardy, D. 2014. Bank resolution costs, depositor preference and asset encumbrance. Journal of Financial Regulation and Compliance 22 (2): 96–114.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  25. Turner, G. 2011. Depositor protection in Australia. Bulletin of Reserve Bank of Australia December Quarter, 142.

  26. FDIC. 2018. Assets and Liabilities of FDIC-Insured Commercial Banks and Savings Institutions. FDIC. https://www.fdic.gov/bank/analytical/qbp/timeseries/balance-sheet.xls. Acessed 22 Jan 2019.

  27. O’Keefe, J.P., and A.B. Ufier. 2017. Determining the target deposit insurance fund: practical approaches for data-poor deposit insurers. In Deposit Insurance Systems: Addressing emerging challenges in Funding, Investment, Risk-based Contributions & Stress Testing, ed. J.P. Nolte and I.Z. Khan. Washington: World Bank.

    Google Scholar 

  28. Merton, R.C. 1977. An analytic derivation of the cost of deposit insurance and loan guarantees an application of modern option pricing theory. Journal of Banking & Finance 1 (1): 3–11.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  29. Merton, R.C. 1978. On the cost of deposit insurance when there are surveillance costs. Journal of Business 51 (3): 439–452.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  30. Marcus, A.J., and I. Shaked. 1984. The valuation of FDIC deposit insurance using option-pricing estimates. Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking 16 (4): 446–460.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  31. Ronn, E.I., and A.K. Verma. 1986. Pricing risk-adjusted deposit insurance: An option-based model. Journal of Finance 41 (4): 871–895.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  32. Pennacchi, G.G. 1987. A reexamination of the over- (or under-) pricing of deposit insurance. Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking 19 (3): 340–360.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  33. Gropp, R., and J. Vesala. 2004. Deposit Insurance, moral hazard and market monitoring. Review of Finance 8 (4): 571–602.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  34. De Lisa, R., et al. 2011. Modelling deposit insurance scheme losses in a Basel 2 framework. Journal of Financial Services Research 40 (3): 123–141.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  35. Maccaferri, S., J. Cariboni, and W. Schoutens. 2012. Lévy processes and the financial crisis: can we design a more effective deposit protection? International Journal of Financial Research 4 (1): 5.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  36. Geske, R. 1977. The valuation of corporate liabilities as compound options. Journal of Financial and quantitative Analysis 12 (4): 541–552.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  37. Black, F., and J.C. Cox. 1976. Valuing corporate securities: Some effects of bond indenture provisions. The Journal of Finance 31 (2): 351–367.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  38. Osterberg, W.P. 1996. The impact of depositor preference laws. Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland Economic Review 32 (3): 2–11.

    Google Scholar 

  39. Osterberg, W.P., and J.B. Thomson. 1991. The effect of subordinated debt and surety bonds on the cost of capital for banks and the value of federal deposit insurance. Journal of Banking & Finance 15 (4–5): 939–953.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  40. Osterberg, W.P., and J.B. Thomson. 1999. Depositor-preference laws and the cost of debt capital. Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland Economic Review 35 (3): 10–20.

    Google Scholar 

  41. Laeven, L. 2002. Pricing of Deposit Insurance, vol. 2871. Washington, DC: World Bank Publications.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  42. IADI. Deposit Insurance and Bail-in: Issues and Challenges. http://www.iadi.org/en/assets/File/Public_Consultation/Bail-in_Research_Paper_Final_Draft_for_IADI_Public_Consultation.pdf. Accessed 22 Jan 2019.

  43. Hüpkes, E.H. 2011. The Role of Deposit Protection and Resolution Policy in Promoting Financial Stability. In IADI Research Conference. BIS.

  44. EC. 2014. Single resolution mechanism—Regulation (EU) No 806/2014. European Commission.

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Kevin Davis.

Additional information

Publisher's Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Prepared for symposium in honour of Professor David Mayes at The University of Auckland on April 9, 2018. David was a good friend and valued colleague and co-author who is sadly missed. He was an important member of the Australia–New Zealand Shadow Financial Regulatory Committee, bringing an all too rare blend of practical knowledge and insights and academic rigour and curiosity to its deliberations.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Davis, K. Regulatory changes to bank liability structures: implications for deposit insurance design. J Bank Regul 21, 95–106 (2020). https://doi.org/10.1057/s41261-019-00094-0

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1057/s41261-019-00094-0

Keywords

Navigation