Skip to content
Licensed Unlicensed Requires Authentication Published by De Gruyter September 26, 2013

Overeducation and skill-biased technical change

  • Xavier Cuadras-Morató EMAIL logo and Xavier Mateos-Planas EMAIL logo

Abstract

There is evidence that rising overeducation has coincided with rapid skill-biased technical change (SBTC). This paper shows that a SBTC can cause a rise in overeducation as firms looking for educated workers become more selective and turn down the less skilled candidates. This result, while consistent with the evidence, is in contrast with the implications of recent search and matching models of the labor market. Here we present a model of a segmented labor market, with imperfect correlation between the individual ability and the observed education of workers, and a fixed cost of setting up a job. A numerical illustration for the US in the period 1970–1990 demonstrates that overeducation rises and that it can in turn be significant for the response of unemployment rates and wage inequality to a SBTC.


Corresponding authors: Xavier Cuadras-Morató, Universitat Pompeu Fabra and Barcelona GSE, Economics and Business, Ramon Trias Fargas, 25-27 Barcelona 08015, Spain, e-mail: ; Xavier Mateos-Planas, Queen Mary University of London, School of Economics and Finance, Mile End Road, London E14NS, UK, e-mail:

  1. 1

    The literature is vast. See Autor, Katz, and Kearney (2008) for an overview of the evidence.

  2. 2

    Acemoglu (1999), Albrecht and Vroman (2002) and Dolado, Jansen, and Jimeno (2009).

  3. 3

    A worker is defined as overeducated when she is employed in an occupation whose required qualifications are lower than her own educational level.

  4. 4

    See also Wolff (2000, table 2.2) for additional evidence.

  5. 5

    See also Chevalier (2003).

  6. 6

    See Bowles, Gintis, and Osborne (2001) for a review.

  7. 7

    See Goos and Manning (2007), Goos, Manning, and Salomons (2009) and Autor, Katz, and Kearney (2008) for evidence on job polarization in the UK, Europe, and the US.

  8. 8

    Slonimczyk (2013) also invokes the idea of polarization to suggest an empirical connection from SBTC to overeducation.

  9. 9

    Formally, overeducation arises in situations in which educated workers accept job offers from both educated and non educated firms (pooling equilibrium), as opposed to situations where educated workers do not take low qualification jobs and wait for better opportunities (separating equilibrium). Dolado, Jansen, and Jimeno (2009) extend that model with on the job search where overeducation is a more transitory situation.

  10. 10

    Chassamboulli (2011) presents a similar model although does not analyze the issue of SBTC and focuses instead on the cyclical behaviour of skill mismatches.

  11. 11

    In the literature there are directed search models with heterogeneous agents and wage posting (our model has wage bargaining instead), but they do not deal with the issue of overeducation. In Shi (2002) wage offers are made conditional on workers’ types, while in Peters (2010), Eeckhout and Kircher (2010), and Lang, Manove, and Dickens (2005) wage offers cannot be conditioned on them.

  12. 12

    Chevalier and Lindley (2009), Chevalier (2003), Pryor and Schaffer (1997) and papers reviewed in Leuven and Oosterbeek (2011).

  13. 13

    A similar assumption is made in Mortensen and Pissarides (1999).

  14. 14

    We will consider only equilibria in which the educated and skilled will always target vacancies of the educated type, so we omit this choice to save notation.

  15. 15

    Note that, as (8) must hold, from (3) and (6) workers always accept the job offers they receive.

  16. 16

    Skilled educated workers must decide to participate in the educated segment. Otherwise non-skilled workers would be the only participants in it, which would be inconsistent with the restriction on pji’s.

  17. 17

    Specifically, zse=μ(s, e)/(μ(s, e)+μ(ns, e)) when πnse=1, and zse=1 otherwise. Instead, for the non-educated segment, the analogous mapping has no discontinuity as both skills are hired there.

  18. 18

    In their steady-state model, like in ours, equilibrium unemployment is neutral with respect to the common trend in market productivity, hence, after de-trending, a permanent skill-biased shock to technology can be interpreted as a mean-preserving spread change. Cuadras-Morató and Mateos-Planas (2006) perform the same type of exercise. In Acemoglu (1999) the cost of vacancies is endogenous and increases when, in the course of SBTC, the productivity of skilled workers increases, thus also rendering non-skilled workers less productive relative to aggregate variables. This is also true in Moore and Ranjan (2005) where a SBTC brings about shifts in sectoral demands.

  19. 19

    For instance, Katz and Murphy (1992) or, more recently, Autor, Katz, and Kearney (2008), as well as Krusell et al. (2000) study the role of technology for the wage structure focusing on changes in the quality of labor inputs relative to skill-neutral changes. Thus, abstracting from changes in absolute output arising from factor-neutral technological change and from changes in the scale of the economy, non-skilled productivity falls and skilled productivity rises relative to aggregate output and, hence, relative to other aggregate variables. See, for example, Greenwood and Yorukoglu (1997) for a macroeconomic analysis containing this feature.

  20. 20

    This is the version of SBTC in Albrecht and Vroman (2002) and Shi (2002).

  21. 21

    First, as one of two possible equilibria, but eventually as a unique one.

  22. 22

    This calibration follows Cuadras-Morató and Mateos-Planas (2006) closely. Further details and data sources can be found there.

  23. 23

    Other specifications leave the results largely unaffected. This is the case, for example, when the changes in productivity are weighted by demographic size.

  24. 24

    The quantitative implications for inequality and unemployment are obviously less satisfactory. The significance of overeducation for those variables is preserved though.

  25. 25

    However, once the equilibrium has switched to the overeducation regime – perhaps because of SBTC – this change in the quality of educated workers would further increase, as a direct composition effect, the proportion of overeducated individuals. Evaluating its actual contribution to observed changes in overeducation would require the quantitative analysis of a more elaborated model, possibly involving a richer distribution of skill levels.

  26. 26

    We thank the editor Arpad Abraham for his suggestions on this.

The paper has benefited from the comments and useful suggestions of two referees and the Editor, Arpad Abraham. We also appreciate comments by Jan Eeckhout and participants at various conferences and seminars. Cuadras-Morató thanks the Ministerio de Educación y Ciencia under project SEJ 2007-64340/ECON and the support of the Barcelona Graduate School of Economics and of the Government of Catalonia.

Appendix 1-Hiring and career choice.

Consider an equilibrium. Then πnse=0 if and only if ϕ=1. The argument is as follows.

If πji=1 then (6) and (8) imply that W(j, i)–U(j, i)>0. Using this in (2) and (3) shows that if πji=1 then

with w(j, i)–b(w(j, i))>0. On the other hand, if πji=0 then, by (3), (r+ρ)U(j, i)=b(w(j, i)).

First one has to prove that πnsne=1 and πnse=0 imply ϕ=1. The result requires, from (4), U(ns, e)<U(ns, ne). Given the preceding discussion, it suffices to prove that w(ns, ne)>w(ns, e), which follows by using (11).

Second one has to prove the reverse that πnsne=1 and ϕ=1 imply πnse=0. One can proceed by contradiction by assuming πnse=1. Use the discussion opening this proof to write the expressions for U(ns,e) and U(ns, ne). Using that ve>vne and, from (11), that w(ns, e)>w(ne, ne), it follows that U(ns, e)>U(ne, ne). From (4) this is a contradiction with the assumption that ϕ=1.

References

Acemoglu, D. 1999. “Changes in Unemployment and Wage Inequality: An Alternative Theory and Some Evidence.” American Economic Review 89 (5): 1259–1278.10.1257/aer.89.5.1259Search in Google Scholar

Albrecht, J., and S. Vroman. 2002. “A Matching Model with Endogenous Skill Requirements.” International Economic Review 43 (1): 283–305.10.1111/1468-2354.t01-1-00012Search in Google Scholar

Autor, D. H., F. Levy, and R. J. Murnane. 2003. “The Skill Content of Recent Technological Change: An Empirical Exploration.” The Quarterly journal of economics 118 (4): 1279–1333.10.1162/003355303322552801Search in Google Scholar

Autor, D. H., L. F. Katz, and M. S. Kearney. 2008. “Trends in US Wage Inequality: Revising the Revisionists.” The Review of Economics and Statistics 90 (2): 300–323.10.1162/rest.90.2.300Search in Google Scholar

Bowles, S., H. Gintis, and M. Osborne. 2001. “The Determinants of Earnings: A Behavioral Approach.” Journal of Economic Literature 39 (4): 1137–1176.10.1257/jel.39.4.1137Search in Google Scholar

Chassamboulli, A. 2011. “Cyclical Upgrading of Labor and Employment Differences Across Skill Groups.” The B.E. Journal of Macroeconomics 11 (1):(Contributions), Article 14.Search in Google Scholar

Chevalier, A. 2003. “Measuring Over-Education.” Economica 70 (279): 509–531.10.1111/1468-0335.t01-1-00296Search in Google Scholar

Chevalier, A., and J. Lindley. 2009. “Overeducation and the Skills of UK Graduates.” Journal of the Royal Statistical Society: Series A (Statistics in Society) 172 (2): 307–337.10.1111/j.1467-985X.2008.00578.xSearch in Google Scholar

Cuadras-Morató, X., and X. Mateos-Planas. 2006. “Skill Bias and Employment Frictions in the US Labor Market 1970–1990.” International Economic Review 47 (1): 129–160.Search in Google Scholar

Dolado, J. J., M. Jansen, and J. F. Jimeno. 2009. “On-the-Job Search in a Matching Model with Heterogeneous Jobs and Workers.” The Economic Journal 119 (534): 200–228.10.1111/j.1468-0297.2008.02210.xSearch in Google Scholar

Eeckhout, J., and P. Kircher. 2010. “Sorting and Decentralized Price Competition.” Econometrica 78 (2): 539–574.10.3982/ECTA7953Search in Google Scholar

Goos, M., and A. Manning. 2007. “Lousy and Lovely Jobs: The Rising Polarization of Work in Britain.” The Review of Economics and Statistics 89 (1): 118–133.10.1162/rest.89.1.118Search in Google Scholar

Goos M., A. Manning, and A. Salomons. 2009. “Job Polarization in Europe.” The American Economic Review 99 (2): 58–63.10.1257/aer.99.2.58Search in Google Scholar

Gould, E. D. 2002. “Rising Wage Inequality, Comparative Advantage, and the Growing Importance of General Skills in the United States.” Journal of Labor Economics 20 (1): 105–147.10.1086/323934Search in Google Scholar

Greenwood, J., and M. Yorukoglu. 1997. 1974. In Carnegie-Rochester Conference Series on Public Policy 46: 49–95.10.1016/S0167-2231(97)00004-3Search in Google Scholar

Katz, L. F., and K. M. Murphy. 1992. “Changes in Relative Wages, 1963–1987: Supply and Demand Factors.” The Quarterly Journal of Economics 107 (1): 35–78.10.2307/2118323Search in Google Scholar

Krusell, P., L. E. Ohanian, J. V. Ríos-Rull, and G. L. Violante. 2000. “Capital-Skill Complementarity and Inequality: A Macroeconomic Analysis.” Econometrica 68 (5): 1029–1053.10.1111/1468-0262.00150Search in Google Scholar

Lang, K., M. Manove, and W. T. Dickens. 2005. “Racial Discrimination in Labor Markets with Posted Wage Offers.” American Economic Review 95 (4): 1327–1340.10.1257/0002828054825547Search in Google Scholar

Layne, C. 2010. “The Demographics of Over-Education in the US, 1971–2006.” paper presented to the 2010 International Labor Process Conference.Search in Google Scholar

Leuven, E., and H. Oosterbeek. 2011. “Overeducation and Mismatch in the Labor Market.” Handbook of the Economics of Education 4: 283.10.1016/B978-0-444-53444-6.00003-1Search in Google Scholar

Moore, M. P., and P. Ranjan. 2005. “Globalisation vs Skill-Biased Technological Change: Implications for Unemployment and Wage Inequality*.” The Economic Journal 115 (503): 391–422.10.1111/j.1468-0297.2005.00994.xSearch in Google Scholar

Mortensen, D. T., and C. A. Pissarides. 1999. “Unemployment Responses to Skill-biased Technology Shocks: The Role of Labour Market Policy.” The Economic Journal 109 (455): 242–265.10.1111/1468-0297.00431Search in Google Scholar

Peters, M. 2010. “Noncontractible Heterogeneity in Directed Search.” Econometrica 78 (4): 1173–1200.10.3982/ECTA8379Search in Google Scholar

Pryor, F. L., and D. Schaffer. 1997. “Wages and the University Educated: A Paradox Resolved.” Monthly Labor Review 120 (7): 3–18.Search in Google Scholar

Shi, S. 2002. “A Directed Search Model of Inequality with Heterogeneous Skills and Skill-Biased Technology.” Review of Economic Studies 69 (2): 467–491.10.1111/1467-937X.00213Search in Google Scholar

Slonimczyk, F. 2013. “Earnings Inequality and Skill Mismatch in the US: 1973–2002.” Journal of Economic Inequality 11 (2): 163–194.10.1007/s10888-011-9212-1Search in Google Scholar

Vaisey, S. 2006. “Education and its Discontents: Overqualification in America, 1972–2002.” Social Forces 85 (2): 835–864.10.1353/sof.2007.0028Search in Google Scholar

Wolff, E. 2000. “Technology and the Demand for Skills.” In The overeducated worker?: The economics of skill utilization, edited by L. Borghans and A. de Grip, chapter 2. Cheltenham, UK and Northampton, US: Edward Elgar Publishing.Search in Google Scholar

Published Online: 2013-09-26
Published in Print: 2013-01-01

©2013 by Walter de Gruyter Berlin Boston

Downloaded on 4.5.2024 from https://www.degruyter.com/document/doi/10.1515/bejm-2013-0020/html
Scroll to top button