SciELO - Scientific Electronic Library Online

 
vol.44 issue1Estimating the effects of teen motherhood in Chile: a family fixed effects approachSpatial matching for Georeferencing Data of Household Surveys author indexsubject indexarticles search
Home Pagealphabetic serial listing  

Services on Demand

Journal

Article

Indicators

Related links

  • On index processCited by Google
  • Have no similar articlesSimilars in SciELO
  • On index processSimilars in Google

Share


Estudios de economía

On-line version ISSN 0718-5286

Estudios de Economía vol.44 no.1 Santiago June 2017

http://dx.doi.org/10.4067/S0718-52862017000100033 

Article

Optimal Zoning in Spatial Differentiation

Diferenciación Espacial y Zonificación Óptima

Hamid Hamoudi* 

Isabel Rodríguez** 

Marcos Sanz Martín-Bustamante*** 

*Universidad Rey Juan Carlos de Madrid. Paseo Artilleros s/n. Madrid 28032, España. Fundamentos de Análisis Económico. Email: hamid.hamoudi@urjc.es.

**Universidad Rey Juan Carlos de Madrid. Paseo Artilleros s/n. Madrid 28032, España. Fundamentos de Análisis Económico. Email: isabel.rodriguez@urjc.es.

***[Corresponding autor] Universidad Rey Juan Carlos de Madrid. Paseo Artilleros s/n. Madrid 28032, España. Fundamentos de Análisis Económico. Email: marcos.sanz.martinbustamante@ urjc.es.

Abstract:

This study analyzes optimal zoning policy in a duopolistic spatial competition framework for both circular and linear spaces. A regulator is introduced in the third stage of the price-location game through a welfare function to model zoning preferences from firms and consumers. An equilibrium outcome is then found for both spatial configurations. When the regulator is inclined to favor consumers (consumer-oriented) both firms are restricted to locate at one point to serve the whole market. Nevertheless, when the preferences of the regulator are biased towards firms (firm-oriented) the zoning area is maximized, with both firms being located at the market boundaries. The equilibrium outcome confirms location patterns found in real life situations under a non-neutral regulator.

Keywords: Zoning; spatial competition; welfare function; equilibrium results; industrial policy.

Resumen:

Este estudio analiza las políticas de zonificación óptima en un marco de competencia espacial duopolística para los espacios lineal y circular. En la tercera etapa del juego de localización-precio se introduce un regulador que optimiza una función de bienestar que formaliza las preferencias de empresas y consumidores. Se obtiene el resultado de equilibrio para ambas configuraciones espaciales. Cuando el regulador se siente inclinado a favorecer a los consumidores (orientación al consumidor), ambas empresas restringen su localización a un mismo punto para atender el mercado entero. Sin embargo, cuando las preferencias del regulador están sesgadas hacia las empresas (orientación empresarial) se maximiza el área zonificada y ambas empresas se sitúan en los extremos del mercado. Este resultado ilustra ejemplos reales en presencia de autoridades reguladoras no neutrales.

Palabras clave: Zonificación; competencia espacial; función de bienestar; resultado de equilibrio; política industrial.

Introduction

In this study a regulator designing an urban area divides the space for two uses: an exclusively residential area for consumers (residents) and a hybrid area where consumers and firms may locate. The aim of the regulator when restricting certain areas is to provide a high-quality environment, reduce trouble and reduce local crime.

Cities and urban contexts provide many real examples of externality effects from firms on the rest of society. In some cases public intervention may become an internalization mechanism for negative externalities such as pollution or lack of residential space. Regulators may decide on the size of the restricted area depending on different factors. For instance, historical cities with a well-preserved city centers sometimes introduce specific regulations for firms locating in the old town area. Authorities may seek to preserve quality space for residents and tourists in order to obtain political influence (i.e. votes from residents) and welfare gains. Furthermore, coastal cities relying on income from tourists may control the number and location of firms near the beach to keep it clear and prevent excessive noise or pollution. The location of shopping centers close to ring roads around big cities such as London or Madrid is a strategic choice which may be influenced by zoning restrictions. Many large cities in the world such as México D.F, Paris, London or New Delhi are using zoning as a policy tool to regulate traffic (i.e. restriction of car access to city areas or any other type of zoning). These types of policies effectively crowd-out firms through regulation by forcing them to locate their activities in unrestricted areas. Zoning may, therefore, be a useful tool for urban design or industrial policies; nevertheless, it may have adverse effects when wrongly implemented. Thus, non-regulation and free entrance may be optimal in terms of welfare under certain assumptions. However, when zoning is implemented authorities need to find regulating instruments (i.e. strategic location choices) which enable them to reduce harmful external factors efficiently. Authors like Mills (1989), Henderson (1991), Miceli (1992) and Wheaton (1993) have shown that zoning may become an interesting urban planning tool. This study focuses on the design of regulation in a duopolistic framework which includes a regulator with alternative political profiles.

Spatial competition models provide strong insights to study zoning policies. One of the most widely extended models in this field is Hoteling’s (1929). There are two crucial assumptions in the original setup depicted in the model: i) firms compete in a duopolistic framework; ii) consumers are distributed uniformly along the market space. Both premises are too restrictive to explain certain equilibrium patterns -for instance: endogenous location of consumers-. Thus, Hotelling’s model and some of its premises have been reconsidered to encompass a higher number of location patterns.

On one hand, when the model is expanded to an oligopolistic competition framework to allow entrance of more than one firm a strong version of the minimum differentiation principle holds. In fact, Economides (1993) finds that equilibrium in location does not exist in Hotelling’s linear model when the number of firms is increased to three or more. The reason is that firms have a strong incentive to approach the center but no equilibrium exists where the whole market is served. When boundaries in the space location (i.e. linear case) exist, equilibrium ceases to exist. However, for the circular case equilibrium is reestablished as boundaries disappear under this spatial configuration.

Another strand of models is developed for the analysis of equilibrium outcomes under non-simultaneous location of firms. Neven (1987) considers a sequential entry of firms in a differentiated industry within a Hotelling model where firms choose location (product) with subsequent price equilibrium. His findings show that early entrants locate first, impeding later competitors to locate between them. Several sunk costs are identified corresponding to different natural market configurations so that equilibrium may be found for two or more firms. The sequential entry competition dynamic is extended by Gupta (1992) to a more general framework by assuming perfect foresight from firms. By modelling a Stackleberg game for the location of firms Anderson (1987) offers an alternative explanation: equilibrium occurs with the first firm locating in the center whilst keeping higher profits than the rest. This outcome is coherent with the entry-deterrent and monopoly solutions. Lastly, Pu-Yan Nie (2011, 2013 & 2014) and Yang & Nie (2015) consider the influence of other variables such as search costs to explain location patterns -i.e. industrial clusters- in low transportation cost frameworks.

A regulator may be introduced in spatial competition framework by specifying a third stage in the location-price game. Since authorities serve the interests of consumers and firms it is common to define a welfare function as the sum of surplus for both economic agents. However, we use a social welfare function formalized as a linear combination of the firm’s profit and the utility for consumers1 (Hamoudi & Risueño, 2012). This welfare function is interpreted in terms of the profile and interests of the public authority.

Research on spatial competition introduces the role of the regulator by focusing mainly on optimal firm location, regulated zone dimensions, pricing, land usage2 and social welfare effects. For instance, Lai & Tsai (2004) examine Hotelling’s linear city model with restrictions on the location of firms. They show that maximum differentiation holds under Bertrand competition and social welfare is improved. Tsai et al. (2006) analyses how zoning affects the location of firms and the rents derived from land. Chen & Lai (2008) investigate the effects of symmetric zoning in the linear city, finding that firms locate in equilibrium at the extremes of the zoning area under Cournot competition. These authors conclude that introducing a regulated zoning area can be welfare improving. Matsumura & Matsushima (2012) study a duopoly model with restrictions on the location of firms. Their objective is to analyze the effects on consumer’s welfare. The model shown is related to the issue of urban sprawl in order to determine the allowed dimension of economic activities. Hamoudi & Risueño (2012) consider the effect of zoning regulation in duopolistic circular model with Bertrand competition where consumers and firms are situated in different geographical zones within a city. They show that the optimal size of the shopping area depends on the regulator’s political profiles. Furthermore, Hamoudi et al. (2015) complete the analysis of the location of firms by studying different specification for transportation costs to establish an equivalence result for convex and concave transport cost functions. The authors show that only a concave specification yields equilibrium.

The rest of this article is organized as follows: Section 2 develops the circular model while Section 3 focuses on the linear model. In both cases, the model is first depicted in order to determine price-location equilibrium and under optimal zoning policies. Each part concludes with specific remarks on the effects of regulation over competition.

The circular model

The model

We study a location model where a regulatory authority is responsible for the design of an area within a unitary circular space. Any point in the perimeter of the circle corresponds to a number from the interval [0,1]. The southeasters’ point is 0 and we move anti clockwise from there. Points 0 and 1 will therefore coincide. The planner divides the circle in two regions: the first one is a commercial area bounded by points v1, v2 such that 3where firms and families locate. The second one is the residential area where only families locate (see Figure 1). There are two firms located at x1 and x2 such that and selling the same good in the commercial area at prices p1 and p2 respectively.

A continuum of consumers spreads uniformly along the city. Each consumer buys one unit of good and pays the cost of transporting the good from the firm’s location to her residence. The transportation cost incurred by the consumer is assumed to be a quadratic function of distance. Specifically, the function is taken as:

, i = 1,2,

FIGURE 1 CIRCULAR MARKET 

where the distance between location consumer x and the location firm xi, is defined as the shortest distance on the circle between the two points x, xi.

Let s be the gross surplus for an arbitrary consumer, x. We assume s is large

enough (s >> 0) to allow all consumers to buy. Utility for consumer x from buying the good from firm i is, therefore, given as: . A consumer purchases the product from firm i when ui (x) < uj (x), i = 1,2, ij . The model is then formalized as a three-stage game (Fudenberg & Tirole, 1987). In the first stage, the regulator chooses the optimum size of the commercial area; in the second stage firms choose their locations simultaneously; in a third stage firms decide on their prices at the same time. The game is then solved by backward induction. Given the size of the commercial area, equilibrium

outcomes are found to substitute in the profit function of firms.

Price and location equilibrium

The fact that the location space for firms is restricted does not alter the location of indifferent consumers4. Thus, the demand function remains the same as for the unrestricted space case, De Frutos et al. (1999). We can then proceed with a change of variable: z = x2 - x1, where z represents the distance between both firms, that is, the difference between the chosen characteristics. The demand function is represented as follows:

In addition, demand for firm 2 is: D2 = 1 - D1.

Once consumer demands are found, the profit functions can be calculated using the following relation: para i = 1,2j = 1,2 for ij .

The existence of Nash equilibrium in prices is guaranteed for any size of the market v and any value of z, since profit functions are strictly concave (again as in De Frutos et al., 1999). The solution corresponds to: Consequently, the demand and profit functions can be written as:

Proposition 1:

There is a unique Nash location equilibrium for any commercial area given by:

Demonstration: (See Appendix). ■

The perfect equilibrium subgame expressions for prices demand and profits are:

Remarks

In the circular model under zoning regulation, the location pattern satisfies the maximum differentiation principle: We observe that if v2 − v1 = 1/2 , the location equilibrium remains the same as in the circular model without zoning (i.e.De Frutos et al., 1999). Therefore, zoning half of the circular market does not affect the location strategies of firms. The intuition behind the maximum differentiation result is straightforward: firms locate at in order to avoid competition and reap some spatial monopolistic rents.

The demands are equal and independent of the size v. Thus, zoning does not affect the structure of demand in the location equilibrium. Prices and profits are also equal to each other and they are increasing in v.

If the regulator chooses a large value for v, competition decreases. Therefore, if firms were able to decide on their location, they will always be interested in the commercial area to be as large as possible in which case, v = 1/2. On other hand, the regulator can force both firms to undergo more competition which could eventually yield to zero profits. Indeed, if v tends to zero, prices and benefits will also approach as both firms engage in Bertrand competition. Subsequently, zoning regulation can be seen as an industrial instrument to limit firms’ monopoly power.

Given that the location pattern in this zoning model still satisfies the maximum differentiation principle, the purpose of a regulator is to find the dimensions for a commercial area and an exclusively residential area.

Optimal zoning

Town planners take their decisions based on the interests of firms and consumers and for this reason the objective function is usually defined as the sum of firm’s profit and consumer’s utility. In contrast to this type of model, at this point, we use an objective function for the regulator described as a linear combination from profits (firms) and utility (consumers). This, therefore, allows us to introduce the possibility to formally represent the preferences of a regulator in terms of the weight attached to surplus from producers and consumers. The welfare function can now be written as:

Where:

  1. λ is the weight given by the regulator to firms. Thus, (1 - λ) accounts for the weight given to consumers.

  2. is firms’ profit.

  3. , is the surplus from consumers.

  4. S is gross utility from consumers.

  5. CT (v) means total transport cost paid by consumers.

Total transport cost is then formalized as:

  • I1 corresponds to total transport cost paid by consumers when they buy the good from seller 1.

  • I2 is the total transport cost paid by consumers when they buy the product from seller 2.

Where are indifferent consumers in terms of buying from firm 1 or firm 25.

We can then represent as follows:

  • decreases as the size of v increases. The mixed location area for both consumers and firms is:

    When the regulator seeks to minimize the total transport cost for consumers (i.e. their disutility), λ = 1/2 in the objective function. The optimal size for this case is v = 1/2.

Utility for the total of consumers is given by:

  • is decreasing and reaches a maximum for v equal zero. In contrast to firms, consumers are interested in a minimum size for the mixed consumers- firms area which then turns into a single point, thus, v = 0. The price of the good is equal to zero for this value and transport cost reaches a maximum. Consumers pay a high price for transport cost but are compensated by a zero cost for the good. The intuition for this result is illustrated by the fact that consumers travel massively (i.e. underplay direct transportation costs) when a free good is offered.

Given the expression for the welfare function W (v) the following can be highlighted:

  • When λ >1/2, the regulator favors firm’s interest over consumer’s.

  • However, when λ <1/2, the opposite happens.

  • When λ =1/2, we have a neutral case in which the same weight is given to both groups: consumers and firms. Furthermore, the welfare function for this case is depicted as:

The optimal strategy for the regulator is given by:

By substituting the expression for BN(v) y CT(v) in the objective function we obtain the following:

Proposition 2:

For , the optimal size for the mixed firms-consumers area is given as:

Demonstration: (See Appendix). ■

Remarks

Note that zoning occurs in different ways depending on the bias of the regulator, thus, effectively changing the spatial distribution of firms:

  • If , the regulator is consumer-biased. Agglomeration is then obtained, that is, location space for firms is reduced to a single point, . In the this case, competition among firms is very intense (Bertrand type) which implies the price of all products is close to zero. These factors clearly benefit consumers as they can live in a larger area enjoying more welfare. On the other hand, in terms of industrial policy, the regulator allows only one characteristic of the good to be produced despite the possibility to produce two characteristics. In this case, we obtain the following results:

  1. Total utility for consumers:

    ,

  2. The profit function of firms equals: B(0) = 0,

  3. The welfare function can be expressed as:

    .

  • If λ = 3/7 , social welfare remains constant and independent from the size of the commercial area. The regulator has no a priori preference on the dimension of the commercial area.

  • When

    , the regulator favors firms because the value of v,

    is their preferred result. In this case, firms separate away from each other (i.e. dispersion), locating at the endpoints of the interval.

    As a result, the regulator is supporting an industrial policy in favor of product variety. In this case:

  1. Total utility for consumers:

    ,

  2. Profit of firms:

    ,

  3. The welfare function:

    .

We can observe that a firm biased regulator, , reduces total utility for consumers and improves profit for firms, .

These results are represented in figure 3 by drawing the optimum size for the commercial area:

FIGURE 2 OPTIMUM SIZE FOR THE COMMERCIAL AREA 

The horizontal axis shows the value of parameter λ whereas the vertical axis shows the value of parameter v. The thick line refers to the optimum size of the commercial area.

The optimal solution v*, supports the popular view on the effects of the behavior of the authorities given their preferences.

The linear city model

The model

As in the circular case, a regulator may restrain the production area to the segment (v1, v2). Inside this interval the location of firms is given by (x1, x2), so that 0≤v1 ≤ x1≤ x2≤ v2≤16. Consumers also distribute uniformly among the linear city of length one [0,1] where the areas [0, v1) y (v2, 1] are only residential. Again, this model is set up as a three stage game. In the first stage, a regulator chooses the size of the commercial area. In the second and third stages firms simultaneously decide on location and price.

We can represent the model as follows:

FIGURE 3 LINEAR MARKET 

Using a quadratic function for transportation cost defined as:

where the distance between the location for consumer x and the location of firm xi.

Thus, the indifferent consumer is:

Given the uniform distribution of consumers along the linear city, the results obtained for the regulated model are the same as in D’Aspremont et al. (1979) except for equilibrium in location given by: The following results are derived in this context:

In order to compare profits between the firms is calculated.

Given the equilibrium locations: , the firm closer to the center of the commercial area obtains higher profits. Under symmetric zoning, v1 + v2 = 1 firms obtain the same profit. The regulator has no a priori preferences for any of the firms since both are private profit maximizing entities. In turn, we focused on the study of optimal zoning for the commercial area in the symmetric zoning case where: v1 + v2 = 1 .

Optimal zoning

The last stage of the game for given prices and locations in equilibrium is then solved. The optimal size of the commercial area is determined by restricting the study to the symmetric case in which v1 + v2 = 1, where v2 - v1 = v.

Equilibrium locations under this condition are also symmetric to the extremes of the market. The above obtained results can then be expressed as:

Prices and profit, therefore, depend on the size of the area, v. Firms ideally prefer the maximum size for the commercial, v = 1.

As in the circular case, the objective function for the regulator is given as:

In this function λ, BN(v), S, CT(v), are respectively the weight given to firms by the regulator; the total profit, consumers’ total surplus, and total transportation cost which is:

Notice that the expression for transportation cost here is identical to the circular city case. In this case, however, v ∈ [0,1] implies that:

  • CT(v) is decreasing for , is increasing , and reaches its minimum value for v = 1/2, thus, firms locate in the following points: , for which

    . This is an identical result to the optimal social value stemming from the unrestricted linear city model seen before.

  • The total price

    paid by consumers reaches a minimum for v equal zero:

Due to the above argument, consumers are interested in the size of the commercial area being reduced to a single point, v = 0, which involves firms locating at exactly the same point: The price of the good is equal to zero for this value but transport cost reaches a maximum. Therefore, it is worth for consumers pay high transport costs since that will mean a null price , for the good as in the circular case.

Given the expressions for , objective function of the regulator is written as:

Proposition 5:

For 0 ≤ v ≤ 1 , the optimal size of for the mixed consumers-firms area is given by:

Demonstration: (See Appendix). ■

Remarks

  • If the regulator is consumer-biased (λ ≤ 3 / 7 ≈ 0,42) and the commercial area is restricted to

    , the endpoints of the restricted interval coincide with

    . Firms subsequently locate at the same point,

    . They engage in Bertrand competition, with null prices

    . Agglomeration takes place and minimum differentiation in product variety (industrial policy) holds. By calculating, and, the following results are obtained:

  1. Utility for the total of consumers is:

    ,

  2. The profit function for the firms equals: B(0) = 0,

  3. The welfare function can be expressed as:

  • If the regulator’s bias (λ) takes some value between 3/7 and 5/9; the optimal size v∗ reaches a minimum in the lower end of the interval for λ = 3/7, and a maximum in the upper end for λ = 5/9, that is, for , . In this case is increasing, meaning that when λ is higher the value of v is larger. We then move from agglomeration to dispersion (from minimum differentiation to maximum differentiation). When planner has more incentives to overvalue consumer, he assigns a value of λ = 1/2, the optimal size of the commercial area is reached for . In this case, U(0), B(0)

and W(0) are given by:

  1. Total utility for consumers is:

    ,

  2. The profit function of firms is:

  3. The welfare function is:

  • - Finally, if the regulator is firms-biased,

    , then , or identically,

    . The mixed consumers-firms area corresponds to the interval [0, 1]; firms can locate in the whole market and they choose maximum differentiation in terms of product variety. This corresponds to agglomeration when interpreted in terms of location patterns. Now, U(0), B(0) and W(0) correspond to:

  1. Utility for the total of consumers:

    ,

  2. The profit of firms is: B(1) = b

  3. The welfare function is:

    .

Similar to the circular model when the regulator is firm-biased and (3/7 ≤ λ≤ 1 the total utility for consumers decreases and U(1 / 2) < U(0) . Firm’s profits improve in this context: B(1 / 2) > B(0) .

We can represent these analytical results in the following figure:

FIGURE 4 LINEAR MODEL 

Again, the optimal solution v* in the linear model, supports the popular belief on the behavior of the authorities.

The results for the optimal size of the mixed commercial-residential are the same for the linear and the circular model, as shown in the following table:

Conclusions

In this article we analyse spatial competition in a regulated market where consumers locate freely along the market space, whereas firms are obliged to locate in a restricted area. We study the influence of regulation on competition in a circular space and then extend the analysis to a linear space. This article contributes to the spatial competition literature by providing a framework to investigate the role the regulator plays on the location pattern of firms. A specific functional form to model the behavior of the regulator is interpreted in terms of the values of the parameters. Equilibrium results are then shown to highlight similarities in the behavior pattern of firms, regardless of the specific spatial configuration. Interestingly, a concave specification for transportation cost yields equilibrium outcomes.

This type of approach is fruitful from two perspectives. On one hand, equilibrium for both different spatial configurations can be categorized in terms of dispersion/agglomeration. This interpretation offers insights for urban policy. Given the weights the regulator places on consumers or firms, different location patterns will emerge from the location and price behavior of firms. Zoning may, therefore, become a useful tool from the perspective of urban policies and city planning. This is particularly relevant given the increasing role of cities -i.e. smart cities- in the economies of emerging and advanced countries.

On the other hand, these results can also be scrutinized from an industrial policy perspective as minimum or maximum differentiation cases. A regulator may, under these premises, exert influence on the location of firms to supply key markets. Zoning may turn into a useful tool for industrial policies. The political-economy issue of re-industrialization may be analyzed in light of the regulator bias towards firms of consumers. As a consequence, the results obtained for both spatial configurations can be interpreted in terms of the redistribution of welfare. It is proved that a regulator influences location patterns of firms, affecting the structure of the market. In this respect it can be stated that strong competition is triggered in the consumer-biased regulator case whereas weak competition arises in the case of a firms-biased regulator. For a neutral regulator we find moderate competition. These results contribute to establish theoretical support to understand the role of regulation in spatial competition.

Acknowledgments

*We thank the editor of Estudios de Economía and two anonymous reviewers for very helpful comments and suggestions on the original manuscript. This article has received financial support from: “Proyecto de Excelencia Investigadora: Análisis Económico de Políticas Públicas (URJC-BSCH)”.

References

Anderson, S. (1987). “Spatial competition and price leadership”. International Journal of Industrial Organization, 5 (4), pp. 369-398. [ Links ]

Armstrong, M., Cowen, S., Vickers, J. (1994). “Regulatory Reform: Economic Analysis and the British Experience”. MIT Press. [ Links ]

Baron, DP., Myerson, R.B. (1982). “Regulating a Monopolist with Unknown Costs”. Econometrica, Vol. 50, Nº 4, pp. 911-930. [ Links ]

Chen, Ch.-Sh., Lai, F.-Ch. (2008). “Location Choice and Optimal Zoning under Cournot Competition”, Regional Science and Urban Economics Nº 38, pp. 119-126. [ Links ]

D’Aspremont, C., Gabszewicz, J.J., Thisse, J.F. (1979). “On Hotelling’s Stability in Competition”, Econometrica, Nº 47, pp. 1145-1150. [ Links ]

De Frutos, M.A., Hamoudi, H. Jarque, X. (1999). “Equilibrium Existence in the Circle model with linear quadratic transport cost”, Regional Science and Urban Economics, Nº 29, pp. 605-615. [ Links ]

Economides, N. (1993). “Hotelling’s main street with more than two competitors”. Journal of Regional Science, 33 (3), 303-319. [ Links ]

Fudenberg, D., Tirole, J. (1987) “Understanding rent dissipation: on the use of game theory in industrial organization”. The American Economic Review, 77 (2) 176-183. [ Links ]

Fujita, M., & Thisse, J. F. (1986). “Spatial competition with a land market: Hotelling and Von Thunen unified”. The Review of Economic Studies, 53 (5), 819-841. [ Links ]

Gupta, B. (1992). “Sequential entry and deterrence with competitive spatial price discrimination”. Economics Letters, 38 (4), 487-490. [ Links ]

Hamilton, JH., Thisse JF, Weskamp, A. (1989). “Spatial discrimination: Bertrand versus Cournot in a model of location choice”. Regional Science and Urban Economics 59 (3), pp. 87-615. [ Links ]

Hamoudi, H. and Risueño, M. (2012). “The effect of zoning in Spatial Economics.” Journal of Regional Science. Vol. 52, Nº 2, pp. 361-374. [ Links ]

Hamoudi, H., Iglesias, I. M. R., & Martín-Bustamante, M. S. (2015). “The equivalence of convex and concave transport cost in a circular spatial model with and without zoning”. Estudios de Economía, 42 (1), pp. 5-20. [ Links ]

Henderson, J. (1991). “Optimal regulation of land development through price and fiscal controls”. Journal of Urban Economic Nº 30, pp. 64-82. [ Links ]

Lai, F.-Ch. and Tsai, J.F. (2004). “Duopoly Location and Optimal Zoning in a Small Open City.” Journal of Urban Economics Nº 55, pp. 614-626. [ Links ]

Matsumura, T., Matsushima, N. (2012). “Locating outside a linear city can benefit consumers”. Journal of Regional Science, 52 (3), pp. 420-432.” [ Links ]

Miceli, T., (1992). Optimal Fiscal Zoning when the Local Government is a Discriminating Monopolists. Regional Science and Urban Economics, Nº 22, pp. 579-504. [ Links ]

Mills, D., (1989). “Is zoning a negative -sum game?” Land Economics Nº 65, pp. 490-596. [ Links ]

Neven, D. J. (1987). “Endogenous sequential entry in a spatial model”. International Journal of Industrial Organization, 5 (4), pp. 419-434. [ Links ]

Nie, P. Y. (2011). “Spatial maintenance goods under monopoly”. Economic Research-Ekonomska istraživanja, 24 (4), pp. 16-26. [ Links ]

Nie, P. Y. (2013). “Innovation under spatial duopoly”. Prague Economic Papers, 23 (4), pp. 474-486. [ Links ]

Nie, Pu-Yan (2014). “Effects of capacity constraints on mixed duopoly”. Journal of Economics 112 (3), pp. 283-294. [ Links ]

Pal, D. (1998). “Does Cournot competition yields spatial agglomeration?”. Economics Letter, Vol. 1, Nº 60, pp. 49-53. [ Links ]

Tsai, Jyh-Fa, Peng, Shin-Kun, Lai, Fu-Chuan (2006). “Spatial Duopoly with Zoning”. Annals of Regional Science, Nº 40, pp. 515-530. [ Links ]

Yang, Y. C., & Nie, P. Y. (2015). “R&D subsidies under asymmetric Cournot competition”. Economic Research-Ekonomska Istraživanja, 28(1), pp. 830-842. [ Links ]

Wheaton, W. (1993). Land Capitalisation, Tiebout Mobility, and the Role of Zoning Regulation. Journal of Urban Economics, Nº 34, pp. 102-117. [ Links ]

Wrede, M. (2015). “A continuous logit Hotelling model with endogenous locations of consumers”, Economics Letters, 126, pp. 81-83. [ Links ]

1 Such weighted approach was defined by Baron & Myerson (1982) whereas Armstrong et al. (1994) used it to describe a welfare function.

2 See Fujita & Thisse (1986).

3 Here, it is not necessary to consider 0.5 ≤ v1 ≤ v2 ≤ 1.

4 An indifferent consumer, α buys from firm 1 or 2 so that; u1(α) = u2 (α).

5 Indifferent consumers α1 N = v1+v2 / 2 , α2 N = v1+v2 / 2 + 1/2

6 Lai and Tsai (2004) comment on this type of zoning, nevertheless, they do not analyse it. In contrast, these authors, study the linear city model in [0, 1] by assuming the area [0, z) to be only residential.

Appendix: Demonstration of Proposition 1

Given the expressions for the price equilibrium profit functions; the Nash equilibrium locations can be calculated by using the first order condition: We obtain that

Since 0 ≤ v1 ≤ x1 ≤ x 2 ≤ v2 ≤ 1 / 2, for any value of x1, x2, we then have that

x2 − x1 ≤ 1 / 2 , so that the necessary condition is only fulfilled for locations:

Appendix:Demonstration of Proposition 2

For clarity reasons, the welfare function is rewritten as follows:

By using the first order condition we find that: . Considering that this condition depends on the value of parameter λ, in order to determine the maximum a second order condition is needed:

Taking into account that: we can deduct the following results:

  • If

    the social welfare function is concave and reaches a maximum for

  • If

    the social welfare is constant which means it takesthe same value for any value of v between 0 y ½. This means the maximum is reached for so that

  • If

    in this case the social welfare function is convex and the solution for the first order condition corresponds to a minimum, so that a maximum is obtained for

Appendix: Demonstration of Proposition 3

By using the first order condition, and for λ ≠ 1, it is found that . Assuming that the second order condition is: . Given that: , is the maximum of the objective function if:

  • -If

    andfor, a maximum is reached for .

  • -If

    and for , the maximum is reached for

Received: March 2015; Accepted: April 2016

Creative Commons License This is an open-access article distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution License